LAND REFORM AND PEASANT REVOLUTION: EVIDENCE FROM 1930s SPAIN. Abstract: We analyze the impact of failed land reform on peasant conflict in Spain

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "LAND REFORM AND PEASANT REVOLUTION: EVIDENCE FROM 1930s SPAIN. Abstract: We analyze the impact of failed land reform on peasant conflict in Spain"

Transcription

1 LAND REFORM AND PEASANT REVOLUTION: EVIDENCE FROM 1930s SPAIN Jordi Domenech, U. Carlos III de Madrid Francisco Herreros, Spanish Higher Scientific Council Abstract: We analyze the impact of failed land reform on peasant conflict in Spain before the Civil War using a novel, municipal data set with monthly observations of peasant conflict from April 1931 to July We find temporary occupations of land were rare and not correlated with either organized reaction to land reform or the existence of a large pool of beneficiaries. Potential beneficiaries of reform struck more often in the first period of land reform. There is some evidence that effective land reform implementation reduced strikes, in towns with a legacy of domination by a noble family. We argue both sets of evidence suggest faster re-distribution would have reduced conflict. Keywords: land reform, conflict, revolution, re-distribution, property rights, peasantry, agrarian economies 1 Introduction Does land reform cause greater levels of rural conflict? According to the literature on political regimes and transitions, re-distributive policies can appease bottom-up revolutionary pressures and social conflict (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2005). While developed economies re-distribute by taxing wealth and on income and giving away 1

2 social transfers, in developing economies characterized by a large presence of the agricultural sector, re-distributive policies have generally taken the form of land reform. However, it has been argued that drastic land ownership re-distribution can sometimes create more conflict. Democratization and the deployment of pro-poor policies generally go hand in hand with a reduction of repression favoring the collective action of peasants. Land reform, in addition, rises the expectations of peasants, which leads to more demands from this social group that, if not met, can increase the levels of conflict (Finkel, Ghelbach, Olsen, 2015: 985). However, it is also the case that conflict arises out of the state s inability to deploy land reform. As land is the main asset in agrarian economies and land is illiquid and immobile, land reform creates sharply defined groups of winners and losers (Luebbert, 1991; Boone, 2014). In this context, winners will do whatever it takes to speed up reform, while losers have every incentive to block reform. When this is the case, the logic of collective action favors landowners, who form a cohesive, small and wealthy group able to co-ordinate collective action more effectively. The ability of landed elites to block reform means that, unless revolution, conquest or unconstrained executive power precede land reform, land reform can be unenforceable. With the patience of the landless wearing thin, failed land reform can trigger peasant rebellions, revolution, and civil wars. The existing empirical studies point at the conflict enhancing effects of incomplete land reforms. In Colombia, the positive effects of land reform on rural insurgency were largely circumscribed to large-scale reform in lands threatened by 2

3 guerrilla activity, with incomplete land reform increasing conflict elsewhere (Albertus and Kaplan, 2013). In Russia after 1861, local elites captured land reform causing dissatisfaction with the terms and pace of reform and widespread conflict (Finkel, Ghelbach and Olsen, 2015: 985). In Brazil, invasions of farms by squatters and other forms of violent conflict were a mechanism to force state actors to enforce or speed up land reform (Alston, Libecap and Mueller, 1999, 2000). In all cases, partial land reform increases peasant conflict. Spain in the 1930s has been included among the cases of failed and incomplete land reform, associated with landlord resistance, bottom-up mobilization of the landless peasantry, revolution, and civil war. The classic historical study on the period bears the self-explanatory title Agrarian Reform and Peasant Revolution. Origins of the Civil War (Malefakis, 1970). More recently, a leading expert on 1930s Spain argued that peasant radicalization happened when it became clear how slowly agrarian reform was progressing (Casanova, 2010: 47). Expectations generated by land reform led to conflict and violence in those areas where peasants would have benefitted the most from reform. Yet, to our knowledge, no systematic test of the impact of land reform on rural conflict and peasant collective action in 1930s Spain has been so far undertaken. In this paper, we present a novel data set of local rural strikes and conflict in two latifundia provinces of Spain, the provinces of Jaén and Córdoba, in the period Both experienced substantial variation in local levels of conflict and degrees of local exposure to land reform legislation and land reform implementation. 3

4 We contribute to the literature on the direct impacts of partial land reforms on rural conflict in two ways. Firstly, we add to this literature a case of land reform under democracy. The comparative literature on land reform under democracies shows that a minimal degree of institutional quality and democratic rules slow down ambitious redistributive democratic agendas (Albertus, 2015; Bardhan and Mokherjee, 2010). At the same time, greater protection of workers rights and softer repression means various segments of the working class, including the rural laborers, could organize more easily (Domenech, 2013). In addition the position of the owners of land was much weaker than in the other cases in the literature. Second, land reform happens at various stages from low- to mid-levels of development with important variation in levels of state capacity. Here we address the case of a state at higher levels of capacity than is usually the case in countries after revolution or war, and also with higher capacity than the Russian state in the second half of the 19 th century or many Latin American states in the 20 th. 2 Land Reform in 1930s Spain Democratization in April 1931 resulted in the weakening of landed elites and the emergence of a dominant coalition favorable to large-scale land ownership redistribution towards tenants and laborers. As a result, article 44 of the December 1931 Spanish constitution claimed national wealth (...) is subordinated to the interests of the national economy (...) Property can be socialized. Some of the initial laws of the new government offered greater protection to rural tenants. There were several interventions in rural labor markets like laws limiting the mobility of laborers during harvest months (Domenech, 2013). A Land Reform law was passed in September

5 The Law was circumscribed to 14 provinces in Central and Southern Spain, more specifically in Andalusia and Extremadura and in the provinces of Ciudad Real, Toledo, Albacete (in New Castile) and Salamanca (in Old Castile). The Institute of Agrarian Reform (IRA, Instituto de Reforma Agraria) was the government body in charge of implementing land reform. In the paper, we exploit characteristics of the law as to which farms were to be expropriated and who was going to benefit for redistribution to generate variation in the intensity of land reform treatment. Article 5 gave a detailed description of the types of farms that could be confiscated. Clauses 12 and 13 of article 5 were the most consequential. Clause 12 stipulated that farms that had been leased for 12 or more consecutive years could be expropriated. Clause 13 established upper limits to the size of farms, with these sizes finally determined by each IRA provincial committee on the basis of soil characteristics and crops. Articles 6 and 7 of the law defined the exceptions (communal lands) and created the register or inventory of farms to be expropriated giving each IRA provincial committee a year to complete the task of identifying and registering the farms to be confiscated. We use local information from the Inventory of Expropriable Land, as well as information on farm sizes and land ownership inequality to proxy the local level of land re-distribution, as well as the level of pre-reform local inequality. Articles 10 of the law stipulated the creation of a Peasant census, which would be the basis for settlements on expropriated land. The Census counted the number of laborers, tenants and small owners in the towns affected by the law. We construct local measures of the number of beneficiaries from land reform using information from this Census. 5

