International dimensions of democratization

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "International dimensions of democratization"

Transcription

1 International dimensions of democratization Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of Social Sciences, University of Glasgow Adam Smith Building S210 Glasgow G12 8RT, Scotland, UK Abstract: Most research on democracy treats each nation state as completely independent, thus ignoring some of the central aspects of interdependence and interaction across borders in World Politics. This paper demonstrates that international aspects such as the political structures in proximate states and the regional threats that states face strongly influence the likelihood that a country will be democratic and experience transitions. The distribution of authority characteristics is not independent between countries, but displays strong evidence of patterns of diffusion. I show that the most commonly emphasized domestic processes within countries cannot by themselves account for the observed variation in distribution of political democracy over time and space. The regional context in which countries are located and their prior history provide important elements for explaining transitions and changes in the distribution of authority structures over time. Przeworski and Limongi's (1997:159) claim that democracy appears exogenously as a deus ex machina overlooks these patterns, and is thus incorrect. I am grateful for comments from Brian A Hearn, Matthew Baum, Renske Doorenspleet, Håvard Hegre, Yi Feng, Erik Gartzke, Nils Petter Gleditsch, Zeev Maoz, Solomon Polacheck, Bruce M. Russett, and in particular Michael D. Ward. This research was supported in part by a grant from the Research Council of Norway #128560/530. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the annual meeting of the Peace Science Society, Ann Arbor, MI, 8-10 October 1999.

2 Democracy and democratization in time and space Theories accounting for how political structures vary over time and across space have a long tradition. The best-known effort is probably Lipset s (1960) social requisites hypothesis, which states that a society s level of development influences its prospects for democracy. Other perspectives hold that certain cultural aspects, norms, or values favor the emergence and sustainment of democratic rule (e.g., Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional aspects such material inequality or the relative strength of groups or classes (e.g., Muller 1988, 1995, Rueschemeyer, Stephens and Stephens 1992, Vanhanen 1990). Theories of transitions to democracy more specifically stress factors such as the timing of national development, negotiated pacts between elites, and critical junctures or forms of path dependence in political development (e.g., Bollen 1979, Casper and Taylor 1996, Moore 1973, O'Donnell, Schmitter and Whitehead 1986, Przeworski 1991, Rueschemeyer et al. 1992). These explanations differ considerably from each other, and may suggest quite different observable implications for variation in authority structures (see, e.g., Vanhanen 1990 for a comprehensive review). Despite their differences, however, these schools are in one sense all similar in that they relate a country s prospects for democratization or sustaining democratic rule to various domestic economic, societal and political factors. By focusing exclusively on domestic processes, these theories effectively treat the distribution of democracy as if this were independent among countries. 1 Similarly, most research interested in the consequences of political democracy tends to treat the distribution of authority structures and changes in these as stemming from purely domestic processes. I argue that the distribution of democracy is not independent among countries and that international factors and processes influence the likelihood that a country will become or remain democratic. The international context thus contains central aspects of democratization processes. The first part of this paper discusses some international contexts of democratization. The second part shows empirically that the distribution of democracy and democratization cluster spatially, suggesting an international dimension to democratization over time. The third part demonstrates more systematically that this clustering cannot be attributed to other domestic factors affecting authority structures, and evaluates the relative importance of internal and external dimensions of democratization. Though Przeworski and Limongi (1997) are correct in concluding that transitions to democracy cannot be 1 Studies on effects of external dependence or how position in the so-called World-System influence prospects for democratic rule provide a possible exception (e.g., Bollen 1983, Wallerstein 1979). Other doubts about these theories aside (see e.g., Weede 1996), these usually consider dependence between national economies rather than political structures, and rarely draw explicit linkages between World-System position and authority structures. Those that do almost exclusively hypothesize that external factors affect domestic conditions which in turn influence a country s authority structures or propensity for democracy. Somewhat ironically, the domestic processes by which external dependence is held to impede democratization are actually often very similar to those highlighted by the social requisites school. 1

3 predicted from wealth alone, their claim that democratization is random is patently incorrect, as there is a systematic relationship between transitions and regional context. International contexts of democratization Though most work on democratization emphasizes domestic causal relationships that are presumed to be constant over time, it is widely recognized that the global distribution of democracy varies considerably over time. Figure 1 displays the distribution of democracy in the international system since 1800, as measured by the proportion of democratic polities and the mean level of institutionalized democracy on the composite scale in the POLITY 98 data. 2 Proportion of democracies Proportion of democracies Mean level of democracy Mean level of democracy Year Figure 1: The global distribution of democracy, The extent of political democracy in the world indeed seems greater at the present than at any previous period in history (e.g., Huntington 1991). Though the mean and median values resemble the socalled three waves of democracy, other measures of central tendency yield quite different images of the 2 This scale ranges from a low of 10 to a high of 10 in degree of institutionalized democracy (Gurr, Jaggers and Moore 1989). I here treat the scale as if it were continuous, though it is strictly speaking ordinal rather than interval (Gleditsch and Ward 1997). The threshold for democracy is here set to a score of six or above. 2

4 evolution of political democracy in the world. The mode is the minimum value for most years well throughout the middle of the 19 th Century, and fluctuates between high and low values in the 20 th Century after World War I. Only in the latter part of the 19 th and the earliest part of 20 th Century are the modal values close to the mean. That the mode oscillates between the extremes of the POLITY 98 scale reflects a bimodal distribution, but also indicates that there is considerable difference in typical countries over time. As the domestic and economic conditions that typically are assigned causal importance tend to change relatively slowly over time, it seems questionable whether the observed variation in the distribution of democracy can be attributed to changes in these factors alone. At a minimum, the relationship between such domestic attributes and authority structures does not seem structurally stable over time. 3 The recent changes toward greater political democracy commonly known as the third wave of democracy have sensitized researchers to that trends in democratization may reflect influences from a changing global environment rather than similar processes operating independently or in a parallel fashion within each case (e.g., Huntington 1991). In a remarkable change of emphasis, Whitehead (1996) even claims that of all the democracies existing at the beginning of the 1990s, only in Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom did political democracy evolve independently of international events. Though recent work focuses almost exclusively on the diffusion of democratic authority structures, changes at the global level have not been consistently toward greater democracy. Most notably, the breakdowns of fragile democracies in the inter-war period and in the aftermath of decolonialization suggest that a spread of autocracy prevailed for much of the 20 th century (see also O'Loughlin et al. 1998). Merely attributing democratization or autocratization to some international context, however, explains little without clarifying the relevant context and some hypothesized mechanisms that influence the emergence of democracy. Many look to changes at the global level itself, and attribute variation in the global distribution of democracy over time to changes in largely autonomous belief structures and the relative status of political ideologies (e.g., Fukuyama 1992), or the changing nature of hegemony and the position of the United States on democracy (e.g., Robinson 1996). These studies tend to remain rather descriptive, and rarely provide any explicit hypotheses as to why the balance of ideologies or hegemony change in such a way as to favor democracy. 4 3 Some of the differences stem from new states entering the international system rather than changes in countries in the system. But while some of the major breakpoints in Figure 1 are associated with changes in the composition of the system notably the two world wars and the process of decolonialization the variation in the mode of democracy indicates that there is no simple relationship between system size and the global distribution of democracy. 4 Marxist and World-Systems analysts such as Robinson (1996) essentially assert that whatever changes occur are due to the changing nature of hegemony thereby directly assuming what is to be proven. US presidential administrations also seem to differ considerably in the emphasis on democracy in foreign policy. Though the Carter administration, at least initially, placed greater emphasis on democracy and human rights, these features were much less prominent under Reagan and Bush when the third wave picked up speed. 3

