Conflict and Fragile States in Africa

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Conflict and Fragile States in Africa"

Transcription

1 Conflict and Fragile States in Africa J. Paul Dunne and Nan Tian n 274 July 2017 Working Paper Series African Development Bank Group

2 Working Paper N o 274 Abstract This paper considers the determinants of conflict in Africa. It revisits the greed grievance debate to consider the specific regional context and changing nature of conflict in sub-saharan Africa. This is a literature that has grown rapidly in economics and political science, but some recent developments in modeling and conceptualization are providing important new contributions. It proposes and uses modeling techniques that deal with the problem of excess zeros, revisits the definition of conflict, and improves upon some proxy measures. Understanding the nature of conflict in Africa is vital to designing post-conflict economic policies and interventions, to ensure policies can prevent conflict-affected states from returning to conflict or remaining fragile. This paper is the product of the Vice-Presidency for Economic Governance and Knowledge Management. It is part of a larger effort by the African Development Bank to promote knowledge and learning, share ideas, provide open access to its research, and make a contribution to development policy. The papers featured in the Working Paper Series (WPS) are those considered to have a bearing on the mission of AfDB, its strategic objectives of Inclusive and Green Growth, and its High-5 priority areas to Power Africa, Feed Africa, Industrialize Africa, Integrate Africa and Improve Living Conditions of Africans. The authors may be contacted at workingpaper@afdb.org. Rights and Permissions All rights reserved. The text and data in this publication may be reproduced as long as the source is cited. Reproduction for commercial purposes is forbidden. The WPS disseminates the findings of work in progress, preliminary research results, and development experience and lessons, to encourage the exchange of ideas and innovative thinking among researchers, development practitioners, policy makers, and donors. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in the Bank s WPS are entirely those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the view of the African Development Bank Group, its Board of Directors, or the countries they represent. Working Papers are available online at Produced by Macroeconomics Policy, Forecasting, and Research Department Coordinator Adeleke O. Salami Correct citation: Dunne J. P. and N. Tian (2017), Conflict and Fragile States in Africa, Working Paper Series N 274, African Development Bank, Abidjan, Côte d Ivoire.

3 Conflict and Fragile States in Africa 1 J. Paul Dunne and Nan Tian JEL Classification: D74; C3 Keywords: Civil war; zero-inflation; greed; grievance 1 J. Paul Dunne: School of Economics and Southern Africa Labour Development Research Unit (SALDRU), University of Cape Town, Cape Town, 7701; Nan Tian: Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (SIPRI) and SALDRU, University of Cape Town; nan.tian.eco@gmail.com 1

4 1 Introduction Civil war has been commonplace over the past 60 years, but until relatively recently received little attention from economists. It is not just common, but also persistent, wars lasting longer, decade after decade (Fearon, Kasara, and Laitin 2007). Blattman and Miguel (2010) estimated that, since 1960, 20 percent of all countries have experienced at least 10 years of civil conflict. Civil conflict is devastating to the countries affected, with Collier et al. (2003) suggesting that the destructive forces of civil conflict could be large enough to explain the income gap between the poorest and richest nations. One could almost see civil war as reversing development, diverting resources from productive activities to destruction and having both devastating direct costs and opportunity costs, from the loss of productive resources (Collier et al. 2003). These potential costs make it important to understand why conflicts start, and the contribution by Collier and Hoeffler (2004), which sought to empirically test two competing theoretical hypotheses concerning the determinants of intrastate armed conflict opportunity versus grievance led to a large empirical literature. Their finding of overwhelming support in favor of the view that rebellion is motivated by greed or opportunity, led to a vigorous debate and an impressive empirical literature, that generally accepted the dominance of greed, but became rather more nuanced (Blatmann and Miguel 2010). Researchers started to accept the general framework, but to examine other potential determinants that had not already been considered. Nowhere is this move beyond greed and grievance more evident than in quantitative studies of conflict prevalence in sub-saharan Africa where the imposition of artificial state borders, living in bad neighborhoods and warmer temperatures (increasingly so, in the face of climate change) have come to take central focus as explanatory variables of interest in the econometric models employed in these studies (Hendrix and Glaser 2007; Burke et al. 2009; Greene 2010). A number of developments have led to a point where there is some value to be gained from revisiting the debate. First, there are obviously more years of data available, more economic shocks, and more conflicts. This provides both more degrees of freedom and potentially more leverage for empirical analyses. Second, there have been significant improvements in the operationalization of difficult-to-measure indicators of grievance (i.e., income inequality, ethnic divisions). Third there has been some development in the estimation methods available for the analysis. In particular, is the recognition that simple probit, or logit model, does not perform well in situations where there are a large number of zeroes in the 2

5 dependent variable, a likely case for civil conflict since fortunately many country-year observations are zero (e.g., peace) (Dunne and Tian 2014). Another important issue is the general consensus that, while conflict is detrimental to economic development, its impact could be even greater for fragile states (Rodrik 1999). Fragile states are weak and failing with severe handicaps in economic development and institutional governance, and a conflict can be particularly devastating to these states and their neighbors (Dunne and Tian 2014). This combination of fragility and civil conflict is a particular concern for Africa, and this paper revisits the greed grievance debate and fragile states, using a database of 33 African countries for the period 1960 to A review of the determinants of civil war literature and the greed grievance debate, together with a review and definition of fragile states, is provided in the next section. Following is a discussion and outline of the estimation procedures to be used in particular, the zeroinflated Probit (ZiOP) model. Section 4 then presents the data used and variable construction and provides some descriptive statistics, followed by the empirical estimates of a greed grievance model, using the usual methods and the ZiOP model, with various robustness checks. The final section offers some conclusions, with discussion on the policy implications. 2 Causes of Civil Conflict There are a range of theoretical perspectives that inform the analysis of civil wars, reflecting the interdisciplinary nature of the research and the relatively late involvement of economists. Political scientists focused upon the grievance determinants of conflicts, with theories emphasizing how modernization could lead to disruption of social order, with social and economic change causing the breakdown of social cohesion and alteration of perceptions. This can lead to disadvantaged groups feeling threatened, identifying with ethnic or social groups and mobilizing for change. It can also ignite of old hatreds, and in times of change and crisis, successful ethnic entrepreneurial networks, despite their importance for economic growth, can become a source of resentment. A formalization of this perspective was provided by political rational choice theories. These focused on the role of political repression, failing institutions, transitions, and informational problems, which together with a failure to redress grievances economic or political can lead to conflict. An alternative was provided by constructivist theories, which focus on the social construction of identity, rather than accepting it as some fixed attribute. It is then political mobilization that leads to civil violence, with leaders constructing ethnic and social identity in ways that benefit themselves (Sambanis 2002). 3