6 In the paper, we will exploit differences in land reform implementation to analyze the effect of land reform deployment on conflict. The work of the Juntas Provinciales started without significant delays in 1933, so that by late 1933 an Inventory of Expropriable Property was completed. In Andalusia, and more specifically in the provinces studied in this paper, land reform had the potential to alter dramatically the existing distribution of ownership. In the province of Córdoba Malefakis estimated 47 per cent of cultivated lands was affected by land reform (Malefakis, 1970: 210). In Córdoba, 88 per cent of the land earmarked for expropriation fell under clause 13, i.e. farms exceeding the thresholds of maximum farm size (López and Mata, 1993: 42; Pérez Yruela, 1979: 260). This ratio was 79 per cent in Jaén. In the immediate years after the passing of reform, progress was modest. In the provinces targeted by reform, only 8,600 families had settled on expropriated properties by the end of Only 211 landless families had been settled by the end of 1933 in Córdoba and probably 205 in Jáen (Malefakis, 1970: 281). In 1934, only an extra 534 peasant families were settled (López and Mata, 1993: 102). In Jaén, the progress of land reform was even more limited. Temporary seizures of land via decrees of intensification of cultivation (laboreo forzoso) were often used in Extremadura (South West of Spain), with temporary settlements of 32,570 families on 98,355 hectares by October But intensification of cultivation was very sparsely used in Córdoba and Jaén, we only find 100 peasant families settled on meager 280 hectares under temporary seizures of land (Malefakis, 1970: 242). 6

7 In February 1936 a coalition of Leftist parties won the general election and started in earnest to accelerate expropriations. Only in March and April of 1936, more than 400,000 hectares were seized and over 94,000 families were settled. From April to July, an extra 111,000 families were settled on 572,000 hectares of land. But, as in 1933, the largest number of settlements happened in Extremadura (83,767 peasant families and an 85 per cent of the peasant census). In comparison, there was a more modest number of settlements in Andalusia. The expropriation of 34,395 hectares in Córdoba made possible the settlement of 5,300 families, about 10 % of landless household heads in the Peasant census of the province. In Jaén, 693 families settled on 8,271 hectares in Jaén, only 2 per cent of the recorded number of landless households in the Census of Peasants (Malefakis, 1970: 378; Robledo, 2014: 77; Garrido, 1979: 25). Such low figures for Córdoba and Jaén underline the very limited progress of land reform in Andalusia until the Civil War ( ). Things changed quickly in the first months of the war with quick collectivizations of land in areas controlled by the Republican government. Some historical studies estimate 65 per cent of land was expropriated in Jaén and 24 per cent in Córdoba. In the case of Jaén, about 80 per cent of the confiscated land was exploited collectively by peasant co-operatives (Martínez Ruiz, 2006: 130). 3 Data This paper studies the Southern provinces of Jaén and Córdoba to understand the determinants of rural conflict in Spain before the Civil War. High land ownership inequality, extensive plans to confiscate the lands of the largest landowners, and high 7

8 rural conflict characterize both provinces, although there is substantial local variation in both rural conflict (the dependent variable) and in the local impact of land reform. Both provinces have been the subject of very detailed historical studies on rural conflict (Pérez Yruela, 1979; Cobo Romero, 1992, 2003). We use these to compute monthly local indices of conflict. Our analysis necessarily stops in July 1936, when the civil war broke out. After the general strike of peasants organized by the FNTT in June 1934, the number of strikes collapsed to almost zero, as many union offices were closed. Strikes and conflicts resumed at a lower level after the Popular Front victory of February We exclude from the analysis the period of complete repression of peasant collective action from July 1934 to January-February a Dependent variable. We measure local rural conflict from April 1931 (the start of the Second Republic) to July We have a continuous panel of 39 consecutive months from April 1931 to June 1934 (both included) and a second period from March 1936 to July 1936 (both included). We first consider land invasions and other attacks on established property rights property, from temporary seizures of land to trespassing by groups of organized peasants. We find no evidence of illegal squatting and temporary occupations of land, so our first conflict measure considers short invasions of farms by groups of peasants with the purpose of damaging crops, enforcing picket lines, performing unsolicited tasks in a farm, or gleaning. Our second variable of interest is peasant strikes. We first look at the extensive margin, with the variable taking value 1 if a strike or more started in a dyad month-town 8

9 and 0 otherwise. We also look at the intensive margin by looking at the number of days on strike in each municipality-month dyad and the number of times peasant strikes in every municipality-month dyad appeared in newspapers. We compute monthly estimates of impact of peasant strikes in each town-month dyad as a weighted average of the number of hits in each month using the following formula: Total impact in municipality i in month t= (.25*hits in the provincial press) + (.75*hits in newspapers in other provinces) for strikes of municipality i in month t. Our main sources are the detailed historiography on 1930s rural conflict in the two provinces and Boolean searches for each town in digitized contemporary newspapers of the period (see online appendix, section A.1). Maps 1 to 4 display the spatial variation in the dependent variables. To construct those maps, we add up all instances of conflict at the extensive and intensive margin to construct local estimates of conflict in the period Map 1 shows the pattern of land invasions and related conflicts at the extensive margin. Map 2 displays local count of strikes for the period. Maps 3 and 4 display intensive margins of strike intensity (cumulative counts for each municipality of days on strike and newspaper hits). Compared to "invasions", strikes at both the extensive and intensive margin were more concentrated in several areas in the province of Córdoba (left half of the map), especially in the towns surrounding the city of Córdoba and in the so-called Campiña region to the South-East of the capital. Other towns in the province away from this cluster also throw a large number of conflicts (like in Villanueva de Córdoba in the 9