5 In one of the few empirical studies of global level influences, Ray (1995b) evaluates how much of the total variance in transitions to democracy can be attributed to system-level and national attributes respectively. His analysis indicates that the global share seems relatively modest, and Ray surmises that the global influences on democracy may have been overstated. Such largely negative findings could also be due to the all-encompassing nature of the notion of global context. Global-level influences on democratization are often presented in a fashion so general as to render a systematic assessment difficult. Assuming that everything is related to everything else makes empirical analysis nearly intractable, and assuming universal global influences might be as grossly inaccurate as fully identical processes operating independently within each country. Invoking global context furthermore implicitly assumes that external influences on regime change and political authority structures at any point in time are essentially similar or consistent across all countries. By contrast, I submit that regions or local environments provide a more reasonable context of diffusion and container of primary external factors and interactions influencing changes in political authority structures. Geography and distance induce dependence and affectedness, and shape incentives and behavior among neighboring countries. Spatially grounded measures that incorporate influences from neighboring states can help address implications of interdependence for international conflict and cooperation (Gleditsch 1999, Gleditsch and Ward 2000, Shin and Ward 1999), and provide a promising avenue to examine international dimensions of democratization. Diffusion and dependence at the local level can have dramatically different implications for entities within the global system, depending upon the specific composition of neighboring states or their regional context. A stable share of countries that by some criterion are judged to be democracies at the global level may mask considerable variation at the local level. Local differences such as countries within highly autocratic regions becoming more autocratic while polities in more democratic contexts experience transitions to democracy could wash out in the aggregate. Though such changes go in different directions, they can nonetheless be seen as qualitatively similar processes that induce similarity in authority structures within regions or geographical clusters that differ markedly between each other. Towards a theory of diffusion What factors underlie such local diffusion and dependence in authority structures? Recent literature on democratization argues that democracy emerges as an outcome of enduring social conflict when no single actor possesses sufficient resources to impose itself upon others (e.g., Olson 1993, Przeworski 1988, Vanhanen 1990). Institutionalizing methods for sharing power and establishing political and civil rights become rational options when social actors are unable or unlikely to have their unrestricted preferences prevail. There is no inherent reason why such struggles over influence and applicable resources should stop at water s edge, or be fully confined within the boundaries of individual countries. The balance of power or the resources and influence that given social groups can mobilize can be altered decisively not 4

6 only by domestic factors and processes, but through external events and opportunities for assistance from outside actors as well. External influences that alter the balance of power at the domestic scene may be located at a variety of types of levels and actors. Many non-governmental social and political networks are clearly transnational in nature and operate across national borders. Though such groups may rarely alone undermine ruling coalitions or influence policies directly, they can exert critical indirect effects through altering the existing distribution of resources or influence that groups within states can muster. Many political movements associated with ethnic groups such as the Irish Republican Army and the Kurdish Labor Party (PKK) have drawn heavily upon resources mobilized in diasporas. History exhibits several examples of international networks actively trying to change the course of events in other countries, spanning from peace activists to commercial interests, armed insurgencies, and revolutionary varieties of Islam (Deutsch 1954, Keck and Sikkink 1999, Randle 1991, Smith, Pagnucco and Lopez 1998). States or domestic coalitions in power will often take an active interest in events occurring in neighboring countries and try to influence outcomes according to their preferences. Foreign policies are shaped by demands from transnational actors (e.g., Davis and Moore 1997), and neighboring states may supply important resources to actors that can affect the outcomes of political struggles at the margin. Such coalitions between external and internal actors are likely to exert the most dramatic effects on authority structures when there are shifts in the coalitions that hold power in neighboring entities, as these tend to be associated with large changes in the resources or means of influence that actors can mobilize. Many studies invoke variations on Schelling s (1971) tipping model to show how merely small changes in external context can suffice to yield cascades of individual participation, thereby generating a critical mass in political contestation (e.g., Kuran 1989, 1991, Lohmann 1994). Such processes are often held to have played out in the fall of socialism in Eastern Europe, where the initial political changes in Poland and Hungary changed the relative influence of actors and constraints on feasible actions which spurred subsequent changes in Czechoslovakia and East Germany. Diffusion processes may also induce regime changes other than transitions to democracy. Ghana can be seen as prototypical for the development of governance in many post-colonial African societies. After the relatively democratic constitution at the time of independence in 1958, president Nkrumah became increasingly dictatorial and severely limited political opposition. The one-party system introduced in 1964 quickly spread to many neighboring states. More recently, regime changes and insurgencies in Central Africa display similar diffusion processes. Many regard the Ugandan support as critical for the 1994 RPF takeover in Rwanda. The changes in Rwanda again boosted Kabila s armed uprising that toppled Mobutu in neighboring Zaïre. Many regime changes involving major political reorientations may not show up in measures of authority structures, however, as changes in the leadership or ideological orientation of autocracies do not necessarily yield changes in institutional structures per se. If diffusion processes operate between states operate more generally, we should see a serial clustering geographically both in the distribution of authority structures as well as changes in such 5