6 In contrast, the focus of economists was the greed-based determinants of conflict. Grossman (1991) modeled rebellion as an industry, where insurgents gain profits from looting and have costs. In this model, insurgents are no different to bandits, and the incidence of rebellion is fully explained by atypical circumstances that generate profitable opportunities. In a different line, Hirschleifer (1995) asked why fighting occurred between rational agents, given it was a Pareto suboptimal situation. A model with preferences, opportunities, and perceptions suggested it was possible that opportunities and grievances were wrongly perceived because of asymmetric information. Agents overestimate capability and their probability of winning, and grievances are based on limited or inaccurate information and/or divergent preferences. While economists generally assume property rights are exogenous, a limited body of theoretical work has focused on endogenous property rights and economic theories of appropriation. Rational agents exist in a lawless setting with competition for resources, and predation and defense are alternatives to directly productive activities. Without well-defined property rights, contracts cannot be enforced, except by a ruler or hegemon, and they can be replaced forcibly. In the contest model, an incumbent and a rebel group allocate resources to production or appropriation through a production function, while a contest success function determines the probability of success, based on the proportion of arms and the effectiveness of technology in an environment of informational asymmetry. The problem with this model is that it always gives a fighting outcome (Skaperdas 2001; Dunne and Coulomb 2008). These economic theory perspectives suggest that the onset of civil conflict is linked to the ability of insurgents to make a profit the greed hypothesis rather than the result of grievances. Collier and Hoeffler (2004) provided an empirical analysis of the competing hypotheses, suggesting that while political grievances are universal, economic incentives are not, and so are often decisive in the start of conflict. They use a Hirschleifer-type framework (1995), where rebellion is the outcome of rational decision-making, subject to constraints of the rebel labor market. The probability of rebel victory depends on the ability of the incumbent to defend, which is determined by technology (and although the technology is also available to the rebels, it is limited) and military spending, to which the rebels do not have access. So the taxable base can be used as a measure of how strong the government is, but it also measures the potential gains that rebels can make if they achieve victory. Population is then used as a proxy for the rebels desire for secession, while per capita income and the duration of the conflict serve as proxies for the costs of rebellion, both opportunity costs and economic disruption costs. Measures of fractionalization are used as proxy for the costs of coordination, 4

7 and the transaction and coordination costs to a rebellion are approximated by ethnic fractionalization. Expected utility is then a function of the probability of victory, the size of the taxable base of the country, and GDP per capita. The expected gain from the rebellion is an increasing function of the size of population, and the probability of conflict will be expected to decrease with GDP per capita and expected duration. Rebel groups have the potential to finance an insurrection if they can extort natural resources, get donations from diaspora, and get support from hostile foreign governments. The ratio of primary commodity exports to GDP natural resources in exports, the proportion of the population that moved to the United States, and the indicator variable for Cold War all are viewed as proxies for these funding sources. Insurrection is considered more likely if individuals foregone income is low, which will mean the cost of recruits will be low, and this will be determined by economic growth and its impact on labor demand, income levels, and levels of schooling. It will also be encouraged if the cost of military equipment is low, and this is likely to be reflected in the time since the previous conflict, as the shorter it is, the more likely weapons will be readily available. Success is more likely if there is weak government military capability, and this will be determined by the nature of the terrain mountainous areas assist guerrillas and the distribution of the population, because if it is spread out thinly, it will be harder to police. It is also likely that low social cohesion will make it easier for the rebels, which can be approximated by measures of ethnic fractionalization. For objective grievances, measures of polarization are used namely, ethnic and religious differences. The Polity III data set and political exclusion is used to approximate political repression, with the Gini coeffient acting as a proxy for a measure of ethnic dominance and economic inequality. The theorists argue greed and misperceived grievance have important similarities. Opportunity and viability provide common conditions for both profit and nonprofit rebel organizations, but the groups are observationally equivalent, making it impossible to discern the underlying drive of the organization. Using five-year averages as data points, researchers estimate separate models for opportunity and grievance, finding opportunity is the one that seems to works best. They then combine the two models, finding that the probability of conflict is mainly determined by slow growth, and the importance of natural resources, which also increases the probability, as well as foregone income, measured by secondary school attainment, which also reduces the probability as the attainment is increased. The proxies for ethnic fractionalization, inequality and democracy, are all insignificant, leading the theorists to conclude that the greed factors 5

8 dominate the grievance, ones. Factors that influence opportunity, finance, cost of rebellion, and military advantage are significant in determining civil war, while most proxies of grievance are insignificant, though population has an effect and time seems to heal. The finding that opportunity explains conflict risk is supportive of the economic interpretation of rebellion as motivated by greed (Collier and Hoeffler 2004; 2007). Around the same time, Fearon and Laitin (2003) developed a slightly different model, a one-shot, reduced-form game of insurgency, where the size of a rebellion is influenced by government effort and the scale of the initial rebellion. They also found that political grievance had little explanatory power, but that state institutional capacity was significant suggesting that wars are caused by countries having weak institutions. They differed with Collier and Hoeffler (2004) in interpreting GDP per capita as reflecting state capacity, rather than as an opportunity cost. They also differed in how they coded civil wars and used annual data, rather than five-year averages. The two papers had major impacts on research and debate and led to a large literature that has advanced understanding, telling us what we do not know, as well as what we do. Clearly, it is not enough to assume grievance drive conflicts, and greed or economic factors have to be considered (Blattman and Miguel 2010). While the general cross-country consensus in the literature developed that motivations of greed outweigh those of grievance in explaining civil war onset, the literature continued to develop and improve in a number of areas. First, political scientists have questioned the apparent lack of significance of variables that are proxies for objective grievance. In a recent contribution by Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014), the authors argued that the lack of significance had to do with the poor proxy variables used in previous research and showed that better proxies indicate that grievances do matter. This has led to efforts being made to improve measurement and obtain better proxies, with natural resource data being improved for resources and better measurement of grievance, better measurement of inequality to include horizontal and vertical inequality, and better measures of weak institutions (Lujala, Gleditsch, and Gilmore 2005; Wucherpfennig et al. 2011). Second, some attempts have been made at improving causal identification. The potential endogeneity of GDP to conflict led to the use of rainfall as an instrument, given that it will impact on agrarian economies but not on conflict. Other attempts have used price shocks and trade shocks in a similar manner. The identification problems remains an issue, mostly due 6

9 to difficulties in finding appropriate instruments (Blattman and Miguel 2010; Miguel, Satyanath, and Sergenti 2004). Third, some attempts have been made to consider possible spillover effects of conflicts, creating conflicts in other countries, with the feedback of refugees keeping conflicts going (Salehyan and Gleditsch 2006; Dunne and Tian 2014). Fourth, questions have been raised about measures of conflict and violence. In the past, war tended to be determined as an event in which there were more than 1,000 battle-related deaths, with peace defined as less than this. Initially, this was developed for inter-country conflicts and continued in use, even after the focus shifted to civil conflicts in the post-cold War world. This was seen, then, as unsuitable, and a definition of conflict, of when there were more than 25 battle-related deaths, was applied. A further development saw Besley and Persson (2010, 2014) create a nonbinary ordinal measure of civil violence, with 0 as the value for peace, 1 for civil repression, based on Banks (2005), and 2 for large-scale civil conflict with more than 1,000 battle deaths. 2 Fifth, there has been some concern over the estimation methods used. These have generally used a zero one dependent variable for conflict, but this leads to a lot of zeros (peace years), and they are likely to be from different data generation processes. There is a difference in interpretation between a a country that is in and out of war and a country that is generally at peace, so a 0 value in a particular year for Botswana is rather different to that for the DRC (Bagozzi et al. 2015). In this study, the focus is, first, on analyzing the determinants of conflict onset in Africa by applying a comprehensive greed grievance model to more up-to-date data and using better proxies that have been developed over time. Second is to consider the measurement of conflict onset and use the wider definition mentioned here, together with relevant econometric methods. 3 Data To operationalize a general greed grievance empirical model, a range of variables were collected following developments in the literature. Proxies for greed or opportunity include real GDP, growth in GDP per capita, degree of urbanization, life expectancy, and natural 2 New datasets are allowing more consistent and detailed information to be used, such as the data set of global instances of political violence ( 7