10 North East of the province or Palma del Río in the South west). In the case of Jaén, strikes cluster in the area of Villanueva del Arzobispo and Villacarrillo in the North East of the province and Alcalá la Real and Alcaudete in the South Western part of the province. INSERT MAPS 1-4 HERE 3.b Independent variables. Land reform treatment intensity: The main hypothesis in the literature is that land reform triggers high levels of conflict, especially when it is not comprehensively deployed and enforced. We consider two treatment periods. A first one starts with the deployment of the land reform law of September The second with the acceleration of land reform after the victory of the Popular Front in the elections of February Defining the window for the first period is fairly arbitrary and we have experimented with several treatment windows. We present results using a window from April 1933, when provincial IRA committees were constituted (López and Mata, 1993: 95) to June The second treatment window (of quickly deployed land reform) goes from March 1936 to July 1936, coinciding with the months of the Popular Front government. In the case of the first period, our main results are robust to the choice of different treatment windows (in the online appendix we offer results with alternative treatment windows October 1932-June 1934 and December 1933-June 1934). We start by assuming there was a general effect of partial land on the landless. We use several proxies of the intensity of land reform treatment. In all cases, the intensity of treatment during the period in which land reform was active is in fact very 10

11 strongly related to inequality, both in terms of land ownership inequality and social structure. We can use pre-treatment estimates of inequality as a proxy for expected land reform in the treatment period. We will label the various proxies of inequality and land reform intensity in town i INEQUALITY!. Firstly, we identify intensity of treatment to the potential supply of expropriable land. We expect in these towns with a larger share of available land could have more invasions and trespassing than in towns with a smaller supply of available land. At the same time, the presence of a small and cohesive group of landowners in the most unequal towns meant unequal municipalities could have seen greater landowner collective action and more resistance to land reform implementation (Albertus, Brambor and Ceneviva, 2016). This could at the same time depress and spur the organization of the landless peasantry. Secondly, we proxy the intensity of land reform treatment via the demand-side by looking at the share of potential beneficiaries of land reform in the local population. Because beneficiaries were empowered by reform or perhaps, because they were not satisfied with the pace of reform, we expect that towns with a larger share of beneficiaries to see more conflict, both in terms of strikes and short invasions. Finally, we interact both supply-side and demand-side measures of treatment intensity to capture the degree of polarization, expecting conflict to be highest where there is a greater proportion of beneficiaries of land reform and a small number landowners. Typically, polarization leads to more conflict (Esteban and Schneider, 2008; Esteban and Ray, 2008). 11

12 In a second set of regressions, we allow for the existence of two different treatment effects. To a first effect of land reform intensity, we add a second effect of land reform deployment. The expectation is that conditional on the ex ante level of land re-distribution, the deployment of re-distribution reduced conflict vis-à-vis the towns with no deployment. We code a dummy variable taking value 1 if the town saw some land reform deployment during the period of preparation and implementation of land reform and 0 otherwise. This was generally the case in towns with farms owned by Grandee families in and 1936 and with towns in which some farms were temporary seized under the decrees of laboreo forzoso (compulsory cultivation) during the government of the Popular Front. We circumscribe the analysis to the province of Córdoba because there were very few families settled in the province of Jaén throughout the period. To capture measurements of the intensity of the land reform treatment based on the amount of potentially expropriable land, we look at various dimensions of prereform land ownership inequality. We start with cadastral information given in Carrión (1975 [1932)]. The Cadastre was compiled in the provinces analyzed here in the early 1920s (Pro, 1992) and Carrión (1975) used this information to compile the share of local area taken by farms of more than 250 hectares ( % area ). Because the lower bound of maximum farm size was established by the 1932 law at 300 hectares for cereal growing areas, we can use Carrión s estimates to measure pre-treatment inequality and the expected level of reform intensity in each municipality. Still from Carrión (1975), we retrieve the share of total taxable agricultural income taken by landowners with a taxable income from land above 5,000 pesetas per year ( % tax ). Carrión (1975) 12

13 estimated medium-sized properties had a taxable income of 1,000 to 3,000 pesetas per year. Therefore, '% tax' would be an estimate of local land ownership inequality, which also takes into account variation in the productivity of land. In addition, we use information from the Inventory of Expropriable Farms Registro de la Propiedad Expropriable- compiled in 1933 by IRA agronomists (Pérez Yruela, 1979, ; Garrido González, 1990: 382-4). The Inventory was a register of farms earmarked for confiscation on the basis of the various causes of confiscation established in article 5 of the law of the land reform of September Using this data we construct indices of local exposure of land reform as the ratio of total expropriable area to total local area. We approximate the intensity of exposure to land reform by looking at the demand for land reform proxied by the number of potential beneficiaries in each town. The IRA collected a Peasant Census in to establish the number of landless or near landless families that had to be settled. This Census gives a count of household heads in various peasant groups (laborers, tenants, and small owners) (Brel and González, 2013). We extract the number of peasants and calculate the local ratio of poor peasant household heads as a proportion of the overall population ( % poor ). We do the same with the share of household heads classified as rural laborers in the total population ( % laborers ). Both are measures of local inequality and the share of potential beneficiaries of land reform in the local population. 13

14 Finally, we look at interactions of the supply- and demand-side to capture the effect of polarization (high land inequality and a large number of beneficiaries). Here we present results with the interaction ( %expropriable ) and ( %laborers ). The three sources (Cadastre, Inventory, and Peasant Census) have gaps, with information missing in some towns. Of 164 towns in the data set, the Peasant Census does not report information on 16. In Carrión (1975), there is missing information on 33 towns. There is no information collected for the 34 towns in the Inventory of Expropriable Farms. In section A.2. of the on-line appendix A2, we discuss the potential biases introduced in our database from missing sources. We conclude that there are selection biases but that the most unequal towns are not excluded from the data set, suggesting that the assets and income of the wealthiest families were not being hidden. Because selection biases most probably eliminate the most egalitarian towns from the analysis. In order to avoid losing observations and introducing selection biases, we give a 0 value to towns with missing information for the exposure variables collected from incomplete sources. In addition, we have coded a dummy variable taking value 1 if the town was missing in the source used to compile that variable. 3.c Controls. The analysis takes into account several controls. We include local population in 1930 to take into account that there might be reporting bias in favor of larger towns. In addition, peasants living in larger towns might have spillovers from the collective action in other sectors, translating into better organization or more capacity for collective action. Greater population is also correlated with observed and unobserved locational advantages like better land, more water, or greater access to markets. We also include the productivity of land as a control, proxying with average 14

