Lost in Globalization

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Lost in Globalization"

Transcription

1 Lost in Globalization Economically Hurt or Culturally Threatened? Yotam M. Margalit Stanford University Prepared for Presentation at the Society for Comparative Research Yale University, May 2006 [DRAFT: Comments and corrections appreciated] Abstract A common assumption in the political economy literature holds that people s preferences on trade policy reflect the objective economic effects market openness has on them; those who gain from free trade support it, and those adversely affected by it oppose it. This paper studies the characteristics of the self-perceived losers from globalization and offers an alternative account that puts this assumption into question. I argue that many individuals view free trade as an inseparable component of a wider openness package, which also includes social and cultural dimensions. Peoples sense of loss from free trade therefore reflects, to a large extent, anxiety about non-economic cultural changes they associate with increased market openness. Using survey data from 44 countries, the paper offers an empirical test of the argument. The analysis also helps explain the oftenobserved anomaly of the support, by economic losers from free trade, of pro-trade yet socially conservative parties.

2 The representatives of the World Bank had better listen to us The World Bank and IMF and the transnationals must stop looting our natural resources, and stop privatizing basic services They must respect human life - Evo Morales, Bolivia s leading presidential candidate (November 2003) We need a president who will change the trade policy of this country. That s what I will do. And the folks who are 55 and 60 won t be losing their jobs to China and other countries around the world. - Richard Gephardt, Democratic Presidential Candidate Debate (October 2004). "It is wrong that our trade policies have caused 1 million good paying jobs to be shipped overseas because our companies can find cheaper labor and lower standards in another country." - John Edwards on the campaign trail (February 2004) What is the responsibility that American or European Markets have in keeping economies closed, in keeping a situation of hunger here in Brazil? - Fernando Enrique Cardoso, Brazil s President, (March 2000) "[Rich country s] approach is very simple. Should there be any new ideas in the social, economic or political field, they quickly come up with their own interpretations designed to benefit them. Thus we see them foisting on the world their moral values, political systems and economic globalization. Mahathir Mohammad, Malaysia s Prime Minister (April 2000) INTRODUCTION Economic globalization has increasingly become a high-profile political issue in many countries around the world. As the quotes above suggest, politicians identify the discontent of many voters with aspects of economic globalization and seek to seize upon this discontent to shore up political support. But, despite the growing salience of opposition to market openness as a political factor, there is very little that we actually know about the politics of the discontents. Who are those who view themselves as losing out from economic globalization 1? What aspects of it cause them to view themselves as such? How does the discontent translate into a political response? Existing literature on attitudes toward economic globalization - commonly taken to mean liberalization of markets, reduction of trade barriers, increased capital movement and foreign direct investments typically takes as a starting point the assumption that individuals are self-interested and that their support or opposition to increased market openness is a direct function of whether they stand to gain or to lose from it. Two central 1 Throughout the paper the terms economic globalization, economic openness, market openness and free trade policies are used interchangeably. 2

3 lines of argument are used in the political economic literature to explain attitudes towards market openness. The dominant approach holds that people s calculus is determined by their relative position in the labor market, i.e. whether the skill-set with which they are endowed stands to become more or less valuable in an open economy (e.g. Rogowski 1987, Irwin 1996, Scheve & Slaughter 2001). The more recent second approach holds that changes in individuals relative purchasing power shape their attitudes towards economic openness (Baker 2003, 2005). Importantly though, both lines of argument share the same underlying assumption, that attitudes towards economic openness ultimately reflect the objective economic conditions individuals are confronting. This paper questions the degree to which this assumption is useful when accounting for people s views on how trade openness affects them, especially of those who feel hard-done by it. I argue that in explaining people s sense of loss from economic globalization, the existing political economic theories offer limited insights. In contrast to the labor-market and consumption-based theories, this paper advances an alternative argument to explain people s belief that market openness is adversely affecting them. My argument holds that many individuals do not assess the economic effects of market openness independently of the non-economic effects they associate with the openness "package". The complex and all-encompassing nature of globalization means that, for many, attitudes toward trade are inseparably tied to views on other changes that come with openness, be they demographic, technological or cultural changes. Specifically, I contend that the selfperceived losers from economic globalization are, to a large degree, not those objectively hurt by it, but rather those who feel culturally threatened by the effects of openness to influences from other countries. Using recent cross-national survey data, the paper examines the degree to which the central arguments advanced in the literature on trade-policy preferences help account for who the self-perceived losers from economic globalization are. The analysis shows that both the factor-endowments model and the more recent consumption-based theory offer limited insight into the question at hand. In contrast, the cultural threat argument advanced in this paper is shown to carry significant empirical weight across all geographical regions: concerns about the effects of cultural openness play a large role in shaping people s sense of personal economic deterioration due to globalization. 3

4 In studying the characteristics and political views of the self-perceived losers of globalization (henceforth LOGs), this paper seeks to make three contributions 2. First, it offers an account of who the LOGs are in the different country settings. Second, it makes the case for a reconsideration of the assumptions underlying the study of trade policy preferences. Complementing the focus in the trade literature on changes in objective economic conditions relative position in the labor market, asset prices and purchasing power of consumers - the claim is made that individual perceptions of the economic effects of trade openness are largely driven by anxieties about the cultural changes associated with openness 3. The addition of this aspect to the analysis of trade preferences, the paper suggests, offers a more accurate account of the process by which people form attitudes. Lastly, the paper offers an insight into the variation in the political responses of the groups who are at the losing end of globalization. By arguing for the close relation in people s minds between the economic and the cultural effects of openness, the paper provides a framework for explaining the widely discussed anomaly whereby the losers of free trade often vote for parties that advocate pro-trade policies. It is important to emphasize that this paper, as well as the larger research project this paper is part of, is concerned with the self-perceived losers from economic globalization. Explaining someone s beliefs about the adverse effects free trade have had on her personally is not the same as explaining her support or opposition to free trade policies in general. As I later show, it is not uncommon for people to hold the view that free trade policies have benefited the country as a whole but adversely affected them personally, and vice versa. The analysis offered herein is therefore not an attempt to 2 Throughout the paper, the acronym LOGs refers to those who perceive themselves to be losing from economic globalization, not necessarily to those actually adversely affected by it. For the sake of convenience, I drop the self-perceived prefix when discussing the LOGs. 3 Important exceptions in the trade literature are the studies that use the ISSP dataset (O Rourke & Sinnott 2001, Rodrik & Mayda 2005), which find that measures of nationalism and patriotism are statistically significant predictors of attitudes towards trade. These studies, however, examine trade policy preferences rather than perceptions of personal economic gain or loss from free trade. The question used by both studies as the dependent variable is: Now we would like to ask a few questions about the relations between [respondent s country] and other countries. How much do you agree or disagree with the following statement: [respondent s country] should limit the import of foreign products in order to protect its national economy?. Note that this question is very different from the issue examined in this paper, which centers on individual s personal beliefs about how they and their families have been affected by economic openness. In another paper, Magaloni and Romero (2004) study cross-national attitudes variation in Latin American countries and find that partisan predispositions are significantly associated with individuals support or opposition to aspects of globalization. 4