10 resource dependence. For this study, two sets of income variables were collected from the World Bank and Penn World Tables 8.0. Degree of urbanization is measured as the proportion of a country's population living in an urban environment, while life expectancy follows the usual measurement. 3 Male secondary school enrollment was not used in the estimations due to poor and incomplete data. Following from the literature, natural resource dependence is measured by the share of primary commodity exports in GDP. The World Bank provides data for the period 1960 to 1999, which was cross-referenced with Fearon (2005) for consistency. The remaining 14 years are constructed, using export data (primary commodities) provided by the World Trade Organization (WTO), and GDP, from the World Bank. Given the ongoing debates on the measure of natural resource dependence and the type of commodities used, three additional measurements are considered. A measure of oil production in metric tons and oil exports greater than one-third of total exports are used as proxy for oil abundance and dependence, respectively. 4 To distinguish fuel and nonfuel minerals from other primary commodities, a mineral dependence variable was created. A country is considered mineral dependent, if its mineral exports constitute 25 percent or more of a country's total tangible exports. Percentage of mountainous terrain in a given country is included, as an indicator of military accessibility or safe havens for rebels. The grievance variables are, for the most part, common to those identified by Collier and Hoeffler (2004) and Fearon and Laitin (2003). This paper considers three general measures of grievance: ethnic and religious hatred, political repression or freedom, and income inequality (horizontal inequality). Ethnic fractionalization is the most commonly chosen indicator to test the linkage between ethnicity and civil conflict. 5 Measurements of ethnic fractionalization is taken from Collier and Hoeffler (2004), with ethnic dominance, which is measured as a binary variable, taking on the value of one if the largest ethnic group in a country amounts to percent of the population, and is used as alternative to ethnic hatred. To measure religious 3 This data is sourced from the World Bank. The degree of urbanization can also be thought of as a measurement of geographic dispersion: the greater the urbanization, the lower the geographic dispersion. All income figures are adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP). 4 Oil production data, in metric tons, are provided by Ross (2013), for the years, 1932 to The additional two years were drawn from the same source used by Ross,, the US Department of Energy website for international energy statistics: 5 Initially used by Easterly and Levine (1997), the fractionalization index follows in accordance with Herfindahl s formula, and is interpreted as the probability that two randomly selected individuals in a population belong to different ethnic groups. 8

11 hatred, Collier and Hoeffler (2004) constructed a fractionalization index analogous to ethnic fractionalization, and this is, in turn, used in the estimation process. Other things being equal, political democracy or freedom should be associated with less discrimination, repression, and civil war. Data from the Polity IV database is used to measure political rights, with the variable polity ranging from 10 (high autocracy) to 10 (high democracy). The relationship between political freedom and civil war has often been thought of having a nonlinear effect (Hegre et al. 2001). This hypothesis is tested through the inclusion of a polity-squared term. In a recent paper by Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014), the authors found that new grievance indices of horizontal income inequality and political discrimination performed much better than conventional indicators. They argued that economic grievance is captured by the relative gap between the mean national income and the income level of the poorest and richest groups (positive and negative horizontal inequality), while ethnopolitical grievance is measured by the demographic size of the largest ethnic group discriminated against. 6 This paper uses these alternative variables as substitutes in robustness checks for ethnopolitical and economic grievance. The control variables included in the model are the standard ones found in the literature (i.e., population and cold war). Finally, the dependent variable used here takes on a value of 0 for all peace year observations and a value of 1 for minor conflict years with combat deaths ranging between , and 2 for full-scale civil wars with annual battle deaths above 1,000. Table 2 presents descriptive statistics of the aforementioned variables with a breakdown by conflict experience and always zeroes or always peaceful. These results seem to support the central thesis that the different zeroes in the sample are formed through completely separate processes. For the always zero or complete peace group, GDP per capita, per capita GDP growth, rate of urbanization, life expectancy, and political freedom are all higher than the not always zero group. Moreover, countries that are potentially completely peaceful have lower levels of ethnic and religious fractionalization and income inequality. 7 Estimated correlations suggest some association between income and inequality variables and the likelihood of a country being completely peaceful versus incompletely peaceful. In episodes of civil conflict, 6 For full description and derivation of the variables, see Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014). 7 LDG = largest discriminated (against) ethnic group, PHI = positive horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income and income level of the richest group), NHI = negative horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income and income level of the poorest group) 9

12 GDP per capita, GDP growth, rate of urbanization, life expectancy, and political freedom are all lower compared to times of peace. Similarly, ethnic divisions, income inequality, and substantial amounts of rough terrain are higher in cases of civil war. Interestingly, primary commodity exports as a share of GDP is on average lower in episodes of civil war compared to no civil war. Opportunity Table 1. Descriptive Statistics Means Full Sample Always 0 Not Always 0 Civil War No Civil War Primary commodity exports/gdp GDP per capita GDP per capita growth Mountains Rate of urbanization Life expectancy Oil production (metric tons 000 s) Mineral dependence Oil exports Grievance Ethnic frac (C&H) Ethnic dominance Religious frac (0 100) Polity IV ( 10 to 10) LDG NHI PHI Greed vs. Grievance Revisited Estimating the probability of civil conflict using an ordered probit gave the results in Table 2. The civil conflict dependent variable takes the value of 1 if deaths total over 25 in a given battle, 2 if there are over 1,000 battle deaths in a given year, and 0 otherwise. 10

13 Table 2. Ordered Probit of Civil War Prevalence (1) (2) (3) Probit Probit Probit Outcome Outcome Outcome Opportunity Pri exports/ GDP ** ** ** (0.966) (0.978) (0.963) Pri exports/ GDP ** 9.045** 5.908** (1.585) (1.595) (1.597) log real GDP ** ** (0.052) (0.052) (0.050) RGDPPC growth ** ** ** (0.523) (0.520) (0.527) log mountains 0.054* 0.118** 0.062* (0.028) (0.030) (0.028) Grievance Polity Index (0.032) (0.032) (0.031) Polity Index (0.005) (0.005) (0.004) Ethno frac (F&L) 6.022** (0.998) Ethno frac2 (F&L ** (0.934) Ethno frac (C&H) (0.008) Ethno frac2 (C&H) (0.001) Ethnic dominance 0.210* 0.292* (0.086) (0.119) Continued on next page 11

14 Table 2. continued (1) (2) (3) Probit Probit Probit Outcome Outcome Outcome Religious frac 0.967** (0.301) (0.275) LDG 1.264** (0.168) PHI * (0.078) NHI 0.859** (0.125) Control Log population 0.340** 0.413** 0.514** (0.066) (0.068) (0.679) Cold War ** (0.097) (0.096) (0.104) Observations 1,519 1,519 1,542 Log likelihood AIC Notes: Dependent variable: Conflict prevalence; AIC = Akaike Information Criterion; Standard errors in parentheses; Significance levels: ** p < 0.01,* p < 0.05, t p < 0.1; LDG = largest discriminated (against) ethnic group, PHI = positive horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income and income level of the richest group), NHI = negative horizontal inequality (relative gap between mean national income and income level of the poorest group). The results (columns 1 3) provide the standard ordered Probit model with a number of alternative specifications considered. These additional estimates replace ethnolinguistic fractionalization used by Fearon and Laitin (2003) with that from Collier and Hoeffler (2004) (specification 2) and introduce a new ethnic discrimination measure and income inequality (specification 3). The results reveal that in the case of the normal ordered Probit, irrespective of the specification, primary commodity exports, as a share of GDP, have a nonlinear relationship on civil conflict incidence, first decreasing and then increasing. This is a finding that is opposite to that found in the existing literature, however, and in light of the summary statistics in Table 2, where primary commodity exports, as a share of GDP, are lower for 12