7 attributes. I will later show that we indeed find such clustering in authority structures, and that transitions and survival for regimes co-vary dramatically with the regional context. Democratization and the diffusion of conflict and peace Though transnational integration might provide a facilitating condition for many forms of diffusion processes, some forms are clearly possible even in the absence of significant integration. In particular, the diffusion of conflict and insecurity within regions may severely constrain prospects for democratic rule. Many have elevated the so-called democratic peace, or the empirical finding that pairs of democracies seem to have a lower likelihood of conflict than other combinations of polities, to an empirical law of international relations (e.g., Levy 1989, Russett 1993). In this research tradition, the distribution of authority structures in the international system is taken as exogenous or given when comparing the conflict proneness of pairs of countries with different authority structures. However, the likelihood that a country is democratic or experiences transitions may itself be related to its propensity for conflict and peace. Stated differently, democracy cannot be considered fully exogenous if countries that are less likely to experience conflict or enjoy a more secure peace have better prospects for democracy in the first place. Many proponents and opponents of the democratic peace concede that the likelihood of transitions or sustaining democracy in part may be related to peace itself, but disagree about whether such broader linkages revolve around positive feedback between democracy and peace or reverse causal linkages from secure peace to democracy. In the first instance, linkages from democracy to peace reinforce the democratic or broader liberal peace proposition. Under the latter view, the notion of democracy as a path to peace confuses the direction of causality and the substantive implications of the association between the two. Many proponents of the democratic peace suggest feedback mechanisms between peace and democracy, where democracy first makes peace more likely and the improved prospects for peace subsequently enhances the prospects for sustaining democracy (see, e.g., Russett 1998). In addition, some of the domestic socio-economic factors seen as conducive to democratization and democratic consolidation such as economic performance, wealth, and trade may conceivably influence the propensity for peace and conflict (e.g., Hegre 1999, Rosecrance 1986). Many critics assert as a self-evident proposition that peace is a prerequisite for preserving democracy. Some surmise that the absence of war between democracies could merely stem from that democracy is likely to break down under the threat of war and thus rarely survives until war breaks out (e.g., Layne 1994). Others hypothesize that times of war will be associated with a decline in democracy, as efforts to wage war can be incompatible with civil liberties or induce at least temporary restrictions in democracies (e.g., Gates, Knutsen and Moses 1996). Similarly, Mansfield and Snyder (1998) hold that young democracies with fragile institutions are at greater risk for reversals when involved in or at risk of conflict. 6

8 Numerous cases where stability and lack of belligerence go together with autocratic rule attest to that peace cannot be sufficient for democracy. Nor can peace or absence of conflict involvement be strictly necessary for democracy, since many democracies participate in interstate wars and sustained conflict and yet remain democracies. Of course, this does not imply that the no linkages may exist from conflict and peace to democracy, and few probably hold that merit of hypotheses on the potential effects of peace on democratization should be judged by whether such deterministic regularities obtain. These examples do, however, indicate that assertions that democracy is incompatible with conflict in their general form are not evidently correct, and that such hypotheses require emendation to be tested empirically in any meaningful manner. Thompson (1996) set forward a more general war-making/state-making perspective on democratization that clarifies some possible linkages. According to Thompson, the political systems that eventually emerge historically have been strongly shaped by rulers need to obtain resources and mobilize for military efforts. Sustained perpetual rivalry and threats to vital security tend to foster authoritarianism as power becomes more centralized. A situation of relative regional peace, by contrast, may facilitate the initial emergence of political pluralism as internal political processes can unfold within some degree of insulation from external demands or threats. Thompson argues that contemporary and historical zones of peace emerged when previously dominant states were forced to abandon ambitions of regional hegemony. In Norway, for example, efforts to push for full independence from Sweden were put on hold in the late 19 th century over concerns over increased Russification in Finland, and it is not incidental that the 1905 independence coincides with the defeat of the perceived threat in the Russo-Japanese war. Barzel and Kiser (1997) set forward an alternative interpretation of the role of war and security in the emergence of voting institutions in medieval Europe. Warfare has in some cases moved states towards democratization through rulers need to cede political rights to subjects in exchange for the ability to extract tax revenue (e.g., Kiser and Barzel 1991). Though many theories relate the emergence of democracy and political rights to weak rulers, Barzel and Kiser hold the security of rule as essential for the possibility of contracting between rulers and the ruled. The less secure a ruler, the lower the potential level of cooperative contracting, and the lower the rate of development of voting institutions. In addition to lower internal threats, the relative geographical isolation and protection from external threat may in part explain why voting institutions were more developed and durable in England than in France. 5 While these linkages are quite different from those of Thompson (1996), the observable implications for linkages between regional peace and democracy are largely similar. From this perspective, it is less surprising that the presence or absence of war among states correlates with the extent of their political democracy. The idea of democracy as a path to peace amounts to putting the cart before the horse if a situation of relatively secure peace or absence of regional threat was an important prerequisite for the emergence of democratic political systems. Though this regional 5 If regional threats do impede democracy, there is certainly something to be said for splendid isolation. Such linkages may in part underlie the relationship between democracy and insularity some emphasize (e.g., Anckar and Anckar 1995). 7

9 peace precedes democratization hypothesis does not necessarily disprove the democratic peace, it suggests that constraints on initial democratization and their relationship to international interactions may have been disregarded in previous work. Such omissions make it difficult to evaluate the implications of existing findings and leave an unstable foundation for inferring policy implications. Thompson and Barzel and Kieser illustrate their arguments by various historical cases, but linkages from war and peace to democracy have rarely been examined in any systematic manner. Some studies examining whether wars exert some effect on the prospects for democracy find that conflict involvement does not seem to decrease democracy (e.g., McLaughlin 1996, Mousseau and Shi 1999). However, not all incidents of war and peace as the absence of war at some given point in time are qualitatively equivalent, and correlating general war involvement with democracy can miss out on central ways by which conflict may influence democracy. First, researchers have examined whether general participation in conflict is associated with democratization and autocratization, though the relevant variable is the extent of threats to security in a country s regional context. The cart before the horse hypothesis suggest that persistent insecurity over time can inhibit the emergence of democracy rather than that participation in conflict is incompatible with democracy in and of itself. Existing efforts to test linkages from conflict to prospects for democracy focus on a state s general belligerence, and have not sought to identify the locus of conflict involvement or to what extent conflicts pose threats to a state s vital security. Participation in UN peacekeeping forces outside the regional context or remote colonial wars that do not expose the core territory to risks, for example, should not be expected to lead to a breakdown of democracy in developed societies. Second, effects of conflict on the prospects for democracy are not necessarily one-time events immediately following outbreaks of war, but hinge upon more enduring forms of insecurity and threats that do not necessarily break out into open warfare or conflict all the time. Rather than just the peaks of conflict resulting in wars, we need to consider the broader array of hostile interactions in a country s regional context over time. The history of interaction shapes the perceived insecurity that may affect long-term prospects for democracy through risk of recurrence and diffusion of conflict. Though the extent of real and perceived threats over time is a latent or not directly observable factor, measures based on interaction across time and space can provide more valid indicators than data on single events. To assess the element of threat, I thus distinguish between local conflict and conflict involvement elsewhere in the international system. If the hypotheses linking conflict and peace to democracy have some merit, we should observe a relationship between democracy and the stability of peace in a country i s regional context. 8