5 confirm or disconfirm the validity of the existing trade-preference theories, which seek to explain variation in mass attitudes on trade policy. Rather, these theories are employed in order to examine the degree to which they help account for the specific phenomenon of discontent and sense of hurt caused by economic openness policies. The paper proceeds as follows. I start with a review of the literature on economic globalization and its losers. Section Two lays out my argument, as well as a set of alternative hypotheses, on the question who are the self-perceived losers of economic globalization. Section Three describes the data used to test these hypotheses and discusses measurement issues. Section Four describes the results of the empirical analysis. A discussion of the main argument of the paper then ensues: to what extent do views on cultural openness inform individuals' interpretation of the changing economic reality? Section Five situates the paper in the context of the larger project of the dissertation and concludes. I. GLOBALIZATION AND ITS LOSERS IN THE LITERATURE In recent years the debate over globalization and its effects has generated a vast literature. Debates on globalization-related topics range from whether it benefits the poor or not (e.g. Bhagwati 2001, Wolf 2004), through the role of international institutions in a globalizing economy (Rodrik 1997, Stiglitz 2000), to the extent to which globalization affects the role of the nation state as the key political unit (Ohmae 1990, Strange 1996). In this expansive literature, however, one cannot find any systematic account of globalization s discontents: who they are, why the view themselves as such, or how does the sense of losing out translate into a political response. Instead, the discussion concerning globalization s losers is often reduced to references to the anti-wto riots in Seattle and Genoa, or some mention of a potential backlash that could come about as the process of market integration expands. This section outlines the key insights the extant literature does offer on the characteristics of globalization s losers and on the political implications of their discontent. An important strand in the study of international trade seeks to explain the trade policies governments adopt over time. Initial arguments linked trade policies to larger theories of power and international conflict (e.g. Krasner 1976, Katzenstein 1985, Gilpin 5

6 1987,). More recently, directed by the view that government policies reflect the preferences of the electorate, attempts have been made to explain and predict individual attitudes on trade. This literature predominantly utilizes two international trade theories based on the notion of relative advantage and applies them to account for variation in individual preferences on trade openness. Each theory has well-defined implications regarding the distributive consequences of trade, and therefore offers clear hypotheses also on the question of who the losers from market openness are. If indeed the individuals that view themselves as losing out from market openness are also those that actually are worse off because of it, these theories could offer valuable insights regarding the composition and characteristics of the self-perceived losers. The most commonly used model in the trade preferences literature is the Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) factors-endowment model. In most of its recent applications, countries are categorized as either skill-abundant or skill-scarce based on their supply of skilled workers relative to other countries 4. Openness of the market to international trade, according to the H-O model, brings a country to export goods whose production is intensive in its abundant factor while importing goods that are intensive in its relatively scarce factor. This logic therefore suggests that the relative losers from market openness are the unskilled in the skill-abundant countries and the skilled labor in the skill-scarce countries. Indeed, a wide range of empirical work has found evidence supporting aspects of the theory, through examination of historical accounts of political alliances and voting records (Rogowski 1987, 1989; Beaulieu 1996, Hiscox 2002), as well in analyses in the individual level through survey responses (Scheve and Slaughter 2001, 2004; O Rourke and Sinnott 2002; Rodrik and Mayda 2005) 5. However, arguments derived from the H-O model have struggled to account for certain empirical regularities, most notably the fact that cross-national survey work has 4 The original version of the H-O model focuses on capital and labor as the factors of production. Later modifications to the model include land and a division of the labor category to skilled and unskilled labor. 5 Some have argued that the H-O logic holds in the long-run analysis, but due to the immobility of certain production factors, the key cleavage along which support and opposition to trade lies in the short-run is the industry of employment. This specific-factors approach, often referred to as Ricardo-Viner (R-V) model, suggests that the losers of economic openness are first and foremost those working in the import-sensitive industries (Magee 1978, Irwin 1998). This approach has shown to be of little explanatory use when examined as a predictor of mass attitudes on free trade (Scheve & Slaughter 2001, Mayda & Rodrick 2005). 6

7 shown little evidence of a negative relationship between skill-level and pro-trade attitudes as a function of the country s relative skill-abundance. In fact, higher-skilled individuals are consistently found to be more in favor of free trade than their less-skilled counterparts almost everywhere, regardless of the relative skill-abundance in their respective economies. A more recent theoretical approach attempts to address this unexplained regularity, as well as others, by arguing that attitudes on trade reflect individuals interests as consumers (Baker, 2003, 2005). Consistent with the H-O logic described above, prices of a country s exportable goods rise with freer trade, while prices of the importable goods decrease. The purchasing power, or real wage, of heavy consumers of importable goods thus increases with free trade, while heavy consumers of exportable goods experience a relative loss. Since the poor have to expend a greater share of their income on necessities that are unskilled-intensive (e.g. food, clothes) and the wealthy have the highest rate of saving, the middle-class are, in relative terms, the key consumers of skill-intensive goods. The consumer-based theory of trade preferences thus holds that the relative losers of free trade are the heavy consumers of exportables, whom are the poor in skill scarce countries and the middle-class in the skill-abundant ones. The economic of happiness literature, which examines the relation between individuals economic standing and their subjective well being, offers insights on the sources of beliefs about economic loss (e.g. Easterlin 1995, 2001; Alesina et al 2002). This literature finds that the economic determinants of happiness are similar in countries that differ significantly in their level of economic development: income, age, or unemployment are strongly associated with reported levels of well-being in all countries. Graham and Pettinato (2001, 2002) analyze data from Russia and Peru, two countries that have experienced difficult market liberalization transitions, and find that relative income differences and volatility in income flows are two of the most important sources for people s economic grievances. Their analysis suggests that those in the middle or lower middle of the income distribution are more likely to be dissatisfied than are the very poorest groups. Another body of work this paper ties into is the literature on economic voting, which addresses the question of the extent to which people s vote is driven by an 7

8 economic rationale. Whereas some scholars claim to find an economic vote function (Fiorina 1981; Kramer 1983, Lewis-Beck 1988), cross-national analyses have failed to find a strong link between electoral and economic outcomes (e.g. Cheibub and Przeworski 1999). This debate has sparked research on the way people process and integrate economic data into their voting decisions, with significant work dedicated to exploring the rationality of individuals economic judgments (e.g. Rabin 1998, Caplan 2001). Well-documented deviations in individual behavior from rational expected utility calculus were a basis for constructivist accounts that focused on norms, ideas and ideology as important sources shaping economic beliefs and interests (e.g. Katzenstein 1996, Blyth 2002, Herrera 2005). The argument advanced in this paper speaks directly to such constructivist accounts, however two important distinctions need to be emphasized. First, my argument does not question the fact that objective economic conditions matter greatly in shaping people s beliefs about economic issues. This paper, in no way, is advancing the claim that all beliefs about the economy are imagined or socially-constructed. Second, unlike constructivist accounts, the argument advanced here does not suggest that context or shared understandings are what shape perceptions of economic self-interest. Rather, my contention is that due to insufficient information or lacking the cognitive skills needed to disentangle the different effects of globalization, individuals that are aggrieved by certain non-economic aspects of openness (mis)perceive themselves to be worse off from its economic aspects too. In simpler terms, perceived loss from cultural openness is translated to a perception of loss also from economic openness. It is to the task of making this point that I now turn. II. HYPOTHESES Who are the self-perceived losers? There is wide agreement that the benefits of globalization are unequally distributed. Clearly, some countries and some groups of individuals have gained tremendously from the increased integration of previously distinct economies and societies. Others, however, have been adversely affected by the changing economic environment, whether in absolute or in relative terms. Economic globalization has made many insecure about their 8