15 countries not in civil conflict, the result makes some empirical sense. GDP and per capita GDP growth are significant in decreasing the probability of civil war, while presence of mountainous terrain seems to increase civil war risk through the proxy of geographic dispersion, which inhibits government or military capacity. As for grievance variables, the results from the three specifications offer a similar conclusion: first, political freedom or opportunity does not matter the coefficient and its square term are insignificant in determining chances of civil war. Second, ethnicity matters, conditional on the choice of the ethnic fractionalization variable. The coefficient that is a proxy for ethnic grievance, which measures a systematic inequality in ethnopolitical opportunities, is positive and statistically significant, with its square term negative and significant when the Fearon and Laitin (2003) variable (1) is used, but is insignificant on the Collier and Hoeffler (2004) variable (2). As expected, ethnic dominance increases civil war risk, while religious fractionalization has a mixed effect. Given the differing results on ethnolinguistic fractionalization between specification 1 and 2, specification 3 looks for an alternative measure and also includes horizontal income inequality. The variable LGD, which is a proxy for ethnic and political inequality, is positive and highly significant. 8 Additionally, of the horizontal measures of economic inequality, the relative gap between the country-level GDP per capita and the mean per capita income for the poorest ethnic group in a given country, NHI, is positive and statistically significant at the 10 percent level, suggesting that African countries with one or more ethnic group(s) radically poorer than the national average have a higher risk of conflict onset. The opposite, however, is also true for the relative gap between the per capita GDP mean and that of the richest group, PHI, which is negative and significant. Here, income inequality has less meaning to the richest group, and there is an incentive to keep peace and retain wealth rather than to rebel. As for the control variables, population has a positive and significant effect on an African countries civil war prevalence, while the Cold War dummy is only negative and significant for the last specification. In most analyses on the determinants of civil conflict, an ordered dependent variable is used, in which a given country-year is assigned a value of 0 for peace and a value of 1 when violence between the state and another side reaches a given threshold, thereby classifying it as 8 For full explanation of the largest discriminated (against) ethnic growth (LGD), see Buhaug, Cederman, and Gleditsch (2014). 13

16 a civil war. This would generally mean that there are a large number of zero observations, since peaceful years will dominate conflict years. These zeros can be considered as reflecting rather different states, one where the structural and societal forces ensure a zero probability of civil conflict regardless of greed or grievance incentives and another that reflects a break in fighting and a high probability of returning to conflict. The first group of zeros will often be non-fragile states, such as South Africa or Botswana, and can be labeled complete-peace while the second group are often found in fragile regions such as Central, West, or East Africa, from which the zeroes can be labeled as incomplete-peace. The main difference between the first and second case of zero is that while the probability of transition into war for first type is zero, the probability for the incomplete peace group is not. In the case of incomplete-peace, incentives resulting from opportunity or grievance can induce violent conflict. Given the high proportion of heterogeneous zeroes in the analysis, using ordinary probit or logit models may not be appropriate tools for statistical inference and can potentially give biased estimates (Bagozzi et al. 2015). A more satisfactory estimation method is the split population or two-part model proposed by Harris and Zhao (2007) and Vance and Ritter (2014). This is typically in the form of zero-inflated models, or in this case, a zero-inflated Probit model, where estimations follow two stages. The first of the two latent equations, stage one, is a selection equation, while the second stage is a Probit outcome equation. This splits the observations into two processes, each potentially having different sets of explanatory variables. In the context of civil war prevalence, zero observations in process 0 (wi = 0) include inflated zeroes, consistent with countries that never experience civil conflict (e.g., Sweden), while zero observations in process 1 (wi = 1) includes cases for which the probability of transitioning into a civil conflict is not zero, and civil war casualties have not reached the lower bound (or limit) of 1,000 battle-related deaths. The binary variable w indicates the split between process 0 (with wi = 0 for no war) and process 1 (with wi = 1 for war). The variable w is related to the latent dependent variable w i so that wi = 1 for w i > 0 and wi = 0 for w i 0, where w i now represents the propensity to enter process 1 and is given by the split probit (1st stage) equation: w i = x i γ + μ i (1) 14

17 where x i is a vector of covariates, γ is its coefficients and μ i is the error term. The probability of i falling into process 1 is Pr(w i = 1 x i ) = Pr(w i > 0 x i ) = Ψ(x i g), and the probability that it is in process 0 is Pr(w i = 0 x i ) = Pr(w i 0 x i ) = 1 Ψ(x i γ), where (.) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. For the Probit outcome equation, the propensity for participation in which the response variable Y i (i.e, conflict) has a distribution given by: w i + (1 w i ) e( λ i ), y i = 0 Pr(Y i = y i ) = { (1 w i ) e( λ i ) λ y i i, y y! i > 0 i (2) where the parameters λ i and w i depend on vectors of covariates x i and zi,, respectively, which are modeled as: and log(λ i ) = x i t β (3) log ( w i 1 w i ) = z i t γ (4) with mean and variance as E(Y i ) = (1 w i ) i and var(y i ) = μ + ( w i 1 w i ) μ 2. In this ZIP model, the matrices z and x contain different sets of experimental factor and covariate effects that relate to the probability of the zero state (zero probability of civil war) and the Poisson mean in the nonzero state (probable civil war), respectively. Thus, the s have interpretations in terms of the factor level effect on the probability that there is a zero probability of conflict and the /3 s have the interpretation of the effect on the average risk of civil war when the probability is non-zero. Following Lambert (1992), the ZIP model (Equation 2) can be regressed using maximum likelihood with an Expectation-maximum (EM) algorithm. 9 The use of ZioP model allows more accurate estimates to be obtained, compared to standard probit or logit models. The probability of a zero observation is now modeled 9 For full derivation of the model, see Lambert (1992) and Hall (2000). 15

18 conditionally on the probability of zero from the Probit process plus the probability of being in process 0 from the splitting equation. It should be noted that the usefulness of the model (i.e., unbiased estimates) declines when the size of the split in the sample population becomes very big or very small, leading to biased results. 10 Bagozzi et al. (2015) suggested that this becomes an issue when there is less than 10 percent or greater than 90 percent of zero observations. Estimating the general greed grievance models using the zero-inflated ordered probit model give the results in Table 3. The specification for the inflation equation is limited to GDP, per capita GDP growth, political freedom (Polity) and ethnic divisions (Eth Frac), as such factors promote a compatibility of interests between the state and its citizens, which in turn influences the probability that a country is in the always zero group and always experiences peace. That said, to ensure that the zero-inflated ordered probit (ZiOP) estimates in Table 3, specification 1, are not driven by choice of variables, a model in which all the covariates in the outcome equation are included in the inflation equation is also estimated (Table 3, specification 2). 10 Statistical inference becomes increasingly difficult as the proportional of zeroes gets close to one. 16

19 Table 3. Probit and ZIP Regression of Civil War Prevalence (1) (2) ZiOP ZiOP Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation Opportunity log RGDP ** * * ** (0.064) (0.152) (0.096) (0.147) RGDPPC growth ** * t (0.550) (1.299) (0.803) (1.243) Pri exports/gdp ** ** ** (1.122) (1.473) (2.535) Pri exports/ GDP ** ** ** (1.709) (2.604) (3.504) log 3 mountains ** 0.781** (0.030) (0.628) (0.083) Grievance Polity Index ** 0.317** ** 0.336** (0.010) (0.108) (0.012) (0.110) Polity Index ** * ** * (0.002) (0.014) (0.003) (0.012) Eth frac (F&L) 7.097** 2.784** 5.463** ** (1.188) (0.673) (2.006) (3.048) Continued on next page 17