15 soil quality in the town. We construct a Soil Quality Index using information from FAO s Harmonized World Soil Database, which gives information on average soil qualities for grids of 30-arc seconds (a horizontal grid spacing of 30-arc seconds represents degrees or approximately 1 km). 1 Using the formula by Brady and Weil (2008), the index is the average of 5 topsoil properties normalized to an index that ranges from 0 to 10. The entire index is then multiplied by 10 to vary between 0 and 100. SQI =!! S!!!!! 10 Finally, we throw in several geographical controls like average altitude, longitude and latitude, to control for unobserved characteristics plausible correlated with these variables. This for example could the case of the propensity of local collective action to be repressed (since repression is more difficult in isolated and rugged terrain) or unobserved income and wealth effects associated with variation in crops and water supply. 4 Panel regressions, We now turn to the statistical analysis. We start with simple difference-in-difference regressions in the panel April 1931-July 1936, with the period of harsh repression from July 1934 to February 1936 excluded from the panel. Our first model looks at the effect of expected land re-distribution on peasant protest, without taking into account the very limited amount of land reform deployment in and 1936 for towns with Grandee property

16 Y!,! = α + β! INEQUALITY! + β! (INEQUALITY! period 1) +β! (INEQUALITY! period 2) + β! period 1 + β! period 2 + γx! + δz! + μ!,! [1] Where Y!,! is the conflict variable, measured at the extensive (one conflict event or more observed in a given month) or at the intensive margin (number of days on strike per month or number of newspaper hits per month), INEQUALITY! is the variable measuring the level of inequality before the treatment period and the intensity of land reform treatment. Period 1 and 2 are dummy variables capturing the treatment windows. Period 1 is a dummy variable taking value 1 for all towns between April 1933 and June 1934 (both included) and 0 in other months. Period 2 is a dummy variable taking value 1 for all observations between March 1936 and July 1936 and 0 otherwise. Regression results with alternative treatment windows in the first period can be found in the online appendix (section A.5). X! captures time-invariant characteristics of towns, such as population in 1930, average soil quality, and geographical controls like altitude, latitude and longitude. Z! is a linear trend for the 44 months included in the analysis from April 1931 to July 1936 and 11 dummies for each month except January. μ!,! is an error term. In the case of time-series, cross-sectional data like the ones used here, serial autocorrelation and the structure of lags are serious problems. Beck (2001) and Beck and Katz (1995) recommend lagging the dependent variable and using unit and time dummies and clustered standard errors as quick fixes. Plümper, Troeger and Manow (2005) dispute this as the included variables absorb potentially important time-series 16

17 variation. In the appendix, section A.4, we report estimates with extra controls for serial and spatial correlation. It is important to clarify that coefficients β! and β!, the treatment effects of land reform intensity in periods 1 (April 1933-June 1934) and period 2 (March-July 1936). do not measure the impact of land reform in towns with high inequality and a large share of landless peasantry relative to a period in which potential beneficiaries did not anticipate land reform. Rather, we have to see the pre-treatment period as one in which potential beneficiaries expected land reform, but were not aware land reform was going to fail. It is generally the case that peasant collective action is repressed in periods with no land reform, therefore comparisons between periods with land reform, when repression is often lifted, and others with repressed peasant collective action would require the estimation of latent conflict propensities in the period of delayed reform. In addition, the validity of our differences-in-differences framework would be compromised if peasants anticipated in (pre-treatment period) a slow and incomplete land reform. However, there is no reason to think this was the case. The 2 nd Republic was welcomed euphorically by the working classes. There were no comparable historical periods of democratic governments trying to implement ambitious plans of land reform. Most peasants were confident that the time of reparto (redistribution) had come. Before we move on to the estimation of equation [1], we display the conflict data to see if the hypothesis that land reform increased conflict in the treatment period has some real empirical basis. Figures 1 and 2 plot strike propensities (extensive 17

18 margin) for the second and top quartiles of our measure of land reform intensity, INEQUALITY!, measured from the demand-side (% laborers) and the supply side (% expropriable). Both figure 1 and figure 2 suggest that the various estimates of INEQUALITY! were largely irrelevant to explain protest in the pre-treatment period ( ). There is an intensification of conflict in 1933 and 1934 and conflict in this period intensified more prominently at higher levels of INEQUALITY!. However, the differences of mean strike propensities at different quartiles of land reform are not statistically significant. In the second treatment period in March-July 1936, peasant conflict remained at low levels and measures of expected re-distribution were irrelevant to explain protest. We have not reported figures with the intensive margin of strikes because they look similar to those based on the extensive margin. Figure 3 reports the mean propensity to invade measured at the second and fourth quartiles of INEQUALITY!. Data here tell a slightly different story than in figures 1-2, although in this case the choice of months May-June might not be ideal for invasions. As in the previous cases, expected land reform does not seem to affect conflict in the pre-treatment period, nor does it affect invasions in the Popular Front period (period 2, March 1936-July 1936). For May and June in 1931 and 1936, our data set reports zero cases of "invasion". In treatment period 1, 1933 does not see an intensification of conflict, whereas 1934 saw a large increase with respect to the other years. Invasion propensity is higher the higher the potential for land reform, yet standard errors of mean invasion probabilities are very large, especially for the second quartile of '% laborers'. On the basis of figures 1 and 2, it would seem there is some basis for the claim that the credible promise of land reform in and in 1936 reduced peasant conflict and that the delays in land reform in intensified 18

19 conflict. However, this needs to be qualified by the visual evidence for invasions and trespassing displayed in figure 3, which lends much weaker support to the hypothesis linking failed land reform and peasant conflict. INSERT FIGURES 1, 2 AND 3 We now turn to the statistical analysis. In table 1, presents the summary statistics of the main variables used in the regressions. Table 2 displays the main correlations. There is a high correlation between the various definitions of strikes and the extensive and intensive margins, as well as the various definitions of the land reform exposure variable (INEQUALITY! ), especially in the case of our supply-side measures of treatment intensity are % area, % tax and % expropriable, as defined in section 3.a.: INSERT TABLES 1 AND 2 PLEASE In table 3, we present estimations of a linear probability model with a dummy variable taking value 1 if peasants entered illegally one or more large estates in town i in month t and zero otherwise. Despite the difficulties in collecting instances of invasions and the necessarily arbitrary definition of these events, we consider invasions a more genuine example of explicit challenges to authority than strikes. When analyzing the extensive margin of invasions (and peasant strikes below), the variable is dichotomous, so that panel logit or probit models could be used. However, the hypothesis tested here requires that our estimated equations have several 19