9 occupation prospects; some have seen their real income shrink, and yet others have grown to feel increasingly inadequate in face of the new skill demands of the globalizing market. Indeed, the difficult processes different countries are undergoing of adaptation to the changing market environment have generated many potential sources for discontent and anxiety. But of those potential sources of discontent, which ones actually matter, and to what extent do they vary across countries with different economic conditions? Figure 1 gives a rough indication of the variation in the size of the self-perceived losing group in different countries. It is evident that the size of the group varies significantly across countries, with as low as 5.6% in the UK, and rising up to 28% in Argentina. In Kenya (not shown the chart) this figure stands at 65%. What accounts for this variation? An intuitive explanation might be that the sizes of the losing group reflect the varying types of shocks different economies have undergone as a result of integration into world markets. Less developed countries that face greater barriers in adapting to a competitive global economy are, one might expect, likely to have a larger sector identifying itself as worse off from market openness. On the other hand, concerns unique to higher income states such as immigration, job loss from outsourcing of production to cheaper markets, and lowering of labor standards, might generate even wider levels of discontent in developed countries. % LOGS in Country % of total population ARG BRZ BUL EGY IND ITA LEB MEX PHI POL SAF TAN UK USA Figure 1. Categorization of LOGs is based on response to the question: Now thinking about you and your family do you think the growing trade and business ties between our country and other countries are very good, somewhat good, somewhat bad or very bad for you and your family? LOGs are those that answered the question with a somewhat bad or very bad response. 9

10 The data however does not support either argument. The correlation between a county s trade openness and the size of the LOG group is low (-0.04) 6. So is the correlation between the country s economic development and the size of its LOG group, (-0.09). In other words, the economic indicators of development and openness do not stand in a direct relation with the extent of discontent towards free trade. If so, what does account for variation in levels of discontent, and to what extent do the self-perceived losers in the different countries share similar characteristics? This section lays out a set of hypotheses to address this question. Starting with hypotheses derived from the major arguments in the literature on trade preferences, I then lay out my cultural protectionism theory of attitudes on economic openness. Lastly, two alternative explanations are offered. The relative strength of the theories is then examined in the empirical section Existing IPE Models 1. Relative Position in the Labor Market Hypotheses The dominant Heckscher-Ohlin theory, which closely follows the logic of the Stolper- Samulason theorem (1941), holds that the key determinant of individual attitudes on trade is the employable assets they have, i.e. the skill type they possess: those endowed with a relatively abundant skill will benefit from opening the economy while owners of a scarce skill will experience a decline in their relative standing in the labor market. If this logic indeed captures the way people form their views on how economic openness affects them, then LOGs could be predicted by their skill-type: H1.1. LOGs are those with factor-endowments that are in relative scarceness in their own country. In economies with relative scarcity of unskilled (skilled) labor, LOGs will predominantly be the unskilled (skilled). A second hypothesis relates to the core argument of both the factor-endowment (H-O) and the factor-specific (R-V) models discussed earlier. The argument is that people s attitudes on free trade are first and foremost a function of their perceptions of how it affects the labor market. The H-O model suggests that the employable skills of the individuals will determine their views on the impact of economic openness on their occupation prospects; R-V holds that the industry of employment, not the employable 6 Trade openness is calculated as the sum of a country s exports and imports as percentage of its GDP. 10

11 skills, will have the main influence on individuals views. Either way, the logic is that attitudes on market openness are driven by a self-interested calculation of whether one s prospects in the labor market are improving or worsening as a result of free trade. The implication of this logic is therefore: H1.2. LOGs are those with a strong sense of deterioration in occupation prospects and increased job insecurity. 2. The Consumption Based Hypothesis An alternative approach to account for attitudes on trade openness shifts the emphasis from individuals role as participants in the labor market to their role as consumers of goods. In brief, the logic goes as follows: Since protectionist trade policy raises the prices of tradable goods, the general consumer public is, in effect, made to pay for the economic rents with which the closed economy provides the protected sectors. Economic globalization drives down the prices of imports while raising the prices of exportable goods. This change in prices directly affects the purchasing power of consumers: it increases for heavy consumers of importable goods and decreases for consumers of exportable goods. The relative losers are therefore consumers of the exportable goods. Since the main consumers of unskilled-intensive goods, in relative terms, are the poor, while the middle-class are the heaviest consumers of skill-intensive goods (as a share of their incomes), the predictions of the consumption-based hypothesis can be summarized as follows: H2. The LOGs are consumers whose purchasing power has diminished. These consumers are disproportionately the poor in skill-scarce countries and the middle class in skillabundant countries. In substantive terms, the expectation is that perceptions of loss from free trade will be in negative relation with income, but that the interaction of income and skill-abundance in a country will be positively correlated with a negative view of free trade. Cultural Protectionism Theory The effects of globalization are dramatic and all encompassing. Cheap imports, enormous variety of products on the shelves, internet, off-shoring of production to markets abroad, growing presence of multi-national corporations, waves of immigration and emigration, 11

12 satellite dishes beaming broadcasts from around the world, unprecedented levels of international travel, etc. are the tip of an iceberg. To what extent are individuals able to disentangle the effects of this complex package of changes and processes that goes under the name 'globalization and assess a specific component of it - trade openness - independently of all its other components? The answer I propose to this question is that many people are not able to do this. I argue that because the effects of increased openness between countries are so intertwined, dramatic and complex, existing theories of individual attitudes to trade rely on an improbable assumption when they posit that people s views on trade directly reflect their calculations of personal economic gain and loss. I contend that, by divorcing the noneconomic aspects of openness from the study of attitudes toward trade, these theories miss an important part of the story. My argument is that the changes brought about by economic globalization are viewed by many as synonymous with other changes such secularization or Americanization. To be sure, many do not view the other changes as negative and associate them rather with development and progress. For others, however, the changes they associate with free trade are a source of uncertainty and anxiety, which translate into a negative view of the openness package' as a whole. Opposition to economic openness thus often reflects concerns about non-economic changes such as a perceived weakening of traditional family structures, secularization, emigration of the young, women in the workplace, etc. Such apprehension about the effects of these wider processes of openness, I conjecture, develops into beliefs about the detrimental effects of economic openness and leads many to believe that free markets adversely affect them 7. This argument suggests that much of the trade-preferences literature makes problematic assumptions about the level of economic knowledge and sophistication among the general population. For example, the often-used working assumption according to which individuals know with certainty the effects of trade policies on 7 The empirical section of the paper offers some data supporting the plausibility of this argument, although to detail the mechanism of this process convincingly is beyond the scope of this paper. In my dissertation I seek to show the causal link between fear of the effects of cultural openness on the one hand and beliefs about economic loss from trade openness on the other. To this end, I am currently working on an experiment that tests for the degree to which exposure to cultural concerns associated with openness affects individuals views on how trade openness affects them. Any suggestions for additional ways to test this presumed link would be greatly appreciated. 12

13 individual incomes and assets holdings (Scheve & Slaughter, 2001), or statements like voters may see trade liberalization as a remedy to high prices (Baker 2005), may offer reassuring tractability in the modeling of individuals preferences. However, they seem descriptively implausible in light of the extensively documented literature about people's knowledge about and judgments on economic issues (Blendon et al 1997, Dahl and Random 1999, Caplan 2001) 8. My expectation is that economic variables account for only a limited part of the variation in individual attitudes with regard to how economic openness affects them. Instead, I conjecture that people s concern with the social and cultural changes associated with foreign influences are the source of much of the apprehension from the perceived effects of free trade. The camp of self-perceived losers from economic openness, I argue, includes many who in objective terms have not lost economically from free trade (some may have even gained) but who associate economic openness with other processes which they feel affect them adversely. The implication of this argument in the political context is straightforward. The scholarly literature on the political implications of free trade has until now assumed a clear-cut division between those who benefit economically from free trade and those who do not (Rogowski 1987, Frieden 1991, Hiscox 2002). The theory presented here, in contrast, offers a framework to explain how free trade can generate political cleavage that is predicated on cultural elements. Approaches to Modeling the Cleavages Created by Market Openness Economic Impact of Openness Economic Impact of Openness Negative ~ Negative Negative ~ Negative Social-cultural Impact of Openness Negative ~Negative Figure 2 Existing PE Models Cultural Protectionism Approach 8 No doubt, the authors utilizing such assumptions are well aware of these assumptions limited descriptive accuracy. The issue then is ultimately the degree to which these assumptions serve as the tools in accounting for individual preferences. 13