20 Table 3 - Continued from previous page (1) (2) ZiOP ZiOP Outcome Inflation Outcome Inflation Eth frac2 (F&L) ** ** ** (1.069) ( 1.599) (3.248) Ethnic dominance 0.417** ** 0.576** (0.096) (0.467) (0.119) (0.269) Religious frac t (0.328) (0.439) (0.786) Controls log Population 0.112** 1.818** ** (0.032) (0.243) (0.104) (0.283) Cold War * (0.102) (0.212) Constant ** ** t ** (0.977) (3.004) (1.364) (3.228) Observations 1,519 1,519 Log likelihood AIC Notes: AIC = Akaike Information Criterion; Dependent variable: Conflict prevalence; Standard errors in parentheses; Significance levels: ** p < 0.01,* p < 0.05, tp < 0.1 Estimating the probability of civil conflict, the zero-inflated ordered probit model in Table 3 can be directly compared to the ordered probit model in Table 2, specification 1. To start with, the coefficients reported in the first stage, inflation equation, of the ZiOP model reveal that GDP per capita has a negative and significant effect on the likelihood of a countryyear not being among the always-zero or peace group and then experiencing any level of civil violence. Additionally, political freedom seems to have the usual nonlinear effect of increasing the likelihood of civil conflict and then decreasing it past a certain point. Ethnicity also plays an important role in the different observed zeroes; here the more ethnically diverse a county's population is, the more likely it is to experience any form of violence, while a country with one ethnic dominant group has the opposite effect in decreasing chances of a civil conflict. 18

21 Turning towards the outcome equation, the estimates here are conditioned only for countries that are able to experience a civil conflict. In other words, the estimates are for country-years that are not in the always peaceful group. As mentioned previously, the key feature of this group is that there are societal forces that make the probability of transitioning into violence non zero. These would essentially be African fragile states. By distinguishing between the different types of zeroes, or types of countries, the ZiOP provides some new insights on the greed grievance estimates. While the ZiOP model (1) gives signs that are consistent with the standard ordered probit, there are substantial differences in the significance of the grievance terms. Primary commodity exports as a proportion of GDP show the same effect as before, albeit at a higher turning point of 40 percent. Income, both its level and its growth, decreases the likelihood that a country experiences civil conflict, conditional on that country being able to experience a conflict. Or in other words, a condition on it being a fragile state. Proxies for ethnopolitical grievance are better represented using the zero inflated models than the ordered probit, with political freedom now a significant predictor of civil war prevalence. This effect, however, is not of the usual inverse u-shape of first increasing and then decreasing, but rather decreases throughout. This is a very interesting finding and suggests that for the fragile states any kind of improvement in political freedom (less political oppression) will substantially lower the likelihood of any form of civil violence, with the impact diminishing as political grievance decreases. Ethnolinguistic fractionalization remains significant and of the correct sign, first increasing the risk and then decreasing when the probability of randomly selecting 2 individuals from different ethnic group reaches 57 percent. In addition to having more explanatory power and significance in the grievance variables, the zero-inflated ordered probit estimates are shown to have lower standard errors than the normal probit. An Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) test is run for both the probit and ZiOP, with the lower AIC value from the ZiOP suggesting that the zero-inflated models fits the data better than the probit. As suggested in Cameron and Trevidi (2010), all regressions are estimated using robust standard errors, while the proportion of zero observations in the sample (76.3 percent) falls within the accepted band of 10 to 90 percent (Bagozzi et al. 2015). Specification 2 represents the full model with all the covariates of the outcome equation also in the inflation equation. Here a comparison between (1) and the full model (2) is also a test for researcher s degrees of freedom, whereby a researcher could selectively choose specifications in order to generate significant results or false positives Simmons, Nelson, and 19

22 Simonsohn (2011). The similar results in (1) and (2) suggest the model is well specified, consistent to various specifications and not sensitive to researcher's degrees of freedom. To consider the robustness of the results, a number of alternative specifications (Table 2, specifications 2 and 3) are reestimated using the zero-inflated probit model. Table 4 in the Appendix is one example, with horizontal income inequality and ethnic discrimination added in place of ethnic dominance and religious fractionalization and Fearon and Laitin s (2003) ethnic fractionalization measure is replaced with Collier and Hoeffler s (2004). These results remain consistent with the estimates in Table 3, where the zero-inflated ordered probit model is preferred to the ordered probit model in almost all instances. Other variants of the zero-inflated ordered probit were estimated replacing primary commodity exports with either mineral dependence, oil production, or oil export; replacing the polity index with the freedom house measure, democracy, and autocracy dummies; substituting income variables with urbanization rate and life expectancy. The results are shown to be relatively robust, with primary commodity dependence increasing civil war risk, democracy political freedom, and higher urbanization decreasing civil war risk. 5 Conclusion This paper has revisited the greed-grievance debate within the context of fragility, using a data set of 33 African countries for the period 1960 to This seemed justified for a number of reasons: the existence of more years of data including more economic shocks and more conflicts, the significant improvements in the operationalization of difficult-to-measure indicators of grievance (i.e., income inequality, ethnic divisions), and the development of new estimation methods that seem well suited to the subject. It is also important to undertake such an analysis within the context of fragile states, as conflict is likely to be even more detrimental to their economic development. Thus, it is even more important to understand the drivers of conflict onset. Empirical estimations using a standard order Probit estimation technique do not account for the heterogeneous zeroes, and a zero-inflated model is also used, which distinguishes between observations that come from countries with a low probability of conflict and others. In essence, this is distinguishing between an important factor in determining fragile and nonfragile states. The main results are: first, unlike much of the earlier literature, civil war risk is not wholly dominated by greed, with grievance terms significant. Second, the zero-inflated ordered 20

23 probit models seem to perform better than the standard probit models and be better able to statistically account for observable and latent factors that produce different types of peace observations. The results suggest that using the ordinary probit, has biased the estimates, giving greater weighting to opportunity variables over grievance variables. This led to most empirical work finding opportunity or income variables as the main determinant of civil conflict. As one takes a deeper look at what type of country is mostly associated with the always zero or complete peace group, the answer is often high-income countries. By not distinguishing the different zeroes, the normal probit gave a likelihood of war calculation that included countries conditioned to not experience such an event. These countries main attribute is high income, and thus income variables were estimated with greater emphasis and significance, crowding out the grievance variable's explanatory power. By using a zero-inflated model and splitting the estimation process into two stages, greed and grievance variables are given equal emphasis, which makes it clear that both ethnopolitical and economic grievance matter, with substantial explanatory power in predicting civil war risk. Clearly, economic factors are important in determining conflict onset, but so are grievances, and this is clearer when the lower probability of higher income/peaceful countries is considered. In post-conflict situations, it is important to distinguish between fragile and nonfragile states and to carefully study the causes of the conflicts, both in terms of greed and grievance factors, and to deal with the underlying problems, rather than believing that general prescriptive policies will suffice (Brauer and Dunne 2012). References Bagozzi, B. E., D. W. Hill, W. H. Moore, and B. Mukherjee Modelling Two Types of Peace: The Zero-inflated Order Probit (ZiOP) Model in Conflict Research. Journal of Conflict Resolution 59 (4): Besley, T., and T. Persson, State Capacity, Conflict and Development. Econometrica 78(1) :1 34. Besley, T., and T. Persson The Causes and Consequences of Development Clusters: State Capacity, Peace and Income. Annual Review of Economics 6: Blattman, C., and E. Miguel Civil War. Journal of Economic Literature 48 (1): Brauer, J., and J. P. Dunne Peace Economics: A Macroeconomic Primer for Violence- Afflicted States. Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace. Buhaug, H., L.-E. Cederman, and K. S. Gleditsch Square Pegs in Round Holes: Inequalities, Grievances, and Civil War. International Studies Quarterly 58 (2):