10 Empirical analysis Clustering of democracy and democratization If the idea of regional diffusion of authority structures has some merit, we should to observe a positive relationship between the composition of authority structures in the proximate regional context and a country s own domestic authority structures. Democracy and democratization should cluster in disparate and qualitatively different zones over time and space. We can explore the empirical record more systematically through descriptive statistics of the extent of clustering and variation across space. Conceptually, the extent of spatial clustering in data on geographically situated units can be studied at either a global or a local level. Attributes are clustered globally if values on the particular variable are distributed in some geographic pattern deviating systematically from a random distribution or what one would expect from chance. By contrast, local measures of spatial clustering identify whether specific regions cluster or exhibit strong similarity in attributes or behavior. Stated differently, global indicators of spatial clustering indicate whether aspects are non-randomly distributed in space, whereas local indicators indicate which regions or locales display high or low values respectively. The most common statistic for assessing the extent of global clustering in some variable x for a cross-section of geographical units is the so-called Moran s (1950) I coefficient. This is defined as I = i n j w ~ ij i j w ~ ( x x x x i )( j ) ij (1) ( x x) 2 i i where w ~ ij denotes an element [ i, j ] of a row-standardized matrix W ~ that acquires a non-zero value if units i and j are contiguous. 6 The value of the Moran s I statistic indicates the similarity of x i for each unit i with its J neighboring entities x j. However, the coefficient is not bounded by ±1, and the expected value is E( I) = a f N 1 1 c Ih a f rather than 0. The estimated standard error of the Moran s I statistic, V I = E σ 2 E I 2, allows testing whether the observed levels of global clustering in a given sample differ significantly from the null hypothesis of no spatial clustering. 7 6 The rows of ~ W each sum up to one. Note that the diagonal of ~ W by convention is set to zero so that countries are not considered contiguous with themselves. b gturns out to be somewhat cumbersome to express and depends upon 7 The expected value of the variance E σ 2 I sampling assumptions. Cliff and Ord (1973:15) develop the expected value of the variance of Moran s I under a b g is n S ns + 3 S S bn 1g b 3 + 3g + 3 ( ) b g 2 + 6, where normality assumption and a randomization assumption. Under normality, E randomization E bσ g 2 turns out to be I 9 σ 2 I n n n S ns S E x x n n S ns S S n 1 n 2 n 3 0 ( )( )( ) i while under

11 To assess whether the distribution of political authority structures cluster geographically in a nonrandom fashion in the international system, I calculate Moran s I coefficients for the levels in the composite institutionalized democracy scale in the POLITY 98 data set for each year in the period , as well as changes on this scale over the prior ten years. I generate contiguity data from a new data set on the minimum distances between polities, and consider states contiguous if they are less than 950 kilometers apart from each other. 8 I plot the value of the Moran s I coefficients over time in Figure 2. Significant values are indicated by filled circles, and blank circles indicate cases where the null hypothesis of no spatial dependence cannot be rejected at p <.05. The expected value of Moran s I is plotted as a solid line. 9 Moran's I, level of democracy Moran's I (950 km) Year Moran's I, change in democracy Moran's I (950 km) Year Figure 2: Moran s I for clustering of institutionalized democracy and changes in democracy, n n 0 i= 1 j= 1 i, j j, i S = w + w 1 a f, S = aw + w 1 2 n 2 f n i = 1 j = 1 i, j j, i, S = n n w~ + w~ 2 i = 1 j = 1 i j 10 a, j, i [ i, j ] in a binary connectivity matrix W, all the other variables as defined above. f 2, and w i, j denotes an element 8 This data set allows varying the cut-off criteria for what is to be considered relevant distances, and has been adjusted to incorporate border changes since It is described in greater detail in Gleditsch and Ward (1999a). A 950-km cut-off criterion has a range of inclusion corresponding quite closely to the notion of geographical regions. I have used cut-off criteria for relevance set to 950, 475, and 50 kilometers respectively to generate binary contiguity matrices. For considerations of space, only results based on the 950 km threshold are shown here. The results at other distance threshold do not yield substantively different conclusions and are available on request. 9 The expected value of Moran s I depends upon sample size, but the change from one year to another is relatively small and the flat nature of the line suggests that comparisons across time are not too problematic here. Though the null hypothesis here obviously is spatial independence (i.e., that observations are not correlated across space), the interpretation of tests can be ambiguous since potential patterns of spatial dependence may lack a known representation. In this sense, we only fail to reject a null hypothesis of no-spatial dependence for some specific hypothesized pattern, and cannot conclusively rule out other patterns of cross-unit dependence (Anselin 1988).

12 The upper row in Figure 2 displays the extent of global clustering in institutionalized democracy. These results strongly suggest that institutionalized democracy is distributed non-randomly in space. With the exception of a few years (notably during World War II), the values of Moran s I indicate quite consistent, significant spatial clustering in the observed data from the end of the 19 th century. In other words, the likelihood of observing whether a given country will be democratic or not differs according to its regional context or the properties of neighboring countries. The lower row indicates whether the changes in authority structures over a ten-year period appear to be distributed geographically in a non-random fashion. Changes are quite infrequent, and for most years, the Moran s I coefficients do not achieve statistical significance. From the late 1970s and on, however, the null hypothesis of no spatial clustering is rejected for most years. Even at the aggregate level of the international system, we thus find evidence of a geographical clustering in political changes and transitions during the third wave of democratization. The Moran s I indicates geographic clustering in the aggregate, but does not by itself indicate where democracies and autocracies cluster. The so-called * G i statistic is a common indicator of local clustering or whether values of a given variable x are similar for entities around some location i (Ord and Getis 1995). This is defined as where G * i wij x j ( wij + w x i ii ) j =, 2 2 σ$ n w w / ( n 1) x j ij i ij w denotes element [ i, j ] in a binary contiguity matrix W and ij location j. 10 The values of the x j denotes an observation at * G i statistic can be interpreted as standardized Z-scores. A positive value of * G i at a particular location implies spatial clustering of high values around that location, while a negative value indicates a spatial grouping of low values. (2) 10 Since the interest here is in to what extent observations are similar to their neighbors, the diagonal entries in W are all set to one. An alternative statistic G i, which does not include the values of i itself, indicates to what extent values surrounding location i are similar values. See Ord and Getis (1995) and Gleditsch (1999: ch. 4) for further details. 11

13 Values of G*i Democracy (1992) (<-3) (-3,-1.96) (-1.96,-1.65) (-1.65,1.65) (1.65,1.96) (1.96,3) (>3) No Data The annual Map 1: Values of G i * for level of democracy, 1992 * G i statistics for the years reveal several discernible zones or clusters of states with similar authority structures within the international system. Map 1 displays the localized clustering in democracy in the international system in 1992, as seen in the values G i * at a 950-km threshold. Shades of green denote zones with significant positive spatial clustering or strong clustering of high levels of democracy. By contrast, shades of orange indicate significant spatial clustering of low values of democracy or zones of autocracies. There is significant positive clustering of democracy throughout most of Europe, and a similar, though less strong, clustering in democracy in the Western Hemisphere. Conversely, these zones of democracy are matched by a belt of strong clustering in authoritarianism, stretching from Central and East Africa through the Middle East. Can we find similar evidence of clustering for changes in authority structures as well? Map 2 indicates the extent of clustering for changes in authority structures over the prior decade as assessed by the G i * statistic. The significant clustering in the changes toward greater democracy both in the Southern Cone and Eastern Europe leads some support to that the third wave of democratization in part unfolded regionally. 12