20 interacted variables that compromise the interpretation of marginal effects (Ai and Norton, 2003). Table 3 displays the regressions with several approaches to measuring INEQUALITY! : in columns I, II, III we proxy intensity of treatment from the supply of land, columns IV and V from the demand for land reform and in columns VI and VII with an interacted supply-demand term capturing polarization. We expect the coefficients on the different measurements of INEQUALITY! for the pre-treatment period, β!, to be positive, although the link between land ownership inequality and conflict has been elusive (Albertus, Brambor and Ceneviva, 2016; Biswanger, Deininger, and Feder, 1995). β! and β! test the main hypothesis of the paper for period 1 and 2 respectively: did the slow and defective deployment land reform increase conflict in towns with a high level of expected re-distribution of land? In this case, do we observe more invasions in towns with a high level of expected re-distribution because there was a large percentage of underexploited land in large estates, because there was a large number of beneficiaries or because there was a lot of underexploited land and a large number of beneficiaries? In the case of invasions, the answer to these questions is no, for every measurement of land reform treatment intensity. Table 3 gives the coefficients. PLEASE INSERT TABLE 3 HERE The explanatory power of the model in the case of invasions is limited, perhaps because invasions were less common than assumed in the literature. Our main hypothesis cannot be confirmed in the case of invasions. Invasions were rare in the period and they did not follow a pattern related to the intensity of expected land reform. None of the specifications throws statistically significant coefficients β!, β! and β!. β!, 20

21 which measures the effect of INEQUALITY! on invasions in the pre-treatment period, is generally positive in line with the expectation that inequality increases conflict, but always statistically insignificant (columns I to VII in table 3). β!, the estimate of the treatment effect in period 1 (April 1933-June 1934), is always negative in the case of supply side measures of INEQUALITY! (columns I, II, III of table 3), positive in the case of demand side measures (columns IV and V) and positive and negative in the case of polarization (columns VI and VII). β!, the estimate of the treatment effect of land reform in period 2, is in most cases negative (decreasing conflict), especially in the case of demand-side measures of the intensity of land reform treatment, although the coefficients remain statistically insignificant in all specifications. Perhaps the acceleration of land reform under the Popular Front slightly reduced the propensity of peasants to invade, yet the effect is small and not distinguishable from zero. Finally, across specifications, only the coefficient on variable population in 1930 is consistently positive and statistically different from zero, perhaps reflecting genuine effects of larger towns (more militancy, more information) or reporting biases in the evidence. What do we make of these coefficients? Negative β coefficients do not lend support to the view that local landowner collective action to resist land reform drove peasants to more invasions. The estimated effects of polarization on invasions do not cohere. Finally, potential beneficiaries invaded more often, despite the statistically insignificant results, which would be partially consistent with explanations of peasant protest based on a change of landless peasants' expectations caused by land reform. 21

22 Table 4 displays the evidence for the extensive margin of peasant strikes. In this case, our dependent variable is a dichotomous variable taking value 1 if there was at least one recorded peasant strike in town i and month t and 0 if there was none. As in table 3, we use a linear probability model to predict the occurrence of strikes. PLEASE INSERT TABLE 4 The explanatory power of models displayed in table 4 is higher than in the case of invasions. In the pre-treatment period, regressions throw negative coefficients β! when the variable is measured using the supply of expropriable land (columns I, II and III of table 3). Isolated towns with a large share of underexploited, expropriable land were far from ideal hotbeds of peasant collective action in the period preceding land reform. In contrast, β! is positive (although statistically insignificant) when INEQUALITY! is measured from the demand side (potential beneficiaries of reform) (columns IV and V), whereas the signs of coefficients are less coherent when the intensity of treatment is proxied by polarization (columns VI and VII). The coefficient β!, capturing the treatment effect of delayed land reform in treatment period 1, is negative for the supply-side measures of INEQUALITY!, in line with the results of table 3. Moreover, as in table 3, when the intensity of treatment is measured from the demand side (the share of potential beneficiaries of future redistribution), β!, the treatment effect of delayed land reform in period 1, flips to positive and in the case of % laborers statistically significant at the 1 per cent level. For the polarization measures, regressions throw both a positive and a negative β! coefficient. Estimated β! coefficients are consistent with table 3, local resistance to 22

23 reform was not correlated with an increase in peasant strikes, whereas the fact that the share of laborers predicts more strikes in the periods of land reform deployment strongly suggests an explanation based on changing expectations of the landless peasantry are not off the mark. Continuing with other results in table 4, for period 2, from March 1936-July 1936, the estimated coefficients send a noisier signal. The estimate of the treatment effect in the second period, β!, bounces more often from negative to positive sign and is not statistically significant. As in table 3, we find the coefficient on population is always statistically significant at the 1 per cent level in all specifications, suggesting there were large reporting biases favoring big towns or that there was something specific about larger towns (spillovers from other sectors perhaps, more information, greater market access, and unobserved locational advantages -water, access to transport routes, etc.) leading to higher strike propensity. The positive impact of size appears in other studies of rural protest, although reporting biases with this kind of information would not be surprising (Hobsbawm and Rudé, 1973; Markoff, 1985, 1986; Blair, Blattman, Hartman, 2015). The fertility of the soil has also a positive relationship with strike propensity and other forms of conflict (Finkel, Ghelbach, Olsen, 2015: 1010). Going back to our estimates of the coefficient β!, the estimated coefficient when INEQUALITY is proxied by the share of laborers in the first treatment period is When performing the various robustness checks, coefficients ranges between.0016 and.004, in most cases being able to reject the null hypothesis of the coefficient being zero with a confidence level above 95 %. 23