14 The shadowed boxes in Figure 2 represent the potential pool of self-perceived economic losers. Note that in the figure on the left, the shadowed box includes only those adversely affected by the economic changes that come with openness. The figure on the right presents the division implied by the theory of this paper. Namely, the losers camp includes a larger potential pool of disaffected individuals: not only those objectively worse off because of trade openness but also those who feel culturally threatened by the changes associated with openness and who thus come to believe that trade openness as such is bad for them. Of course, the theory does not predict that all those culturally threatened by openness necessarily believe that freer trade is bad for them, but rather that there is a significant group to which this argument does apply. Relying on Prospect Theory s notion that losses loom larger than gains (Kahneman and Tversky 1979, 1984), my argument suggests that individuals whom openness has made better off in one dimension (economic or cultural) and worse off in the other, will tend to view themselves as overall losing out from the openness process 9. We should not expect therefore to encounter many instances where individuals who benefit from changes in the cultural dimension but lose in the economic dimension describing themselves as better off from free trade 10. The theory proposed here emphasizes that low levels of information, or lack of necessary analytical tools, are keys to explaining people s tendency to assess the different effects of globalization as a single bundle rather than to analyze them separately. Greater understanding of economic issues and higher cognitive skills are thus likely to lessen this tendency. I therefore expect that - holding all else equal - individuals with lower levels of education are more likely to associate cultural anxieties about openness with a sense of loss from economic openness, than individuals with similar levels of cultural anxieties 9 Obviously, in extreme cases where the gains in one dimension are so tremendous they may well trump small losses in the other dimension. But the theory holds that in cases where gain and loss are in the same range, losses will indeed loom larger. 10 A question this argument raises is whether the process described above operates also in the other direction, namely does economic loss translate into beliefs also about cultural loss? My sense is that this process is happening too, in significant levels, however demonstrating it empirically is difficult since there are no clear measures of objective cultural threat or loss. It is therefore very difficult to show that one s negative perception of the cultural effects of openness is unmerited and caused by something else such as economic loss. Panel data that tracks over time the economic performance of individuals as well as their changing beliefs about social and cultural issues would be an effective way of testing for the existence of such a relationship. It is something I hope to address in greater depth in the dissertation. 14

15 but with higher levels of education. The theory therefore makes the following two predictions: H3. Individuals' sense of losing out from trade openness is often driven not by an assessment of its objective economic effects, but rather by feelings of being threatened by cultural openness to foreign influences. H3.2 The tendency to form attitudes on the effects of free trade that reflect attitudes towards cultural openness is a function of one s available analytical tools. Ceteris paribus, lower levels of education will tend to correlate with the bundling of economic and cultural effects of openness. Alternative Explanations In addition to the extant trade-preferences theories in the literature and the one proposed in this paper, I examine two alternative arguments that seem plausible in explaining subjective assessments of economic loss. The first approach centers on individuals economic standing - absolute as well as relative in accounting beliefs about trade. The second approach assumed that a sense of being adversely affected by economic openness reflects a wider, and unrelated, dissatisfaction in life. 4. Personal Economic Standing Hypotheses An argument advanced in the economics of happiness literature holds that those perceiving themselves to be worse off economically are not those with the lowest earnings but rather those most discontent with their relative economic position, whether as a result of increasing income inequalities in the country or a prevailing perception of social immobility (e.g. Graham & Pettinato 2002). Subjective reports of economic dissatisfaction may thus correspond well with beliefs about the effects of economic openness. A plausible alternative could be that the sense of losing out from economic globalization is a straightforward outcome of financial struggle, regardless of whether it is caused by trade openness or not. If one s economic situation is bleak, goes this argument, any process associated with the country s economy may be considered to have had an adverse effect on the individual s personal standing. The predictions of these two arguments can be summarized as follows: 15

16 H4.1 Individuals that view market openness as bad for them are those most discontent with their relative economic standing. H4.2 Individuals that view market openness as bad for them are people that are economically struggling. In other words, LOGs are the poor. 5. General Dissatisfaction with Life Hypotheses The classification of LOGs used in the empirical section of this paper focuses on individual s own assessment of how increased market openness has affected them; it does not rely on an objective measure of loss by the individual. A possible conjecture might be that the self-perceived losers from globalization are simply the kvetchers, i.e. those that are generally discontent with life and that respond to a survey saying they are worse off because of free trade, just as they would about anything else being considered in the survey. In examining this argument, I distinguish between two types of discontents: First, those who have a very negative assessment of their current situation in life; second, those who feel that their personal situation has severely deteriorated over the past several years. The logic underlying these hypotheses is that for both types of discontents increased market openness is guilty by association, i.e. it is viewed as detrimental regardless of whether it actually had a negative effect on the respondent or not. H5.1 The LOGs are those most discontent with their current situation in life. H5.2 The LOGs are those who view their lives as having significantly worsened over recent years. In sum, the hypotheses outlined above can be described as falling into three types of explanations: (1) Hypotheses conforming to the main trade-theory models in the literature (H1 & H2); (2) Hypotheses based on the notion that dissatisfaction (with life in general or with one s personal economic standing) translates into a negative view of any precipitator of change, in this case free trade (H4 & H5) (3) The paper s main argument, namely that concern and anxiety about cultural changes associated with openness generate beliefs about the detrimental effects of trade openness (H3). In the following sections the hypotheses outlined above are tested empirically. I begin by describing the cross-national survey data utilized in the empirical analysis, and then move on to discuss the variables used to operationalize each of the hypotheses. 16

17 III. THE DATA & EMPIRICAL APPROACH The analysis in the paper is based on data from the Pew Global Attitudes Project. The data is comprised of 44 national surveys carried out in five continents during the year The surveys were all conducted in the native language by leading local polling firms, interviewing a representative sample of the population. The sample size ranges from 500 (e.g. Slovak Republic) to 3000 (China). Overall, the dataset consists of 38,263 survey responses 12. In almost all countries the exact same set of questions was asked, though in several cases certain questions had to be omitted (this applies mostly to China and Egypt). This dataset is uniquely suited for the purposes of this research since the survey includes questions about the perceived effects of free trade on the respondent herself, rather than questions about the respondent s general attitude on free trade policies, as is the case with other cross-national surveys. The dependent variable used in the analysis is based on a respondent s answer to the question Now thinking about you and your family do you think the growing trade and business ties between our country and other countries are very good, somewhat good, somewhat bad or very bad for you and your family? 13 The exact same question was asked also about the effects of trade and business ties on the respondents country, rather than on their family. The answers to the two questions indicate that respondents were clear-minded about the difference in the questions emphases, as responses often diverged: In fact, a majority (59.5%) of those who answer that growing trade and business ties were bad for them and their family believe that free trade is good for the country as a whole. The opposite figure is much 11 See appendix for complete list of countries. 12 Approximately 91% of the respondents answered the question on the effects of trade openness on themselves and their family. This reduced the total number of survey responses to 34,725. To avoid losing additional observations, missing observations were imputed for income (8.6% of observations), age and education (0.7% each). Imputation was done for each country separately, using Amelia (King et al, 2001). Results were unchanged for all variables when running the regressions with and without the imputed observations. 13 For example, the dependent variable used in Scheve and Slaughter s (2004) study on individual trade preferences is based on the following question in the NES Surveys of 1992 and 1996: Some people have suggested placing new limits on foreign imports in order to protect American jobs. Others say that such limits would raise consumer prices and hurt American exports. Do you favor or oppose placing new limits on imports, or haven t you though much about this? Clearly, such a question taps into a different issue from the one examined in this paper, namely individuals sense of how trade openness affects their family and them personally. 17