14 G*i change in democracy, (<-3) (-3, -1.96) (-1.96, -1.65) (-1.65, 1.65) (1.65, 1.96) (1.96, 3) (>3) No Data Map 2: Values of G i * for changes in level of democracy over prior 10 years, 1992 Internal and external dimensions of democracy Though many suggest international dimensions to democratization, relatively few empirical analyses have examined systematically the importance of regional diffusion. Existing efforts to analyze empirically the diffusion of democracy and authority structures across borders (e.g., O'Loughlin et al. 1998, Starr 1991) largely disregard the potential influences that domestic attributes and processes may exert. Merely reporting an aggregate relationship between a country s authority structures and the composition in its regional context does not in itself provide convincing evidence that diffusion processes operate. There is in all likelihood comparable non-random geographical clustering among the principal social and economic conditions hypothesized to influence democracy. As such, what analyses that ignore domestic aspects altogether attribute to diffusion may simply stem from geographical clustering in omitted domestic attributes that influence the propensity for democracy. 11 To say something about the relative effects of external dimensions of democracy, these must be assessed while simultaneously considering some of the plausible confounding domestic factors. While I cannot consider all theories relating democracy to domestic processes here, the primary alternative hypothesis is obviously the social 11 Gleditsch (1996) compared the influences of diffusion and socio-economic development on democracy as reflected by the Freedom House data more systematically. This study encompassed a relatively limited sample of 13

15 requisites school or that democracy is related to a country s level of socio-economic development (e.g., Lipset 1960, 1994). Much of the existing comparative research on the relationship of democracy to domestic attributes and processes exhibits various other problems. Studies have relied on largely cross-sectional designs where the variance is predominantly between countries. However, researchers are interested in the likely implications of changes in the independent variables over time, and often proceed to make inferences about prospects for democratization. Though rarely stated explicitly, many assume that the temporal dynamics simply are mirror images of the differences between countries. In principle, however, there is no logical connection between the two empirical domains, and it can easily be shown that inferences about temporal dynamics based on cross-sectional variation may be misleading if the two are not identical (e.g., Brunner and Liepelt 1972, Smith 1995). 12 The basic point that the dynamics of democratization cannot be directly inferred from levels or the distribution of democracy at a given point often appears to have been overlooked. 13 Many studies pool time-series for several countries, but fail to address the problems that the structure of the data poses for analysis (Arat 1988, Gonick and Rosh 1988). 14 Given the inherent temporal ordering of annual observations for some country i, it would be tenuous at best to treat these observations as independent. As authority structures rarely change from one year to the other, these observations are likely to be highly correlated over time. Most of the variance in the pooled data is thus still between countries rather than over time. Though there is considerable empirical evidence indicating a strong association between a country s development, it is less clear whether the causal effect most commonly inferred that economic development will yield changes toward greater democracy over time obtains as strongly as many assume. To assess the relative importance of external and internal factors, I examine how the distribution of democracy varies across time and space according to both domestic social requisites as well as external factors in the surrounding regional context. I measure a society s economic wealth or social requisites countries, however, and suffered from problems of non-systematic coding of proximity or closeness between entities, based upon subjective assessments of each individual case. 12 Some critics like Tilly (1984) hold that cross-sectional designs are based on an underlying assumption that history follows general sequences or similar paths. This assertion, however, is highly questionable. Since the values on right hand side variables can both decrease and increase, there is no form of evolution assumed by the design alone. If the processes over time and space are similar, the variation across units in a cross-section might be more informative about long-run behavior than relatively short individual unit time-series. 13 Though various more historically grounded macro-comparative studies examine changes in democracy over time (e.g., Moore 1973), many researchers rely on often rather controversial historical interpretations as unambiguous and indisputable evidence (see Goldthorpe 1991, Lustick 1996). Others criticize the extreme determinism, where class constellations and events several decades, if not centuries, earlier are held to fully determine current regime structures (e.g., Przeworski and Limongi 1997). 14 Burkhart and Lewis-Beck (1994) try to remedy some of these shortcomings, but understates the extent of permanence over time in the data by purging the serial correlation of observations over time before the analysis and (see Beck and Katz 1996, Gleditsch 1996). Since regimes rarely change from one year to another and the serial correlation approaches 1, purging the autocorrelation essentially leaves a regression of covariates on the first differences of the annual observations where any change would have to be attributed to the covariates by construction. 14

16 by the natural logarithm of its GDP per capita in purchasing power parities at time t (denoted ln cp i, t h symbolically), using data from the Penn World Tables (Summers and Heston 1991). 15 I assess the regional context of democracy by the average of the authority structures in the region surrounding country R i using a 950-km threshold (denoted D i, t ). I use the clustering of years without local conflict involvement τ in the polities within 950-km of each country i as a proxy indicator of the extent of threat or stability of peace (denoted G * i, t τ ). More specifically, I regress a country i s level of democracy at time t (denoted D i, t ) on the natural logarithm of its GDP per capita in purchasing power parities at time t, the regional average authority structures at time t, and the stability of peace in the regional context. To prevent serial correlated residuals from inducing biased estimates and statistical overconfidence, 16 I include the first lag of the dependent variable or country i s level of democracy in the preceding year (i.e., D i, t 1 ) on the righthand side. This parameter can also be interpreted as a measure of the persistence over time in the dependent variable. Symbolically, we have the regression equation all the variables as defined above. R * D = α + β D + β ln( P ) + β D + β G τ + µ i, t 0 1 i, t 1 2 i, t 3 i, t 4 i, ta f i, t, (3) 15 Many suggest that differences in GDP capita probably matter comparatively more at lower levels of per capita income (e.g., Burkhart and Lewis-Beck 1994, Jackman 1973). As a linear relationship seems implausible, I use a logarithmic transformation of GDP per capita. The natural logarithm is obviously a somewhat arbitrary transformation, and other types of non-linear functional forms are of course possible (see, e.g., Jackman 1973 for a more extended discussion). Some include an additional a square term of GDP per capita (e.g., Przeworski and Limongi 1997). However, though effects may decrease in magnitude at higher per capita income, this specification seems theoretically inappropriate as there is no clear reason why additional income above some threshold should be associated with a lower level of democracy. 16 Serial dependence or autocorrelation implies that the error terms for different observations are correlated rather than independent of each other. The variance-covariance matrix V of the coefficient estimates for a regression T model is given by X X 1 T 2 T 1 X σ Ω X X X. Generally stated, an error structure exhibits autocorrelation c h c h c h whenever Ω is not the identity matrix I, and the expected value of the off-diagonal entries ω ij are not all 0. Generalized least squares (GLS) techniques model the correlation-structure of Ω explicitly by some hypothesized estimate Ω, $ and can be shown to yield consistent estimates and various desirable asymptotic properties (e.g., Hsiao 1986). Since the true structure of Ω is generally not known, researchers must resort to some hypothesized estimate and it is commonly assumed that error structures follow either AR(1), MA(1), or ARMA (1,1) processes. In an AR(1) structure, the correlation between two residuals ε t, ε t j reflects a common correlation coefficient ρ < 1 as well as their temporal distance so that cor ε t, ε t j = ρ j c h. The serial correlation is always larger than zero, but becomes increasingly smaller and negligible for longer temporal distances. An MA(1) structure implies that the error term incorporates the values of prior residuals ε t 1 in addition to the stochastic component µ t, so that ε t = µ t λµ t 1. Analysts typically estimate ρ from the residuals of a regression, and then purge the autoregressive component from the model until the estimated residuals appear to be white noise. However, the properties of GLS hold only asymptotically and may not obtain in an actual limited sample situation. Beck and Katz (1996) provide Monte Carlo simulation results indicating that feasible GLS estimates are not generally more efficient than regular OLS regression, with some minor corrections to control for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity, in applied settings with the data properties common in social science. More importantly, purging the serial correlation might be an adequate statistical solution, but coefficient estimates that fail to reflect the stickiness or autoregressive structure can easily be analytically misleading in that we are likely to exaggerate the substantive implications of changes in the right-hand side variables on the dependent variable. 15