24 This effect is robust to the use of different treatment windows and is closely related to land reform, not to changes in the dominant political coalition and a more prolandowner policy after the general election of November This is apparent when we use different treatment windows. Using a first treatment window starting right after the passing of reform in October 1932 until June 1934, our estimate of the treatment effect using the share of laborers is.0024 and is statistically significant at the 5 per cent level (table A5.1 in the online appendix). For a window for period 1 going from December 1933 to June 1934, which would capture the change towards a political coalition opposed to reform, we get an estimate of.0018 with a p-value of.26 (table A5.2 in the online appendix). Despite the robustness of the coefficient estimates, the size of the effect is not at first sight large. A coefficient of.003 in table 4 column V means a one standard deviation increase in the share of laborers ( % laborers ) brings only an increase in 1.6 probability points in the probability of striking, which is only 6 % of the standard deviation in the extensive margin of strikes. However, this small coefficient is in fact caused by a compositional effect. For almost three quarters of the year, there is no relationship between the share of laborers and strikes, because, in several months of the year, municipalities report zero strikes. In contrast, in months in which strikes and the share of laborers are linked, the implicit coefficient is much higher. This is immediately obvious if we estimate the treatment effect of the share of laborers in period 1, β!, for each month separately. From January to June (included) the coefficient is close to zero, in the second half of the year it is much higher, especially in July and August. Figure 4 displays the coefficients estimated for each month separately. A coefficient of estimated for July and August, means an increase in one standard deviation increase in 24

25 the share of laborers increases the probability of strikes by 6-7 probability points, which is almost a third of the standard deviation in the extensive margin of strikes for those months. INSERT FIGURE 4 In table 5, we report the coefficient estimates of equation [1] using the intensive margin of strikes. In this case, our dependent variable is the number of days peasants were on strike in town i in month t. Coefficient estimates confirm to a large extent the conclusions of table 4 now for the intensive margin. As in table 4, coefficients β! in the pre-treatment period are negative when we consider the share of expropriable land and positive for the share of potential beneficiaries, although as in table 4 the coefficients are not statistically significant. The treatment effect in the first period (April 1933-June 1934), β!, is generally negative for the supply-side measures of the intensity of land reform treatment and positive for the measurements of treatment intensity based on the demand side. The coefficient for the share of laborers is positive and significant at the 1 per cent level. For estimations of β! using the share of laborers to proxy INEQUALITY!, we get point estimates ranging from.015 to in tables 5 and table A3.2 in the appendix. These estimates imply a standard deviation increase in the share of laborers increases the number of days on strike by a tenth of a day (.09). As in the case of the extensive margin of strikes, the small number responds to a compositional effect as many months register very low strike activity, suggesting effects in particular months might be large. 25

26 When we restrict our observations to the month of August, the estimated effect is.071, meaning a one standard deviation increase in the share of laborers brings almost an extra half day on strike per month and 25 per cent of the standard deviation in days. Similar to the regressions with the extensive margin of strikes, β! does not have a coherent direction for measures of polarization. In line with coefficients in table 4, the sign of the treatment effect in the second period, β!, goes in different directions without a clear pattern and is not statistically significant. Table 5 reinforces the conclusion that potential beneficiaries of land reform struck more often and for longer in the first period of implementation. Unreported regressions using the weighted number of newspaper hits on peasant strikes in town i and month t instead of the number of days of strikes also tell a very similar story (these regressions can be found in the online appendix). INSERT TABLE 5 Results in tables 3, 4, and 5 show that the first period of implementation of land reform saw greater number of strikes in. For both and 1936, perhaps a credible promise of re-distribution meant there was a reduction in levels of conflict. In the case of strikes and invasions, the negative coefficients on the supply side measurements of INEQUALITY! mean that peasant collective action was not stronger where landowners had greater capacity to resist land reform (Domenech, 2015). The fact that demand side proxies of INEQUALITY! get a positive coefficients, especially in the case of strikes, could suggest land reform can increase conflict by changing the expectations of beneficiaries of reform. However, what tables 3, 4, and 5 do not clarify is whether land reform by itself lifted the expectations of peasants or whether it was its failure what 26

27 galvanized the collective action of peasants. In other words, would the deployment of reform have appeased peasants? In the next section, we attempt to clarify this point. 4 Limited Land reform implementation in Córdoba In section 2 we have shown how land reform implementation was very limited in Córdoba and Jaén.. However, in towns with surviving estates from Grandes de España, peasants saw the promise of land reform did in fact materialize, irrespective of the slow deployment of settlements. There, some large estates were expropriated, tenants were expelled plots were assigned to landless families. A credible promise of re-distribution should have appeased landless peasants' protests. The problem with the analysis of deployment the very limited number of experiments with expropriations, which were only tried in towns with Grandeza property that could be expropriated quickly without a lengthy and costly compensation process. In the early modern period, Grandee noble families held sway over large tracts of land in Andalusia, as did the King, the Church and religious-military orders (like the orders of Santiago or of Calatrava). The Church and the religious-military orders were dispossessed of their lands in the mid nineteenth century, especially after the land reform of Pascual Madoz in Despite the formal abolition of jurisdictions controlled by noble families, or señoríos, in the early nineteenth century, many noble families retained their economic, social and political clout over many towns and villages through their large holdings of land, their control over the electoral process and their actions as main employers or landlords of the local peasantry. However, there had been a progressive break-up of latifundia in the 19 th and early 20 th centuries (Bernal, 1988: 91-93; Díaz del Moral, 1973) and relatively efficient land markets also re-distributed 27

28 land to the most efficient producers (Carmona, Rosés, Simpson, 2015). As a result, land owned by Grandeza in both provinces represented 6 % in the province of Córdoba and 7.4 % in the province of Jaén (Robledo, 2012: 383) and was clearly insufficient to settle all peasants. We examine the effect of implementation by focusing on the limited set of towns with expropriated Grandeza property. It was characteristic of these towns that they also had abundant land relative to the number of landless laborers, perhaps making settlements technically feasible. Table 6 displays all towns with a legacy on being ruled by a noble family in the early modern period (noble jurisdiction) comparing towns with estates owned by Grandes de España before expropriation and those without. This second group would reflect the experience of municipalities that had historically been under the jurisdiction of some Grandeza family. Table 6 shows that towns with surviving Grandee farms had similar social structure (% laborers) than towns with a legacy of being under the jurisdiction of a noble family, but crucially they also had abundant expropriable land. Compared to other towns with past noble jurisdiction, towns with expropiated Grandeza ownership had higher means of the share of large estates, share of tax paid by the largest landowners and share of expropriable land, they were also more polarized. These differences, despite small sample sizes, are statistically significant. INSERT TABLE 6 In order to show there is something going on with land reform deployment and conflict, we plot the rates of growth in protests for different quartiles of INEQUALITY! 28