18 lower: only 6.4% of those who believe that they themselves benefit from growing trade openness think that it negatively affects their country. To test Hypothesis 1, namely the Heckscher-Ohlin factor-endowment argument, I use education level as a proxy for respondent s skill-type. This is a common assumption in much of the trade literature 14. The categorization is based on the highest level of education attained, and the categories are: 1. No formal education; 2. Completed primary education; 3. Some secondary education; 4. Completed high school; 5. Some university or college education; 6. Completed university or college degree. The factor-endowment argument holds that a survey respondent that completed his high school education in a skill-scarce country, say Bolivia, has a very different standing in the local labor market than a high-school-graduate in a skill-abundant country, say Germany. To account for the effect of skill as a function of the relative standing in the market I also include an interaction term of individual skill and the country s skill endowment. Measurement of a country s skill-endowment is problematic due to lack of comparable cross-national data. Even the most commonly used datasets measuring crossnational formal education attainment are partial and rely on extensive extrapolations (Barro and Lee, 2003). I therefore use the natural log of a country s per capita GDP as a proxy for a country s skill-abundance. The interaction term of skill and skill-abundance is represented with the Education X GDP per capita variable. As noted earlier, the arguments inspired by the H-O model focus on risk exposure in the labor market as the dominant source of attitudes on free trade. However, operationalizing the level of risk exposure in the labor market is problematic for several reasons. First, measuring accurately what industries in a given country have gained or lost is a difficult task that produces a lot of measurement noise. This in turn renders the exercise of identifying the workers in the losing industries highly problematic 15. Second, the occupation classifications in the surveys used in the paper are not specific enough to be able to get at an accurate measure of the industry effect. In order to get around these 14 For recent examples see Scheve & Slaughter 2002, Rodrik & Mayda Use of rough measures of growing or declining industries would not capture the variation in individuals changing standing in the labor market. For example, the significant variation in success of firms within an industry, or changes in production methods most notably in agriculture - that affect individuals job security would not be picked up by the categorization of the industry. 18

19 problems, I use a more direct measure of respondents assessments of changes in the job market. In addition, I include employment status data in the regression as another control. The variable Job availability is coded using the following question: Has each of the following gotten better or worse over the last five years in our country: The availability of good-paying jobs? (0 = Worse, 1= Not Changed 2= Better) 16. The employment status dummy variables are: (i) Self-employed; (ii) Part-time (iii) Unemployed, (iv) Pensioner; (v) Not employed (e.g. housewives, students, disabled). To test my argument that the sense of economic loss from free trade is derived from concern with or anxiety about non-economic (social-cultural) changes associated with openness, I code the Foreign Cultural Influence variable using the response to the survey question: Do you think that having the opportunity to watch movies and TV and listen to music from different parts of the world is very good, somewhat good, somewhat bad or very bad for you and your family? (Coded on a scale from 1-4, with 1 being very good and 4 very bad ) The two pocket-book hypotheses (H4.1 & H4.2) advance the logic that financial struggle leads respondents to view economic openness as having had an adverse effect on them personally, regardless of whether it actually had or not. To test these hypotheses, I include two variables in the analysis: the relative household income of respondents, and their subjective assessment of their economic standing. Income is measured by the question Here is a list of incomes. Which of these does your household fall into counting all wages, salaries, pensions and other incomes that come in? Just give the letter of the group your household falls into, before taxes and other deductions. Since the focus here is with one s relative income compared to that of others in the country, respondents in each country were divided into five income quintiles (5 denoting the highest earners). The second income-related variable is Economic Satisfaction. Measurement of the variable is based on the response to the question: How satisfied are 16 This question is problematic in that it is double barreled; in theory, one can interpret the question to be asking about job availability in general, while another might understand the emphasis of the question to be on good paying jobs. This leads to some difficulty in interpreting the meaning of the response. Nonetheless, the correlation of responses to the question with those to related questions on employment status and on satisfaction in the workplace suggests that this proxy does capture an important variation in individuals perceived prospects in the labor-market. 19

20 you with your household income? (1. Very dissatisfied; 2.Somewhat dissatisfied; 3. Somewhat satisfied; 4 Very satisfied) The final two hypotheses link general discontent in life to views on economic globalization. H5.1 emphasizes respondents view of their current state, and H5.2 focuses on respondents sense of deterioration, i.e. of a negative change to their lives. The following measures are used to test these two arguments: Current State is coded on a scale of 1 to 10, using the following question: Here is a ladder representing the ladder of life. Let's suppose the top of the ladder represents the best possible life for you; and the bottom, the worst possible life for you. On which step of the ladder do you feel you personally stand at the present time? (1-10) 17. Five Year Change is based on the question asking the respondent to rate her personal situation five years ago on the same ten-scale ladder of life : On which step would you say you stood five years ago? The coding of Five Year Change is then obtained by subtracting the ladder today rating from the response to the question about five years ago: Five Year Change= [(ladder five years ago) (ladder today)]. This means that the higher the score of Five Year Change, the bigger the perceived deterioration in one s life. Additional independent variables. In addition to the variables outlined above, the literature gives reason to include several additional control variables in the analysis. Age of the respondent is included since older people may find it more difficult to adjust to new skill requirements in the labor market (Tucker, Pacek and Berinskiy 2002). Studies of attitudes to free trade have repeatedly found gender gaps in respondents preferred level of protectionism. Possibly due to child-birth and child rearing considerations that affect their prospects in the labor market, women tend to be more apprehensive about free market economic policies (Burgoon and Hiscox 2003). A dummy variable for Female is therefore included. Measure of Religiosity is also controlled for, though omitted in the final models due to a large number of missing observations. I therefore conducted separate tests of the model for countries where data on religiosity was available. Results are reported in the appendix. Lastly, a variable measuring Nationalist Sentiment is 17 Emphasis appears in the original survey question. 20

Commerce & Oppositions

Commerce & Oppositions Commerce & Oppositions The Political Responses of Globalization s Losers Yotam Margalit Department of Political Science Stanford Univesity ymargalit@stanford.edu Abstract The integration of markets has

More information

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization 3 Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization Given the evidence presented in chapter 2 on preferences about globalization policies, an important question to explore is whether any opinion cleavages

More information

ATTITUDES TOWARDS IMMIGRATION: ECONOMIC VERSUS CULTURAL DETERMINANTS. EVIDENCE FROM THE 2011 TRANSATLANTIC TRENDS IMMIGRATION DATA

ATTITUDES TOWARDS IMMIGRATION: ECONOMIC VERSUS CULTURAL DETERMINANTS. EVIDENCE FROM THE 2011 TRANSATLANTIC TRENDS IMMIGRATION DATA ATTITUDES TOWARDS IMMIGRATION: ECONOMIC VERSUS CULTURAL DETERMINANTS. EVIDENCE FROM THE 2011 TRANSATLANTIC TRENDS IMMIGRATION DATA A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences

More information

Individual Attitudes Toward Free Trade Beyond the Economics Alina Zheng

Individual Attitudes Toward Free Trade Beyond the Economics Alina Zheng Individual Attitudes Toward Free Trade Beyond the Economics Alina Zheng INTRODUCTION Understanding voters attitudes toward international free trade is essential to understanding the origins of trade policy

More information

Public opinion regarding economic and cultural globalization: evidence from a cross-national survey

Public opinion regarding economic and cultural globalization: evidence from a cross-national survey Review of International Political Economy 13:4 October 2006: 587 608 Public opinion regarding economic and cultural globalization: evidence from a cross-national survey Martin S. Edwards John C. Whitehead

More information

Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration?

Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2855 Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration? Anna Maria Mayda June 2007 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Why Are People

More information

Can attitudes towards globalization be explained by who perceive themselves to be losers from trade?

Can attitudes towards globalization be explained by who perceive themselves to be losers from trade? Can attitudes towards globalization be explained by who perceive themselves to be losers from trade? Lund University School of Economics and Management Department of Economics Bachelor thesis Authors:

More information

Heckscher-Ohlin Theory and Individual Attitudes Towards Globalization. Kevin H. O Rourke. Department of Economics and IIIS. Trinity College Dublin

Heckscher-Ohlin Theory and Individual Attitudes Towards Globalization. Kevin H. O Rourke. Department of Economics and IIIS. Trinity College Dublin Heckscher-Ohlin Theory and Individual Attitudes Towards Globalization Kevin H. O Rourke Department of Economics and IIIS Trinity College Dublin March 2004 This paper was in part written while the author

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY AND INDIVIDUAL ATTITUDES TOWARDS GLOBALIZATION. Kevin H. O Rourke

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY AND INDIVIDUAL ATTITUDES TOWARDS GLOBALIZATION. Kevin H. O Rourke NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY AND INDIVIDUAL ATTITUDES TOWARDS GLOBALIZATION Kevin H. O Rourke Working Paper 9872 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9872 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

Globalisation and Open Markets

Globalisation and Open Markets Wolfgang LEHMACHER Globalisation and Open Markets July 2009 What is Globalisation? Globalisation is a process of increasing global integration, which has had a large number of positive effects for nations

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS microreport# 117 SEPTEMBER 2008 This publication was produced for review by the United States Agency for International Development. It

More information

Why are people more pro-trade than pro-migration?

Why are people more pro-trade than pro-migration? Discussion Paper Series CDP No 11/06 Why are people more pro-trade than pro-migration? Anna Maria Mayda Centre for Research and Analysis of Migration Department of Economics, University College London

More information

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter Organization Introduction The Specific Factors Model International Trade in the Specific Factors Model Income Distribution and the Gains from

More information

Risk, Government and Globalization: International Survey Evidence

Risk, Government and Globalization: International Survey Evidence Risk, Government and Globalization: International Survey Evidence Anna Maria Mayda, Georgetown University Kevin H. O Rourke, Trinity College Dublin Richard Sinnott, University College Dublin July 2006

More information

Free Trade Producers, Protectionist Consumers? Evidence from A Survey Experiment in Japan

Free Trade Producers, Protectionist Consumers? Evidence from A Survey Experiment in Japan Free Trade Producers, Protectionist Consumers? Evidence from A Survey Experiment in Japan Megumi Naoi Assistant Professor, University of California, San Diego Ikuo Kume Professor, Waseda University How

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

NAZI VICTIMS NOW RESIDING IN THE UNITED STATES: FINDINGS FROM THE NATIONAL JEWISH POPULATION SURVEY A UNITED JEWISH COMMUNITIES REPORT

NAZI VICTIMS NOW RESIDING IN THE UNITED STATES: FINDINGS FROM THE NATIONAL JEWISH POPULATION SURVEY A UNITED JEWISH COMMUNITIES REPORT NAZI VICTIMS NOW RESIDING IN THE UNITED STATES: FINDINGS FROM THE NATIONAL JEWISH POPULATION SURVEY 2000-01 A UNITED JEWISH COMMUNITIES REPORT December, 2003 INTRODUCTION This April marked the fifty-eighth

More information

Risk, Government and Globalization: International Survey Evidence 1

Risk, Government and Globalization: International Survey Evidence 1 Risk, Government and Globalization: International Survey Evidence 1 Anna Maria Mayda, Georgetown University Kevin H. O Rourke, Trinity College Dublin Richard Sinnott, University College Dublin April 2007

More information

II. Roma Poverty and Welfare in Serbia and Montenegro

II. Roma Poverty and Welfare in Serbia and Montenegro II. Poverty and Welfare in Serbia and Montenegro 10. Poverty has many dimensions including income poverty and non-income poverty, with non-income poverty affecting for example an individual s education,

More information

IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU

IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU Browne Center for International Politics University of Pennsylvania QUESTION What explains

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Political Integration of Immigrants: Insights from Comparing to Stayers, Not Only to Natives. David Bartram

Political Integration of Immigrants: Insights from Comparing to Stayers, Not Only to Natives. David Bartram Political Integration of Immigrants: Insights from Comparing to Stayers, Not Only to Natives David Bartram Department of Sociology University of Leicester University Road Leicester LE1 7RH United Kingdom

More information

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Abstract: Growing income inequality and labor market polarization and increasing

More information

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa International Affairs Program Research Report How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa Report Prepared by Bilge Erten Assistant

More information

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets David Lam I. Introduction This paper discusses how demographic changes are affecting the labor force in emerging markets. As will be shown below, the

More information

BY Amy Mitchell, Katie Simmons, Katerina Eva Matsa and Laura Silver. FOR RELEASE JANUARY 11, 2018 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES:

BY Amy Mitchell, Katie Simmons, Katerina Eva Matsa and Laura Silver.  FOR RELEASE JANUARY 11, 2018 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES: FOR RELEASE JANUARY 11, 2018 BY Amy Mitchell, Katie Simmons, Katerina Eva Matsa and Laura Silver FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES: Amy Mitchell, Director, Journalism Research Katie Simmons, Associate Director,

More information

How s Life in Hungary?

How s Life in Hungary? How s Life in Hungary? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Hungary has a mixed performance across the different well-being dimensions. It has one of the lowest levels of household net adjusted

More information

In class, we have framed poverty in four different ways: poverty in terms of

In class, we have framed poverty in four different ways: poverty in terms of Sandra Yu In class, we have framed poverty in four different ways: poverty in terms of deviance, dependence, economic growth and capability, and political disenfranchisement. In this paper, I will focus

More information

WHAT EXPLAINS FIRM TRADE POLICY PREFERENCES?

WHAT EXPLAINS FIRM TRADE POLICY PREFERENCES? WHAT EXPLAINS FIRM TRADE POLICY PREFERENCES? A thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences of Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree

More information

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito The specific factors model allows trade to affect income distribution as in H-O model. Assumptions of the

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Trade, Populism and Public Opinion

Trade, Populism and Public Opinion COLLOQUIUM FALL 2017 Trade, Populism and Public Opinion By Cameron Ballard-Rosa, Assistant Professor of Political Science at the University of North Carolina; Judith Goldstein, Janet M. Peck Professor

More information

Open Trade, Closed Borders Immigration Policy in the Era of Globalization

Open Trade, Closed Borders Immigration Policy in the Era of Globalization Open Trade, Closed Borders Immigration Policy in the Era of Globalization Margaret E. Peters University of Wisconsin Madison November 9, 2011 Prepared for the 2011 Annual Conference of the International

More information

Persistent Inequality

Persistent Inequality Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives Ontario December 2018 Persistent Inequality Ontario s Colour-coded Labour Market Sheila Block and Grace-Edward Galabuzi www.policyalternatives.ca RESEARCH ANALYSIS

More information

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France No. 57 February 218 The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France Clément Malgouyres External Trade and Structural Policies Research Division This Rue

More information

Korea s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Korea s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses How s Life in Korea? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Korea s average performance across the different well-being dimensions is mixed. Although income and wealth stand below the OECD average,

More information

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016 Enormous growth in inequality Especially in US, and countries that have followed US model Multiple

More information

Gender attitudes in the world of work: cross-cultural comparison

Gender attitudes in the world of work: cross-cultural comparison Gender attitudes in the world of work: cross-cultural comparison Natalia Soboleva Junior research fellow Laboratory for comparative social research HSE nsoboleva@hse.ru the Third LCSR International Workshop

More information

How s Life in Germany?