24 Burke, M. B., E. Miguel, S. Satyanath, J. A. Dykema, and D. B. Lobell Warming Increases the Risk of Civil War in Africa. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (USA) 106 (49): Cameron, A. C., and P. K. Trivedi Microeconometrics Using Stata. Rev Ed. College Station, TX: Stata Press. Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler Greed and Grievance in Civil War. Oxford Economic Papers, 56 (4): Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler Civil War. In Handbook of Defense Economics, Vol. 2, edited by K. Hartley and T. Sandler, Amsterdam: North Holland. Collier, P., V. L. Elliot, H. Hegre, A. Hoeffler, M. Reynal-Querol, and N. Sambanis Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Dunne, P., and F. Coulomb Peace, War and International Security: Economic Theories. In War, Peace and Security, Vol. 6, edited by J. Fontanel and M. Chatterji, Bingley, UK: Emerald. Dunne, J. P. and N. Tian Conflict Spillovers and Growth in Africa. Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy 20 (4). DOI: Easterly, W. and Levine, P Africa s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): Fearon, J. D Primary Commodity Exports and Civil War. Journal of Conflict Resolution 49 (4): Fearon, J. D., and D. D. Laitin Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War. American Political Science Review 97 (1): Fearon, J. D., K. Kasara, and D. D. Laitin Ethnic Minority Rule and Civil War Onset. American Political Science Review 101 (1): Greene, W., Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear models. Economics Letters, 107(2): Grossman, H. I A General Equilibrium Model of Insurrections. American Economic Review 81 (4): Hall, D. B Zero-inflated Poisson and Binomial Regression with Random Effects: A Case Study. Biometrics 56 (4): Harris, M. N., and X. Zhao A Zero-inflated Ordered Probit Model with an Application to Modelling Tobacco Consumption. Journal of Econometrics 141 (2) : Hegre, H., T. Ellingsen, S. Gates, and N. P. Gleditsch Toward a Democratic Civil Peace? Democracy, Political Change, and Civil War, American Political Science Review 95(1): Hendrix, C. S., and S. M. Glaser Trends and Triggers: Climate, Climate Change and Civil Conflict in Sub-Saharan Africa. Political Geography. 26:

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, 1960-2006 Sources: Data based on UCDP/PRIO armed conflict database (N. P. Gleditsch et al., 2002; Harbom & Wallensteen, 2007).

More information

Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World

Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World Xiao 1 Yan Xiao Final Draft: Thesis Proposal Junior Honor Seminar May 10, 2004 Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World Introduction Peace and prosperity are

More information

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. World Politics, vol. 68, no. 2, April 2016.* David E. Cunningham University of

More information

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict Undergraduate Economic Review Volume 8 Issue 1 Article 10 2012 Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict Katharine M. Lindquist Carleton

More information

Greed and Grievance in Civil War

Greed and Grievance in Civil War Public Disclosure Authorized Greed and Grievance in Civil War Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler Public Disclosure Authorized October 21st, 2001 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Abstract

More information

Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Oxford Economic Papers.

Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Oxford Economic Papers. Greed and Grievance in Civil War Author(s): Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler Source: Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 56, No. 4 (Oct., 2004), pp. 563-595 Published by: Oxford University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3488799

More information

Repression or Civil War?

Repression or Civil War? Repression or Civil War? Timothy Besley London School of Economics and CIFAR Torsten Persson IIES, Stockholm University and CIFAR January 1, 2009 1 Introduction Perhaps the croning achievement of mature

More information

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries Illinois State University ISU ReD: Research and edata Master's Theses - Economics Economics 6-2008 Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries Michael Hotard Illinois

More information

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be he Nonlinear Relationship Between errorism and Poverty Byline: Poverty and errorism Walter Enders and Gary A. Hoover 1 he fact that most terrorist attacks are staged in low income countries seems to support

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict?

Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict? Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict? A GLOBAL ANALYSIS FHI 360 EDUCATION POLICY AND DATA CENTER United Nations Children s Fund Peacebuilding Education and Advocacy Programme Education

More information

Natural Resources & Income Inequality: The Role of Ethnic Divisions

Natural Resources & Income Inequality: The Role of Ethnic Divisions DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS OxCarre (Oxford Centre for the Analysis of Resource Rich Economies) Manor Road Building, Manor Road, Oxford OX1 3UQ Tel: +44(0)1865 281281 Fax: +44(0)1865 281163 reception@economics.ox.ac.uk

More information

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Violent Conflict and Inequality Violent Conflict and Inequality work in progress Cagatay Bircan University of Michigan Tilman Brück DIW Berlin, Humboldt University Berlin, IZA and Households in Conflict Network Marc Vothknecht DIW Berlin

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Lecture 19 Civil Wars

Lecture 19 Civil Wars Lecture 19 Civil Wars Introduction Much of the literature of civil war lies outside economics measurement difficulties importance of non economic factors such as personalities & leadership civil wars are

More information

Patterns of Conflicts and Effectiveness of Aid

Patterns of Conflicts and Effectiveness of Aid Patterns of Conflicts and Effectiveness of Aid Arcangelo Dimico * Queen s University of Belfast This Version: 13/05/2012 Abstract The effect of aid on civil war is one of the most debated in economics.

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Education Inequality and Violent Conflict: Evidence and Policy Considerations

Education Inequality and Violent Conflict: Evidence and Policy Considerations Education Inequality and Violent Conflict: Evidence and Policy Considerations UNICEF and recently completed by the FHI 360 Education Policy and Data Center, sought to change this using the largest dataset

More information

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Douglas M. Gibler June 2013 Abstract Park and Colaresi argue that they could not replicate the results of my 2007 ISQ article, Bordering

More information

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA Openness and Internal Conflict Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA 17837 cmagee@bucknell.edu Tansa George Massoud Department of Political Science Bucknell

More information

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland Online Appendix Laia Balcells (Duke University), Lesley-Ann Daniels (Institut Barcelona d Estudis Internacionals & Universitat

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment

Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment Catia Batista Trinity College Dublin and IZA Pedro C. Vicente Trinity College Dublin, CSAE-Oxford and BREAD Second International

More information

Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1. Jose G. Montalvo Universitat Pompeu Fabra and IVIE

Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1. Jose G. Montalvo Universitat Pompeu Fabra and IVIE Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized POST-CONFLICT TRANSITIONS WORKING PAPER NO. 6 Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of

More information

Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1

Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1 Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1 Jose G. Montalvo Universitat Pompeu Fabra and IVIE Marta Reynal-Querol Universitat Pompeu Fabra, CEPR and CESifo Abstract: In this paper we analyze

More information

The Colonial Origins of Civil War

The Colonial Origins of Civil War The Colonial Origins of Civil War Simeon Djankov The World Bank and CEPR Marta Reynal-Querol 1 Universitat Pompeu Fabra, CEPR, and CESifo March 2007 (Very preliminary and incomplete. Do not quote, circulate

More information

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015 Powersharing, Protection, and Peace Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm September 17, 2015 Corresponding Author: Yonatan Lupu, Department of Political Science,

More information

Trade and civil conflict: Revisiting the cross-country evidence *

Trade and civil conflict: Revisiting the cross-country evidence * Trade and civil conflict: Revisiting the cross-country evidence * Massimiliano Calì and Alen Mulabdic This version: December 2014 We revisit and expand the evidence on the impact of trade shocks on intra-state

More information

Rain and the Democratic Window of Opportunity

Rain and the Democratic Window of Opportunity Rain and the Democratic Window of Opportunity by Markus Brückner and Antonio Ciccone* 4 February 2008 Abstract. According to the economic approach to political transitions, negative transitory economic

More information

Aid, Policy and Peace: Reducing the Risks of Civil Conflict

Aid, Policy and Peace: Reducing the Risks of Civil Conflict Public Disclosure Authorized Aid, Policy and Peace: Reducing the Risks of Civil Conflict by Public Disclosure Authorized Paul Collier * World Bank 1818 H Street, N.W. MSN MC3-304 Washington, D.C. 20433

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann 1, Fernanda Martinez Flores 1,2, and Sebastian Otten 1,2,3 1 RWI, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD,

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD, ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD, 1970-1997. January 20, 2012 1. Introduction Rebels Without a Territory. An Analysis of Non-territorial

More information

Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1

Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1 Ethnic Polarization and the Duration of Civil Wars 1 Jose G. Montalvo IVIE and UPF Marta Reynal-Querol The World Bank July 2005 Abstract: In this paper we analyze the relationship between ethnic polarization

More information

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Kristian Skrede Gleditsch University of California, San Diego & Centre for the Study of Civil War, International Peace Research Institute, Oslo See http://weber.ucsd.edu/

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse

Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse [Author Information Omitted for Review Purposes] June 6, 2014 1 Table 1: Two-way Correlations Among Right-Side Variables (Pearson s ρ) Lit.