29 comparing towns with and without land reform implementation in the province of Córdoba. In Figure 5, we display strike propensities only for the months of May-June before and during the deployment of land reform. As in the previous cases, the confidence intervals are very large for the means of treated towns (because we have to rely on a small set of month-town observations to make years comparable). Taking towns in the top two quartiles of INEQUALITY!, figure 5 displays the levels of protest for towns without settlement plans and with settlement plans before treatment and during the first treatment period (April 1933-June 1934). It looks as if protest was always lower in towns with land reform deployment before treatment and during treatment, although these differences are not statistically significant due to large standard errors. INSERT FIGURE 5 In order to substantiate these impressions with statistical analysis, we modify equation [1] to introduce triple interactions in the two treatment periods to take into account implementation of land reform or its absence on peasant protest. Y!,! = α + β! INEQUALITY! + γ!,! SETTLEMENT1! + γ!,! SETTLEMENT2! + β! (INEQUALITY! period 1) + γ! (INEQUALITY! SETTLEMENT1! period1) + β! (INEQUALITY! period 2) + γ! (INEQUALITY! SETTLEMENT2! period 2) + β! period 1 + β! period 2 + δx! + εz! + μ!,! [4] 29

30 where INEQUALITY! is the measure of land reform intensity used in the previous sections, X! the set of time-invariant characteristics of each town or village and Z! the monthly dummies and the time trend. SETTLEMENT1! is a dummy variable taking value 1 for all monthly observations if the town had a settlement plan drawn up in and 0 otherwise (López and Mata, 1993: 98, 102). SETTLEMENT2! is a dummy variable taking value 1 for all monthly observations of i if the town had land reform deployed after February 1936 in the form of temporary confiscations or settlement plans on Grandee property and 0 otherwise (López and Mata, 1993: 107, 110). Our main coefficients of interest are β!, γ!, β!, and γ!, with the expectation of finding that the intensity of expected land reform in the implementation period increased conflict in towns with no implementation (both β! and β!, but especially β! ) and reduces it in towns with implementation (γ! and γ! ). Table 7 reports the coefficients of estimating equation [4] using various dependent variables (extensive margin of strikes and invasions and extensive margin of strikes days and impact) with our main independent variable (INEQUALITY! ) proxied by the share of laborers ( %laborers ). INSERT TABLE 7 In column I of table 7, using invasion as our dependent variable, we get a positive, non-significant coefficient for the share of laborers in the first and second treatment periods (β! and β! ), a positive effect of settlement on land invasions (γ! ) in the first period and a negative effect in the second period (γ! ). These results are only slightly altered by robustness checks, especially re-estimating equation [4] excluding towns with missing information from the sample (table A2.4). 30

31 In the case of strikes, coefficient β! is statistically significant (columns, II, III, IV), with bigger size than in tables 4 and 5, (.008 as opposed to.003 and.005 in previous tables). In column II, with the extensive margin of strikes as dependent variable, the coefficient is.027 and statistically significant, also much larger for the province of Córdoba than in previous regressions from the two provinces. Coefficient γ!, the treatment effect of intensity of land reform conditional on deployment of land reform, is negative in the case of strikes and impact but, in absolute value, smaller than β! (columns II and IV). It is however positive in the case of using days as the intensive margin of strikes. In addition, standard errors on estimates of γ! are big, making the coefficient statistically non-significant. Finally, negative estimated γ! flip to positive when we exclude towns with no information in the Peasant Census from the sample. All in all, despite some negative coefficients, there is little evidence that land reform deployment appeased peasants In treatment period 2, results are even more inconclusive. We get positive coefficients on the intensity of land reform treatment in the second period, β!, in the case of invasions and strikes (intensive and extensive margin). But land reform implementation in the second treatment period gets positive, not statistically significant coefficients for strikes and negative for invasions. It could be the case that the comparisons between towns with settlement and towns without settlement performed in table 7 underestimate the effect of settlement. Because Republican land reform had a strong anti-nobility bias, perhaps the effects of absent deployment of reform were only felt in towns that had been under the 31

32 jurisdiction of a noble family in the past (which in general also had larger shares of laborers), meaning the right comparison is between towns with expropriated farms owned by Grandeza families and towns with a history of noble domination (a group we label Historical Grandeza towns). The latter towns could have a legacy of greater polarization and peasants in these towns could expect higher levels of land reform. For this reason, we code a variable taking value 1 if the town had been under the jurisdiction of a Grandee family in the early modern period but did not have large tracts of land owned by Grandeza (and therefore did not see quick deployment of land reform) (past jurisdiction of towns from España dividida, 1789). We then Historical Grandeza with the share of laborers in both periods of land reform implementation (period 1 and period 2). So we estimate the following regression: 𝑌!,! = 𝛼 + 𝛽! 𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄𝑈𝐴𝐿𝐼𝑇𝑌! + 𝛾!,! 𝑆𝐸𝑇𝑇𝐿𝐸𝑀𝐸𝑁𝑇1! + 𝛾!,! 𝑆𝐸𝑇𝑇𝐿𝐸𝑀𝐸𝑁𝑇2! + +𝜃! (𝐻𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝐺𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑧𝑎! ) + 𝛽! (𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄𝑈𝐴𝐿𝐼𝑇𝑌! 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑜𝑑 1) + 𝛾! (𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄𝑈𝐴𝐿𝐼𝑇𝑌! 𝑆𝐸𝑇𝑇𝐿𝐸𝑀𝐸𝑁𝑇1! 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑜𝑑1) + 𝜃! (𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄𝑈𝐴𝐿𝐼𝑇𝑌! 𝐻𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝑔𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑧𝑎!,! ) + 𝛽! (𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄𝑈𝐴𝐿𝐼𝑇𝑌! 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑜𝑑 2) + 𝛾! (𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄𝑈𝐴𝐿𝐼𝑇𝑌! 𝑆𝐸𝑇𝑇𝐿𝐸𝑀𝐸𝑁𝑇2! 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑜𝑑 2) + 𝜃! (𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄𝑈𝐴𝐿𝐼𝑇𝑌! 𝐻𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝑔𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑧𝑎!,! ) + 𝛽! 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑜𝑑 1 + 𝛽! 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑖𝑜𝑑 2 + 𝛿𝑋! + 𝜀𝑍! + 𝜇!,! [5] with 𝐻𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝑔𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑧𝑎! being a dummy variable taking value 1 in towns with a past noble jurisdiction but no surviving large estates from Grandeza noble, 𝐻𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝑔𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑧𝑎!,! is a dummy variable taking value 1 for towns that were under the jurisdiction of a Grandee family in the early modern period only for period 1 and 0 otherwise and 𝐻𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝑔𝑟𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑧𝑎!,! does the same for period 2. The remaining variables are defined as in equation [4]. Table 8 reports the coefficients of various 32