How s Life in Germany? How s Life in Germany? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Germany performs well across most well-being dimensions. Household net adjusted disposable income is above the OECD average, but household

More information

How s Life in the United Kingdom?

How s Life in the United Kingdom? How s Life in the United Kingdom? November 2017 On average, the United Kingdom performs well across a number of well-being indicators relative to other OECD countries. At 74% in 2016, the employment rate

More information

Attitudes towards influx of immigrants in Korea

Attitudes towards influx of immigrants in Korea Volume 120 No. 6 2018, 4861-4872 ISSN: 1314-3395 (on-line version) url: http://www.acadpubl.eu/hub/ http://www.acadpubl.eu/hub/ Attitudes towards influx of immigrants in Korea Jungwhan Lee Department of

More information

How s Life in Mexico?

How s Life in Mexico? How s Life in Mexico? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Mexico has a mixed performance across the different well-being dimensions. At 61% in 2016, Mexico s employment rate was below the OECD

More information

Global Corruption Barometer 2010 New Zealand Results

Global Corruption Barometer 2010 New Zealand Results Global Corruption Barometer 2010 New Zealand Results Ben Krieble TINZ Summer Intern www.transparencynz.org.nz executive@transparency.org.nz Contents Executive Summary 3 Summary of global results 4 Summary

More information

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Chapter 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Preview Production possibilities Changing the mix of inputs Relationships among factor prices and goods prices, and resources and output Trade in

More information

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries? The University of Akron IdeaExchange@UAkron Honors Research Projects The Dr. Gary B. and Pamela S. Williams Honors College Spring 2019 Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries? Nicholas

More information

Rev. soc. polit., god. 25, br. 3, str , Zagreb 2018.

Rev. soc. polit., god. 25, br. 3, str , Zagreb 2018. doi: 10.3935/rsp.v25i3.1522 ESTIMATING LABOUR MARKET SLACK IN THE EUROPEAN UNION John Hurley and Valentina Patrini Dublin: Eurofound, 2017., 56 str. In the social policy and political discussions sufficient

More information

Does increasing the minimum wage reduce poverty in developing countries?

Does increasing the minimum wage reduce poverty in developing countries? T. H. GINDLING University of Maryland Baltimore County, USA, and IZA, Germany Does increasing the minimum wage reduce poverty in developing countries? Whether raising minimum wages reduces or increases

More information

Happiness and International Migration in Latin America

Happiness and International Migration in Latin America Chapter 5 Happiness and International Migration in Latin America 88 89 Carol Graham, Leo Pasvolsky Senior Fellow, The Brookings Institution; College Park Professor, University of Maryland Milena Nikolova,

More information

How s Life in Norway?

How s Life in Norway? How s Life in Norway? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Norway performs very well across the OECD s different well-being indicators and dimensions. Job strain and long-term unemployment are

More information

Italy s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Italy s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses How s Life in Italy? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Italy s average performance across the different well-being dimensions is mixed. The employment rate, about 57% in 2016, was among the

More information

Understanding who benefits from globalization, who is hurt by it, and who remains

Understanding who benefits from globalization, who is hurt by it, and who remains Political Science Research and Methods Vol 5, No. 1, 55 80 January 2017 The European Political Science Association, 2015 doi:10.1017/psrm.2015.64 Globalization and the Demand-Side of Politics: How Globalization

More information

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database. Knowledge for Development Ghana in Brief October 215 Poverty and Equity Global Practice Overview Poverty Reduction in Ghana Progress and Challenges A tale of success Ghana has posted a strong growth performance

More information

How s Life in France?

How s Life in France? How s Life in France? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, France s average performance across the different well-being dimensions is mixed. While household net adjusted disposable income stands

More information

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers. Executive summary Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers. In many ways, these are exciting times for Asia and the Pacific as a region. Dynamic growth and

More information

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform Political support for market-oriented economic reforms in Latin America has been,

More information

WORKING PAPERS ON POLITICAL SCIENCE

WORKING PAPERS ON POLITICAL SCIENCE Documentos de Trabajo en Ciencia Política WORKING PAPERS ON POLITICAL SCIENCE Judging the Economy in Hard-times: Myopia, Approval Ratings and the Mexican Economy, 1995-2000. By Beatriz Magaloni, ITAM WPPS

More information

Income, Deprivation, and Perceptions in Latin America and the Caribbean:

Income, Deprivation, and Perceptions in Latin America and the Caribbean: Income, Deprivation, and Perceptions in Latin America and the Caribbean: New Evidence from the Gallup World Poll Leonardo Gasparini* Walter Sosa Escudero** Mariana Marchionni* Sergio Olivieri* * CEDLAS

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients) Section 2 Impact of trade on income inequality As described above, it has been theoretically and empirically proved that the progress of globalization as represented by trade brings benefits in the form

More information

How s Life in Canada?

How s Life in Canada? How s Life in Canada? November 2017 Canada typically performs above the OECD average level across most of the different well-indicators shown below. It falls within the top tier of OECD countries on household

More information

Memo. Explaining the Rise of Populism

Memo. Explaining the Rise of Populism Memo To: Global Populism Conference Participants From: Cameron Ballard-Rosa, University of North Carolina Mashail Malik, Stanford University Stephanie Rickard, London School of Economics Kenneth Scheve,

More information

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View 1. Approximately how much of the world's output does the United States produce? A. 4 percent. B. 20 percent. C. 30 percent. D. 1.5 percent. The United States

More information

How s Life in Turkey?

How s Life in Turkey? How s Life in Turkey? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Turkey has a mixed performance across the different well-being dimensions. At 51% in 2016, the employment rate in Turkey is the lowest

More information

POLICY BRIEF. Assessing Labor Market Conditions in Madagascar: i. World Bank INSTAT. May Introduction & Summary

POLICY BRIEF. Assessing Labor Market Conditions in Madagascar: i. World Bank INSTAT. May Introduction & Summary World Bank POLICY INSTAT BRIEF May 2008 Assessing Labor Market Conditions in Madagascar: 2001-2005 i Introduction & Summary In a country like Madagascar where seven out of ten individuals live below the

More information

How s Life in Switzerland?

How s Life in Switzerland? How s Life in Switzerland? November 2017 On average, Switzerland performs well across the OECD s headline well-being indicators relative to other OECD countries. Average household net adjusted disposable

More information

Book Discussion: Worlds Apart

Book Discussion: Worlds Apart Book Discussion: Worlds Apart The Carnegie Endowment for International Peace September 28, 2005 The following summary was prepared by Kate Vyborny Junior Fellow, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace

More information

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Chapter 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Chapter Organization 1. Assumption 2. Domestic Market (1) Factor prices and goods prices (2) Factor levels and output levels 3. Trade in the Heckscher-Ohlin

More information

How s Life in Belgium?

How s Life in Belgium? How s Life in Belgium? November 2017 Relative to other countries, Belgium performs above or close to the OECD average across the different wellbeing dimensions. Household net adjusted disposable income

More information

Globalization: What Did We Miss?

Globalization: What Did We Miss? Globalization: What Did We Miss? Paul Krugman March 2018 Concerns about possible adverse effects from globalization aren t new. In particular, as U.S. income inequality began rising in the 1980s, many

More information

Labour market trends and prospects for economic competitiveness of Lithuania

Labour market trends and prospects for economic competitiveness of Lithuania VILNIUS UNIVERSITY Faculty of Economics and Business Administration Luxembourg, 2018 Labour market trends and prospects for economic competitiveness of Lithuania Conference Competitiveness Strategies for

More information

First Midterm. Time allowed: 50 minutes. Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely.