More information

THE FRIGHTFUL INADEQUACY OF MOST OF

THE FRIGHTFUL INADEQUACY OF MOST OF Discussion Paper no.11 THE FRIGHTFUL INADEQUACY OF MOST OF THE STATISTICS : A CRITIQUE OF COLLIER AND HOEFFLER ON CAUSES OF CIVIL WAR Laurie Nathan Crisis States Research Centre September 2005 Copyright

More information

CONFLICT, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SPATIAL SPILLOVER EFFECTS IN AFRICA

CONFLICT, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SPATIAL SPILLOVER EFFECTS IN AFRICA CONFLICT, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SPATIAL SPILLOVER EFFECTS IN AFRICA J Paul Dunne School of Economics and SALDRU, University of Cape Town John.Dunne@uct.ac.za Nan Tian School of Economics University of Cape

More information

On the Duration of Civil War

On the Duration of Civil War On the Duration of Civil War Paul Collier (1), (2), Anke Hoeffler (2) and Måns Söderbom (2) (1) World Bank (2) Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford May, 2001 Prepared for the

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

The Causes of Civil War

The Causes of Civil War The Causes of Civil War Simeon Djankov The World Bank and CEPR Marta Reynal-Querol 1 ICREA Universitat Pompeu Fabra, CEPR, and CESifo December 2010 (first version May 2007) Abstract We analyze the effect

More information

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at American Economic Association Poverty, Political Freedom, and the Roots of Terrorism Author(s): Alberto Abadie Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 2 (May, 2006), pp. 50-56 Published by:

More information

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn Index A Africa, 152, 167, 173 age Filipino characteristics, 85 household heads, 59 Mexican migrants, 39, 40 Philippines migrant households, 94t 95t nonmigrant households, 96t 97t premigration income effects,

More information

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance PRELIMINARY WORK - PLEASE DO NOT CITE Ken Jackson August 8, 2012 Abstract Governing a diverse community is a difficult task, often made more difficult

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis Author Saha, Shrabani, Gounder, Rukmani, Su, Jen-Je Published 2009 Journal Title Economics Letters

More information

The Role of External Support in Violent and Nonviolent Civil. Conflict Outcomes

The Role of External Support in Violent and Nonviolent Civil. Conflict Outcomes The Role of External Support in Violent and Nonviolent Civil Conflict Outcomes Prepared for the Western Political Science Association Annual Conference 2015 Jaime Jackson April 4, 2015 1 In 2000, Serbian

More information

Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel

Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel Dinuk Jayasuriya and Paul J. Burke Abstract This article investigates whether female political representation affects economic growth.

More information

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Direction of trade and wage inequality This article was downloaded by: [California State University Fullerton], [Sherif Khalifa] On: 15 May 2014, At: 17:25 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number:

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

The Economic Determinants of Democracy and Dictatorship

The Economic Determinants of Democracy and Dictatorship The Economic Determinants of Democracy and Dictatorship How does economic development influence the democratization process? Most economic explanations for democracy can be linked to a paradigm called

More information

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Ilkay Yilmaz 1,a, and Mehmet Nasih Tag 2 1 Mersin University, Department of Economics, Mersin University, 33342 Mersin, Turkey 2 Mersin University, Department

More information

Do governance indicators predict anything? The case of fragile states and civil war

Do governance indicators predict anything? The case of fragile states and civil war Do governance indicators predict anything? The case of fragile states and civil war James D. Fearon Department of Political Science Stanford University May 24, 2010 1 Introduction The term fragile state

More information

Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences

Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences Working Paper Series No.2007-1 Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences by Lee-in Chen Chiu and Jen-yi Hou July 2007 Chung-Hua Institution for Economic Research 75 Chang-Hsing Street,

More information

Ethnic Political Parties and Civil Conflict

Ethnic Political Parties and Civil Conflict Louisiana State University LSU Digital Commons LSU Master's Theses Graduate School 2016 Ethnic Political Parties and Civil Conflict Erin Nicole El Koubi Louisiana State University and Agricultural and

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2012 2012 The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Shrabani Saha Edith Cowan

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

Beyond Greed and Grievance: Feasibility and Civil War

Beyond Greed and Grievance: Feasibility and Civil War Beyond Greed and Grievance: Feasibility and Civil War Paul Collier, Anke Hoeffler, and Dominic Rohner Department of Economics, University of Oxford Department of Economics and Related Studies, University

More information

Post-Conflict Risks. Paul Collier, Anke Hoeffler and Måns Söderbom* In collaboration with the

Post-Conflict Risks. Paul Collier, Anke Hoeffler and Måns Söderbom* In collaboration with the Post-Conflict Risks Paul Collier, Anke Hoeffler and Måns Söderbom* In collaboration with the United Nations Department of Peace Keeping Operations and the World Bank Centre for the Study of African Economies,

More information

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ECONOMIC SHOCKS AND INSURGENT STRATEGY: EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTAN A BACHELOR THESIS SUBMITTED TO

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ECONOMIC SHOCKS AND INSURGENT STRATEGY: EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTAN A BACHELOR THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ECONOMIC SHOCKS AND INSURGENT STRATEGY: EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTAN A BACHELOR THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS FOR HONORS WITH THE DEGREE OF BACHELOR

More information

EFFECTS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS AND CORRUPTION ON GENDER DEVELOPMENT

EFFECTS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS AND CORRUPTION ON GENDER DEVELOPMENT EFFECTS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS AND CORRUPTION ON GENDER DEVELOPMENT A Thesis submitted to the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences at Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

More information

Should We Stay or Should We Go? Investigating the Impacts of Intervention on Post-War Development

Should We Stay or Should We Go? Investigating the Impacts of Intervention on Post-War Development Skidmore College Creative Matter Economics Student Theses and Capstone Projects Economics 2018 Should We Stay or Should We Go? Investigating the Impacts of Intervention on Post-War Development Benjamin

More information

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Preliminary version Do not cite without authors permission Comments welcome Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Joan-Ramon Borrell

More information

Understanding Subjective Well-Being across Countries: Economic, Cultural and Institutional Factors

Understanding Subjective Well-Being across Countries: Economic, Cultural and Institutional Factors International Review of Social Sciences and Humanities Vol. 5, No. 1 (2013), pp. 67-85 www.irssh.com ISSN 2248-9010 (Online), ISSN 2250-0715 (Print) Understanding Subjective Well-Being across Countries:

More information

How (wo)men rebel: Exploring the effect of gender equality on nonviolent and armed conflict onset

How (wo)men rebel: Exploring the effect of gender equality on nonviolent and armed conflict onset How (wo)men rebel: Exploring the effect of gender equality on nonviolent and armed conflict onset Journal of Peace Research 2017, Vol. 54(6) 762 776 ª The Author(s) 2017 Reprints and permission: sagepub.co.uk/journalspermissions.nav

More information

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE WP 2015: 9 Reported versus actual voting behaviour Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE Chr. Michelsen Institute (CMI) is an independent, non-profit research institution and a major international centre in

More information

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states?