17 As the model probably will not fit all countries equally well and some may display larger variance in the error terms than others, the pooled nature of the data is also likely to invalidate the assumption of homoskedasticity or constant variance of the expected values of the error term between observations. 17 Table 1 thus reports heteroskedastic consistent standard errors for estimating Equation 3 based on MacKinnon and White s (1985) jack-knife estimator. Table 1: Regression of level of democracy on regional context, wealth, and conflict LEVEL OF DEMOCRACY INDEPENDENT VARIABLES COEFFICIENT ESTIMATE STANDARD ERROR Constant Democracy at time t GDP per capita, natural log Regional context of democracy Regional clustering of years at peace F 4, 4095 = 22990, N = 4096 As reflected in the.96 coefficient estimate in Table 1, there is a near deterministic relationship between level of democracy in the previous and current year. Given the high persistence in authority structures over time, variation in the explanatory variables is unlikely to be associated with dramatic effects on the level of democracy, at least in the short term. The high degree of permanence indicated here cannot be dismissed merely as an idiosyncratic feature of the POLITY data, but should be seen as an actual feature of authority structures. 18 Of course, dichotomous indicators of democracies and non- 17 Heteroskedasticity means that the entries on the diagonal matrix Ω in the variance covariance matrix of the coefficient estimates V are not identical but vary in size. Heteroskedasticity does not bias coefficient estimates, but the standard error estimates will no longer be efficient. White (1980) show that a so-called sandwich estimator S w, or a diagonal matrix with the squared estimated residuals of the regression $σ i 2 on the diagonal, under quite general conditions yield a consistent estimate of σ 2 Ω. MacKinnon and White (1985) suggest an alternative 2 σ$ estimator known as the jack-knife S mw. This weights the diagonal entries i by the influence each h$ 2 1 i observation exerts on the coefficient estimates, as measured by the diagonal elements of the so-called hat matrix 1 c h T given by H = X X X X T. Davidson and MacKinnon (1993) suggest that the jack-knife estimator S mw performs better than the original White estimator S w in small samples. 18 This estimate corresponds almost perfectly to a similar analysis (Gleditsch 1996) using the Freedom House data on democracy, with a different panel and a distinct set of right hand side variables in the model. 16

Diffusion and the International Context of Democratization

Diffusion and the International Context of Democratization Diffusion and the International Context of Democratization Kristian Skrede Gleditsch and Michael D+ Ward Abstract Democracy does not evolve sui generis+ The spatial clustering in democracy and transitions

More information

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Kristian Skrede Gleditsch University of California, San Diego & Centre for the Study of Civil War, International Peace Research Institute, Oslo See http://weber.ucsd.edu/

More information

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Lisa L. Verdon * SUMMARY Capital accumulation has long been considered one of the driving forces behind economic growth. The idea that democratic

More information

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Comparing the Data Sets

Comparing the Data Sets Comparing the Data Sets Online Appendix to Accompany "Rival Strategies of Validation: Tools for Evaluating Measures of Democracy" Jason Seawright and David Collier Comparative Political Studies 47, No.

More information

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters* 2003 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 40, no. 6, 2003, pp. 727 732 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) www.sagepublications.com [0022-3433(200311)40:6; 727 732; 038292] All s Well

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

WEB APPENDIX. to accompany. Veto Players and Terror. Journal of Peace Research 47(1): Joseph K. Young 1. Southern Illinois University.

WEB APPENDIX. to accompany. Veto Players and Terror. Journal of Peace Research 47(1): Joseph K. Young 1. Southern Illinois University. WEB APPENDIX to accompany Veto Players and Terror Journal of Peace Research 47(1): 1-13 Joseph K. Young 1 Departments of Political Science and Criminology/Criminal Justice Southern Illinois University

More information

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden Hammarstedt and Palme IZA Journal of Migration 2012, 1:4 RESEARCH Open Access Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation in Sweden Mats Hammarstedt 1* and Mårten Palme 2 * Correspondence:

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

Income and Democracy

Income and Democracy Income and Democracy Daron Acemoglu Simon Johnson James A. Robinson Pierre Yared First Version: May 2004. This Version: July 2007. Abstract We revisit one of the central empirical findings of the political

More information

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. World Politics, vol. 68, no. 2, April 2016.* David E. Cunningham University of

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

Working Papers in Economics

Working Papers in Economics University of Innsbruck Working Papers in Economics Foreign Direct Investment and European Integration in the 90 s Peter Egger and Michael Pfaffermayr 2002/2 Institute of Economic Theory, Economic Policy

More information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Practice Questions for Exam #2 Fall 2007 Page 1 Practice Questions for Exam #2 1. Suppose that we have collected a stratified random sample of 1,000 Hispanic adults and 1,000 non-hispanic adults. These respondents are asked whether

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Long-Run Causes of Comparative Economic Development Institutions University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Outline 1 Introduction 2 3 The Korean Case The Korean