First Midterm. Time allowed: 50 minutes. Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely. Theory of International Trade (ECON0301) Dr. Stephen Chiu First Midterm Time allowed: 50 minutes Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely. Name: University Number:

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

How s Life in Greece?

How s Life in Greece? How s Life in Greece? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Greece has a mixed performance across the different well-being dimensions. Material conditions in Greece are generally below the OECD

More information

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of Chicago Press www.nber.org/books/glob-pov NBER Study: What is the relationship between globalization and poverty? Definition of globalization trade

More information

What does the U.K. Want for a Post-Brexit Economic. Future?

What does the U.K. Want for a Post-Brexit Economic. Future? What does the U.K. Want for a Post-Brexit Economic Future? Cameron Ballard-Rosa University of North Carolina Mashail Malik Stanford University Kenneth Scheve Stanford University December 2016 Preliminary

More information

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior ***

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue Importance and Performance Voting Patrick Fournier, André Blais, Richard Nadeau, Elisabeth Gidengil, and Neil Nevitte *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue importance mediates the impact of public

More information

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: BELARUS

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: BELARUS ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: BELARUS 2 nd Wave (Spring 2017) OPEN Neighbourhood Communicating for a stronger partnership: connecting with citizens across the Eastern Neighbourhood June 2017 1/44 TABLE OF CONTENTS

More information

How s Life in the Slovak Republic?

How s Life in the Slovak Republic? How s Life in the Slovak Republic? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, the average performance of the Slovak Republic across the different well-being dimensions is very mixed. Material conditions,

More information

Voter ID Pilot 2018 Public Opinion Survey Research. Prepared on behalf of: Bridget Williams, Alexandra Bogdan GfK Social and Strategic Research

Voter ID Pilot 2018 Public Opinion Survey Research. Prepared on behalf of: Bridget Williams, Alexandra Bogdan GfK Social and Strategic Research Voter ID Pilot 2018 Public Opinion Survey Research Prepared on behalf of: Prepared by: Issue: Bridget Williams, Alexandra Bogdan GfK Social and Strategic Research Final Date: 08 August 2018 Contents 1

More information

The Pull Factors of Female Immigration

The Pull Factors of Female Immigration Martin 1 The Pull Factors of Female Immigration Julie Martin Abstract What are the pull factors of immigration into OECD countries? Does it differ by gender? I argue that different types of social spending

More information

Theories of International Political Economy II: Marxism and Constructivism

Theories of International Political Economy II: Marxism and Constructivism Theories of International Political Economy II: Marxism and Constructivism Min Shu Waseda University 17 April 2017 International Political Economy 1 An outline of the lecture The basics of Marxism Marxist

More information

Partisan Cleavages, State Retrenchment, And Free Trade: Latin America in the 1990s

Partisan Cleavages, State Retrenchment, And Free Trade: Latin America in the 1990s Partisan Cleavages, State Retrenchment, And Free Trade: Latin America in the 1990s Beatriz Magaloni, Vidal Romero Latin American Research Review, Volume 43, Number 2, 2008, pp. 107-135 (Article) Published

More information

How s Life in Portugal?

How s Life in Portugal? How s Life in Portugal? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Portugal has a mixed performance across the different well-being dimensions. For example, it is in the bottom third of the OECD in

More information

Emerging and Developing Economies Much More Optimistic than Rich Countries about the Future

Emerging and Developing Economies Much More Optimistic than Rich Countries about the Future Emerging and Developing Economies Much More Optimistic than Rich Countries about the Future October 9, 2014 Education, Hard Work Considered Keys to Success, but Inequality Still a Challenge As they continue

More information

R Eagleton Institute of Politics Center for Public Interest Polling

R Eagleton Institute of Politics Center for Public Interest Polling 2002 SURVEY OF NEW BRUNSWICK RESIDENTS Conducted for: Conducted by: R Eagleton Institute of Politics Center for Public Interest Polling Data Collection: May 2002 02-02 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY TABLE OF CONTENTS

More information

How s Life in Austria?

How s Life in Austria? How s Life in Austria? November 2017 Austria performs close to the OECD average in many well-being dimensions, and exceeds it in several cases. For example, in 2015, household net adjusted disposable income

More information

The Politics of Emotional Confrontation in New Democracies: The Impact of Economic

The Politics of Emotional Confrontation in New Democracies: The Impact of Economic Paper prepared for presentation at the panel A Return of Class Conflict? Political Polarization among Party Leaders and Followers in the Wake of the Sovereign Debt Crisis The 24 th IPSA Congress Poznan,

More information

Explaining Attitudes toward Economic Integration: The Conditional Impact of National-Level Perceptions*

Explaining Attitudes toward Economic Integration: The Conditional Impact of National-Level Perceptions* Explaining Attitudes toward Economic Integration: The Conditional Impact of National-Level Perceptions* Abstract: To what extent are individuals attitudes toward economic integration shaped by their perceptions

More information

Spain s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Spain s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses How s Life in Spain? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Spain s average performance across the different well-being dimensions is mixed. Despite a comparatively low average household net adjusted

More information

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Ilkay Yilmaz 1,a, and Mehmet Nasih Tag 2 1 Mersin University, Department of Economics, Mersin University, 33342 Mersin, Turkey 2 Mersin University, Department

More information

AMERICANS ON GLOBALIZATION: A Study of US Public Attitudes March 28, 2000

AMERICANS ON GLOBALIZATION: A Study of US Public Attitudes March 28, 2000 AMERICANS ON GLOBALIZATION: A Study of US Public Attitudes March 28, 2000 Appendix E: Questionnaire and Results Please note that the questionnaire is 149 questions long. Questions 174 are displayed here.

More information

How Important Are Labor Markets to the Welfare of Indonesia's Poor?

How Important Are Labor Markets to the Welfare of Indonesia's Poor? Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized S /4 POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1665 How Important Are Labor Markets to the Welfare

More information

Wage inequality and skill premium

Wage inequality and skill premium Lecture 4d: Wage inequality and skill premium Thibault FALLY C181 International Trade Spring 2018 (Continuation of chapter 4) Skilled vs. unskilled labor As mentioned earlier, we can reinterpret HO model

More information

Welfare, inequality and poverty

Welfare, inequality and poverty 97 Rafael Guerreiro Osório Inequality and Poverty Welfare, inequality and poverty in 12 Latin American countries Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, El Salvador, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru,

More information

Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives

Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives Rise in Populism: Economic and Social Perspectives Damien Capelle Princeton University 6th March, Day of Action D. Capelle (Princeton) Rise of Populism 6th March, Day of Action 1 / 37 Table of Contents

More information

of immigration policymaking. To understand both the policies implemented and the accompanying

of immigration policymaking. To understand both the policies implemented and the accompanying 1 1 Introduction Individual preferences over immigration policy are an essential input into any complete model of immigration policymaking. To understand both the policies implemented and the accompanying

More information

Consumer Expectations: Politics Trumps Economics. Richard Curtin University of Michigan

Consumer Expectations: Politics Trumps Economics. Richard Curtin University of Michigan June 1, 21 Consumer Expectations: Politics Trumps Economics Richard Curtin University of Michigan An unprecedented partisan divide in economic expectations occurred following President Trump s election.

More information

How s Life in Ireland?

How s Life in Ireland? How s Life in Ireland? November 2017 Relative to other OECD countries, Ireland s performance across the different well-being dimensions is mixed. While Ireland s average household net adjusted disposable

More information