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states? Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states? Ines A. Ferreira School of International Development, University of East Anglia (UEA) ines.afonso.rferreira@gmail.com Overview Motivation

More information

THE IMPACT OF OIL DEPENDENCE ON DEMOCRACY

THE IMPACT OF OIL DEPENDENCE ON DEMOCRACY THE IMPACT OF OIL DEPENDENCE ON DEMOCRACY A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree

More information

Economia i conflicte. Marta Reynal-Querol UPF-ICREA, IPEG, Barcelona GSE. Bojos per l Economia Barcelona, 4 Març 2017

Economia i conflicte. Marta Reynal-Querol UPF-ICREA, IPEG, Barcelona GSE. Bojos per l Economia Barcelona, 4 Març 2017 Economia i conflicte Marta Reynal-Querol UPF-ICREA, IPEG, Barcelona GSE Bojos per l Economia Barcelona, 4 Març 2017 1) Introduction to the empirical analysis of civil wars. We can create an analogy with

More information

SOCIOPOLITICAL INSTABILITY AND LONG RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CROSS COUNTRY EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION. +$/ø7 <$1,..$<$

SOCIOPOLITICAL INSTABILITY AND LONG RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CROSS COUNTRY EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION. +$/ø7 <$1,..$<$ SOCIOPOLITICAL INSTABILITY AND LONG RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CROSS COUNTRY EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION +$/ø7

More information

Will Inequality Affect Growth? Evidence from USA and China since 1980

Will Inequality Affect Growth? Evidence from USA and China since 1980 http://rwe.sciedupress.com Research in World Economy Vol. 8, No. 2; 217 Will Inequality Affect Growth? Evidence from and China since 198 Yongqing Wang 1 1 Department of Business and Economics, University

More information

Democracy and government spending

Democracy and government spending MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Democracy and government Pavlos Balamatsias 6 March 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86905/ MPRA Paper No. 86905, posted 23 May 2018 19:21 UTC Democracy

More information

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties Wenbin Chen, Matthew Keen San Francisco State University December 20, 2014 Abstract This article estimates

More information

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix F. Daniel Hidalgo MIT Júlio Canello IESP Renato Lima-de-Oliveira MIT December 16, 215

More information

Explaining occurrence of conflicts - clashes of cultures or abundance of resources?

Explaining occurrence of conflicts - clashes of cultures or abundance of resources? Institutionen för samhällsvetenskap Explaining occurrence of conflicts - clashes of cultures or abundance of resources? Bachelor Thesis in Linnaeus University Fall semester 2014 Nathalie Eriksson Tutor:

More information

The Origin of Terror: Affluence, Political Freedom, and Ideology

The Origin of Terror: Affluence, Political Freedom, and Ideology The Origin of Terror: Affluence, Political Freedom, and Ideology An Empirical Study of the Risk Factors of International Terrorism Caitlin Street Economics Honors Thesis College of the Holy Cross Advisor:

More information

GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE?

GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE? GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE? A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in

More information

5. Destination Consumption

5. Destination Consumption 5. Destination Consumption Enabling migrants propensity to consume Meiyan Wang and Cai Fang Introduction The 2014 Central Economic Working Conference emphasised that China s economy has a new normal, characterised

More information

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W. A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) by Stratford Douglas* and W. Robert Reed Revised, 26 December 2013 * Stratford Douglas, Department

More information

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil Peter Brummund Laura Connolly University of Alabama July 26, 2018 Abstract Many countries continue to integrate into the world economy,

More information

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51 THE IMPACT OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION ON TRADE SHARE AND PER CAPITA GDP: EVIDENCE FROM SUB SAHARAN AFRICA Abdurohman Ali Hussien, Terrasserne 14, 2-256, Brønshøj 2700; Denmark ; abdurohman.ali.hussien@gmail.com

More information

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Abstract: Growing income inequality and labor market polarization and increasing

More information

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook Digital Commons @ George Fox University Student Scholarship - School of Business School of Business 1-1-2016 Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook Benjamin Antony George Fox University, bantony13@georgefox.edu

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Democratic Tipping Points

Democratic Tipping Points Democratic Tipping Points Antonio Ciccone March 2018 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 1026 Democratic Tipping Points Antonio Ciccone March 2018 Abstract I examine whether transitory

More information

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? LSE Research Online Article (refereed) Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? Originally published in Applied economics letters, 10

More information

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test Axel Dreher a and Hannes Öhler b January 2010 Economics Letters, forthcoming We investigate the impact of government ideology on left-wing as

More information

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter?

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? An Innovative Approach to the Characterisation of the European Political Space. Giovanna Iannantuoni, Elena Manzoni and Francesca Rossi EXTENDED

More information

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA Mahari Bailey, et al., : Plaintiffs : C.A. No. 10-5952 : v. : : City of Philadelphia, et al., : Defendants : PLAINTIFFS EIGHTH

More information

Combining Behavioral and Structural Predictors of Violent Civil Conflict: Getting Scholars and Policymakers to Talk to Each Other

Combining Behavioral and Structural Predictors of Violent Civil Conflict: Getting Scholars and Policymakers to Talk to Each Other Combining Behavioral and Structural Predictors of Violent Civil Conflict: Getting Scholars and Policymakers to Talk to Each Other Douglas M Gibler October 1, 2015 Abstract This paper uses conflict narratives

More information

Does Poverty Cause Conflict? Isolating the Causal Origins of the Conflict Trap *

Does Poverty Cause Conflict? Isolating the Causal Origins of the Conflict Trap * Does Poverty Cause Conflict? Isolating the Causal Origins of the Conflict Trap * Conflict Management and Peace Science doi: 10.1177/0738894214559673 Alex Braithwaite (corresponding author) Associate Professor

More information

Do Civil Wars, Coups and Riots Have the Same Structural Determinants? *

Do Civil Wars, Coups and Riots Have the Same Structural Determinants? * Do Civil Wars, Coups and Riots Have the Same Structural Determinants? * Cristina Bodea Michigan State University Ibrahim Elbadawi Dubai Economic Council Christian Houle Michigan State University Accepted

More information

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware Working Paper No. 2004-03 Institutional Quality and Economic Growth: Maintenance of the

More information

Short- and Long-Term Effects of United Nations Peace Operations

Short- and Long-Term Effects of United Nations Peace Operations Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Short- and Long-Term Effects of United Nations Peace Operations Nicholas Sambanis In

More information

The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty

The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty American Journal of Engineering Research (AJER) 2017 American Journal of Engineering Research (AJER) e-issn: 2320-0847 p-issn : 2320-0936 Volume-6, Issue-12, pp-283-288 www.ajer.org Research Paper Open

More information

THE CAUSES, CONSEQUENCES, AND MANAGEMENT OF CIVIL WARS 030:178, Section 1

THE CAUSES, CONSEQUENCES, AND MANAGEMENT OF CIVIL WARS 030:178, Section 1 THE CAUSES, CONSEQUENCES, AND MANAGEMENT OF CIVIL WARS 030:178, Section 1 Professor Sara Mitchell Spring 2012 307 Schaeffer Hall 61 SH Office hours: Tuesday 10-11am, Wednesday 1:30-3:30pm TR 12:30pm-1:45pm

More information