More information

The Joint Democracy Dyadic Conflict Nexus: A Simultaneous Equations Model

The Joint Democracy Dyadic Conflict Nexus: A Simultaneous Equations Model International Studies Quarterly (2003) 47, 325 346 The Joint Democracy Dyadic Conflict Nexus: A Simultaneous Equations Model RAFAEL REUVENY Indiana University QUAN LI The Pennsylvania State University

More information

In their path breaking study, Ostrom and Job (1986) develop a cybernetic

In their path breaking study, Ostrom and Job (1986) develop a cybernetic 438 SARA MCLAUGHLIN MITCHELL AND WILL H. MOORE Presidential Uses of Force During the Cold War: Aggregation, Truncation, and Temporal Dynamics Sara McLaughlin Mitchell Will H. Moore Florida State University

More information

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? Chapter Six SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES? This report represents an initial investigation into the relationship between economic growth and military expenditures for

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Simulating the Evolution of Global Democracy Levels

Simulating the Evolution of Global Democracy Levels Simulating the Evolution of Global Democracy Levels Joachim Carlsen Centre for the Study of Civil War; e-mail: joachim@prio.no Håvard Hegre Centre for the Study of Civil War; e-mail: hhegre@prio.no Paper

More information

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, 1870 1970 IDS WORKING PAPER 73 Edward Anderson SUMMARY This paper studies the impact of globalisation on wage inequality in eight now-developed countries during the

More information

David Stasavage. Private investment and political institutions

David Stasavage. Private investment and political institutions LSE Research Online Article (refereed) David Stasavage Private investment and political institutions Originally published in Economics and politics, 14 (1). pp. 41-63 2002 Blackwell Publishing. You may

More information

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Appendix to Sectoral Economies Appendix to Sectoral Economies Rafaela Dancygier and Michael Donnelly June 18, 2012 1. Details About the Sectoral Data used in this Article Table A1: Availability of NACE classifications by country of

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Bernard L. Fraga Contents Appendix A Details of Estimation Strategy 1 A.1 Hypotheses.....................................

More information

Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes

Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes Evidence from Namibia Marie Lechler 1 Lachlan McNamee 2 1 University of Munich 2 Stanford University June

More information

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) MIT Spatial Economics Reading Group Presentation Adam Guren May 13, 2010 Testing the New Economic

More information

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter?

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? An Innovative Approach to the Characterisation of the European Political Space. Giovanna Iannantuoni, Elena Manzoni and Francesca Rossi EXTENDED

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Douglas M. Gibler June 2013 Abstract Park and Colaresi argue that they could not replicate the results of my 2007 ISQ article, Bordering

More information

Democratic Tipping Points

Democratic Tipping Points Democratic Tipping Points Antonio Ciccone March 2018 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 1026 Democratic Tipping Points Antonio Ciccone March 2018 Abstract I examine whether transitory

More information

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51 THE IMPACT OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION ON TRADE SHARE AND PER CAPITA GDP: EVIDENCE FROM SUB SAHARAN AFRICA Abdurohman Ali Hussien, Terrasserne 14, 2-256, Brønshøj 2700; Denmark ; abdurohman.ali.hussien@gmail.com

More information

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables?

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables? Andrew D. Martin Washington University admartin@wustl.edu Kevin M. Quinn Harvard University kevin quinn@harvard.edu October 8, 2005 1 Introduction

More information

Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression

Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression EPSY 905: Multivariate Analysis Spring 2016 Lecture #7 March 9, 2016 EPSY 905: Multivariate Regression via Path Analysis Today s Lecture Multivariate

More information

The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads in the Study of Interdependence and Dyadic Disputes

The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads in the Study of Interdependence and Dyadic Disputes Conflict Management and Peace Science, 22:113 133, 2005 Copyright C Peace Science Society (International) ISSN: 0738-8942 print / 1549-9219 online DOI: 10.1080/07388940590948556 The Relevance of Politically

More information

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2012 2012 The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis Shrabani Saha Edith Cowan

More information

Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal

Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal Analysing the relationship between democracy and development: Basic concepts and key linkages Alina Rocha Menocal Team Building Week Governance and Institutional Development Division (GIDD) Commonwealth

More information

Keywords: democracy; diffusion; democratization; regime; income

Keywords: democracy; diffusion; democratization; regime; income 10.1177/0010414005276666 Comparative Brinks, Coppedge Political / Diffusion Studies Is No Illusion Diffusion Is No Illusion Neighbor Emulation in the Third Wave of Democracy Comparative Political Studies

More information

The Macro Polity Updated

The Macro Polity Updated The Macro Polity Updated Robert S Erikson Columbia University rse14@columbiaedu Michael B MacKuen University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill Mackuen@emailuncedu James A Stimson University of North Carolina,

More information

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads 1 Online Appendix for Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads Sarath Balachandran Exequiel Hernandez This appendix presents a descriptive

More information

Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel

Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel Dinuk Jayasuriya and Paul J. Burke Abstract This article investigates whether female political representation affects economic growth.

More information

The Supporting Role of Democracy in Reducing Global Poverty

The Supporting Role of Democracy in Reducing Global Poverty The Supporting Role of Democracy in Reducing Global Poverty Joseph Connors Working Paper no. 16 Department of Economics Wake Forest University connorjs@wfu.edu November 10, 2011 Abstract The Washington

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

Democracy and government spending

Democracy and government spending MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Democracy and government Pavlos Balamatsias 6 March 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86905/ MPRA Paper No. 86905, posted 23 May 2018 19:21 UTC Democracy

More information

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust? Comment on Corak (2013) Bradley J. Setzler 1 Presented to Economics 350 Department of Economics University of Chicago setzler@uchicago.edu January 15, 2014 1 Thanks to James Heckman for many helpful comments.

More information

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? LSE Research Online Article (refereed) Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening? Originally published in Applied economics letters, 10

More information

Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5

Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5 Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5 Centrality and Prestige - Primary goal is identification of the most important actors in a social network. - Prestigious actors are those with large indegrees, or choices received.

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: 1966-2000 Abdurrahman Aydemir Family and Labour Studies Division Statistics Canada aydeabd@statcan.ca 613-951-3821 and Mikal Skuterud

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation Kristen A. Harkness Princeton University February 2, 2011 Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation The process of thinking inevitably begins with a qualitative (natural) language,

More information

Legislatures and Growth

Legislatures and Growth Legislatures and Growth Andrew Jonelis andrew.jonelis@uky.edu 219.718.5703 550 S Limestone, Lexington KY 40506 Gatton College of Business and Economics, University of Kentucky Abstract This paper documents

More information

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be he Nonlinear Relationship Between errorism and Poverty Byline: Poverty and errorism Walter Enders and Gary A. Hoover 1 he fact that most terrorist attacks are staged in low income countries seems to support

More information

III. Wage Inequality and Labour Market Institutions

III. Wage Inequality and Labour Market Institutions Fortin Econ 56 Lecture 3D III. Wage Inequality and Labour Market Institutions D. Labour Market Institutions 1. Overview 2. Effect of Minimum Wages 3. Effect of Unions on Wage Inequality Fortin Econ 56

More information

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W. A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) by Stratford Douglas* and W. Robert Reed Revised, 26 December 2013 * Stratford Douglas, Department

More information

BOOK SUMMARY. Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War. Laia Balcells Duke University

BOOK SUMMARY. Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War. Laia Balcells Duke University BOOK SUMMARY Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War Laia Balcells Duke University Introduction What explains violence against civilians in civil wars? Why do armed groups use violence

More information

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution Per Krusell Institute for International Economic Studies, CEPR, NBER Anthony A. Smith, Jr. Yale University, NBER February 6, 2015 The project

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES

HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES HCEO WORKING PAPER SERIES Working Paper The University of Chicago 1126 E. 59th Street Box 107 Chicago IL 60637 www.hceconomics.org Now You See Me, Now You Don t: The Geography of Police Stops Jessie J.

More information

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix F. Daniel Hidalgo MIT Júlio Canello IESP Renato Lima-de-Oliveira MIT December 16, 215

More information

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015 Powersharing, Protection, and Peace Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm September 17, 2015 Corresponding Author: Yonatan Lupu, Department of Political Science,

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Axel Dreher a Justina A. V. Fischer b November 2010 Economics Letters, forthcoming Abstract Using a country panel of domestic

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Long live your ancestors American dream:

Long live your ancestors American dream: Long live your ancestors American dream: The self-selection and multigenerational mobility of American immigrants Joakim Ruist* University of Gothenburg joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se April 2017 Abstract

More information

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Jérôme Adda Christian Dustmann Joseph-Simon Görlach February 14, 2014 PRELIMINARY and VERY INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper analyses the wage

More information

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention Averyroughdraft.Thankyouforyourcomments. Shannon Carcelli UC San Diego scarcell@ucsd.edu January 22, 2014 1 Introduction Under

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook Digital Commons @ George Fox University Student Scholarship - School of Business School of Business 1-1-2016 Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook Benjamin Antony George Fox University, bantony13@georgefox.edu

More information

Authoritarian Reversals and Democratic Consolidation

Authoritarian Reversals and Democratic Consolidation Authoritarian Reversals and Democratic Consolidation Milan Svolik Abstract I present a new empirical approach to the study of democratic consolidation. This approach leads to new insights into the determinants

More information

A Re-assessment of Democratic Pacifism at the Monadic Level of Analysis

A Re-assessment of Democratic Pacifism at the Monadic Level of Analysis 1 A Re-assessment of Democratic Pacifism at the Monadic Level of Analysis Abstract Extant studies provide inconsistent evidence that democracies are generally more pacific than nondemocracies. Many scholars

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution

Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution Paul Christian (World Bank) and Christopher B. Barrett (Cornell) University of Connecticut November 17, 2017 Background Motivation

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, 1960-2006 Sources: Data based on UCDP/PRIO armed conflict database (N. P. Gleditsch et al., 2002; Harbom & Wallensteen, 2007).

More information

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence Philip Keefer All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth

More information

Does Democracy Promote Transnational Terrorist Incidents?

Does Democracy Promote Transnational Terrorist Incidents? Does Democracy Promote Transnational Terrorist Incidents? QUAN LI Assistant Professor Department of Political Science The Pennsylvania State University 107 Burrowes Building University Park, PA 16802 Email:

More information

The Dynamics of Immigration and Wages

The Dynamics of Immigration and Wages The Dynamics of Immigration and Wages Silvia Helena Barcellos RAND Corporation September, 2009 Abstract The number of immigrants in the US economy has been increasing rapidly in recent decades. An extensive

More information

A Continuous Schumpeterian Conception of Democracy. James Raymond Vreeland Yale University. August 21, Comments Appreciated.

A Continuous Schumpeterian Conception of Democracy. James Raymond Vreeland Yale University. August 21, Comments Appreciated. A Continuous Schumpeterian Conception of Democracy James Raymond Vreeland Yale University August 21, 2003 Comments Appreciated. Abstract Political scientists often require a continuous conception of democracy

More information

Democratic Inefficiency? Regime Type and Sub-optimal Choices in International Politics

Democratic Inefficiency? Regime Type and Sub-optimal Choices in International Politics Democratic Inefficiency? Regime Type and Sub-optimal Choices in International Politics Muhammet A. Bas Department of Government Harvard University Word Count: 10,951 My thanks to Elena McLean, Curtis Signorino,

More information

Hierarchical Item Response Models for Analyzing Public Opinion

Hierarchical Item Response Models for Analyzing Public Opinion Hierarchical Item Response Models for Analyzing Public Opinion Xiang Zhou Harvard University July 16, 2017 Xiang Zhou (Harvard University) Hierarchical IRT for Public Opinion July 16, 2017 Page 1 Features

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

Democratic Waves? Global Patterns of Democratization,

Democratic Waves? Global Patterns of Democratization, Democratic Waves? Global Patterns of Democratization, 1816 2008 Håvard Strand 1, Håvard Hegre 1,2, Scott Gates 1,3, and Marianne Dahl 1 1 Department of Political Science, University of Oslo 2 Centre for

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Electoral Systems and Judicial Review in Developing Countries*

Electoral Systems and Judicial Review in Developing Countries* Electoral Systems and Judicial Review in Developing Countries* Ernani Carvalho Universidade Federal de Pernambuco, Brazil Leon Victor de Queiroz Barbosa Universidade Federal de Campina Grande, Brazil (Yadav,

More information

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Direction of trade and wage inequality This article was downloaded by: [California State University Fullerton], [Sherif Khalifa] On: 15 May 2014, At: 17:25 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number:

More information

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract Author(s): Traugott, Michael Title: Memo to Pilot Study Committee: Understanding Campaign Effects on Candidate Recall and Recognition Date: February 22, 1990 Dataset(s): 1988 National Election Study, 1989

More information

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector Pierre Mérel and Zach Rutledge July 7, 2017 Abstract This paper provides new estimates of the short-run impacts of

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY Over twenty years ago, Butler and Heckman (1977) raised the possibility

More information

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005) , Partisanship and the Post Bounce: A MemoryBased Model of Post Presidential Candidate Evaluations Part II Empirical Results Justin Grimmer Department of Mathematics and Computer Science Wabash College

More information

Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals

Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals Chapter 1 Introduction and Goals The literature on residential segregation is one of the oldest empirical research traditions in sociology and has long been a core topic in the study of social stratification

More information