33 estimations of equation [5] for invasion, strike, days and impact, only reporting the γ, β, and θ coefficients. INSERT TABLE 8 HERE PLEASE In column I of table 8, using invasion as our dependent variable, we get a positive, non-significant coefficient for the share of laborers in the first and second treatment periods (β! and β! ), a positive, now significant effect of settlement on land invasions (γ! ) in the first period and a negative effect in the second period (γ! ). The effect of Grandeza s legacies is inconclusive, with a positive effect in period 1 (θ! ) and a negative effect in period 2 (θ! ). In the case of strikes, coefficient β! is statistically significant in columns II and IV, with slightly bigger sizes than in tables 4 and 5. Coefficient γ!, the treatment effect of intensity of land reform conditional on deployment of land reform, is negative in the case of strikes and impact but, in absolute value, smaller than β! (columns II and IV). Standard errors on γ! are large, making the coefficient statistically non-significant. Coefficient θ! on the interaction between %laborer, period 1 and the Historical Grandeza dummy gets statistically significant, positive, larger coefficients. We also get a positive, large and statistically θ! coefficient (treatment effect of historical Grandeza in the second period) suggesting towns with a past of being under noble jurisdiction protested more often perhaps expecting greater and faster re-distribution. These results are very similar if we exclude the towns with missing information from the sample (table A2.4). 33

34 Results in tables 7 and 8 need to consider the small number of observations treated with land reform implementation, however coefficients in table 7 suggest potential beneficiaries not treated with implementation struck more often, but we do not find a robust coefficient for the triple interaction between land reform intensity, settlement and both time periods. However, table 8 suggests the impact of settlement is perhaps underestimated in table 7. Comparing towns with past Grandeza presence with those with surviving Grandeza presence and expropriation, the coefficients on the interactions between historical Grandeza presence, the extent of potential land reform and the first treatment period throws positive and in many case significant coefficients in the first and second treatment periods. If we accept that this is the right comparison, then expropriation and land deployment reduced strikes and invasions. If this were the case, the peasant conflict in the case studied here, was endogenous to land reform and its glacial progress. Quicker land reform maybe would have reduced strikes, although the empirical basis to make this claim is still thin. 5 Conclusions This paper contributes to the literature on land reforms and rural conflict by analyzing one of the classic cases of failed land reform under democracy. Because the minimal protection of property rights meant lengthy assessments of costly compensations to be paid to landowners, the deployment of reform was slower and more difficult than expected by landless peasants. Did the glacial pace and uneven deployment land reform cause greater levels of peasant conflict in 1930s Spain? Our answer to the question is a qualified yes. We find that a group of potential beneficiaries of reform (laborers) struck more often in the period in which land reform was slow and partial, compared to an initial treatment period. There is also suggestive evidence that implementation reduced 34

35 protest. Our regressions show that the mechanics of rural protest in the provinces studied here were not caused by the interactions between recalcitrant owners of land and frustrated peasants. Rather, in a context of very slow land reform implementation, our results would be consistent with model of rural protest that emphasizes interactions with state actors and state policy (Alston, Libecap, Mueller, 1999), especially in the case of rural laborers. This protest was generated by frustrated expectations of land ownership re-distribution created by the same process of land reform. There were many reasons for the absence of invasions in Andalusia. Towns with an abundance of landless laborers were typically more egalitarian and therefore had less land to settle peasants, with the only exception being the case of towns with surviving farms owned by Grandeza families. This mismatch meant settlement of large groups of rural laborers and their families was maybe technically difficult, as it meant expropriating farms away from the main population centers and settling peasants in distant and unfertile areas where settlements were most probably only viable for short periods of the year. Perhaps one important issue not considered by the literature on land reform and rural conflict relates to the type of peasant affected by reform. Very mobile workers facing a sharply seasonal demand for labor like rural laborers in Andalusia were perhaps poorly adapted to reform. In contrast, land reform perhaps had greater effects in regions were farms could sustain tenants and their families year-round, for example where tenancy rather than wage labor was the norm, meaning tenants and sharecroppers were perhaps better equipped to take advantage of land reform quickly. The slow pace of land 35

36 reform in Andalusia and the apparent lack of appetite of Andalusian peasants for invading farms were perhaps not at all surprising. The analysis of land reform in Córdoba and Jaén suggests a one-size-fits-all land reform was perhaps poorly adapted to the variety of agrarian problems in 1930s Spain (Dobby, 1936). The lack of fit of land reform to Andalusian conditions perhaps reflected a very defective knowledge of agriculture and agrarian conditions by policy makers in the period. It was only during the implementation of reform that the state started to collect hard evidence to understand the causes of the various agrarian problems in Spain. But this process of problem discovery was not happening quickly enough to avoid reform paralysis. Attempts at solving the problem of rural poverty preceded the adequate understanding of the problem at hand. More than 50 years ago, Albert Hirschman studied the evolution of various important policies in Latin America, including land reform in Colombia (Hirschman, 1963). In developed economies, he observed it was typically the case that the advances in the understanding of a particular problem preceded the motivation to tackle that problem. In developing economies, however, the impulse or need of governments to act generally precedes the understanding of the problem at hand. In this context, potentially large mistakes, fast learning and continuous trial and error characterize policy-making. Hirschman did not have a negative view of trial and error and discovery, in part seeing them as inevitable. Yet, in the case of Spain, civil war and authoritarian reaction, not peasant revolution, put an end to a most ambitious project of social transformation. 36

37 Main abbreviations: CNT: Confederación Nacional del Trabajo, National Confederation of Labor. FNTT: Federación Nacional de Trabajadores de la Tierra, National Federation of Rural workers. IRA: Instituto de Reforma Agraria. Institute of Agrarian Reform UGT: Unión General de Trabajadores, Workers General Union. SOURCES: ABC, Madrid and Seville editions. Anuario Estadístico de España (AE), various years. El Sol España dividida en provincias e intendencias y subdividida en partidos, corregimientos, alcaldías mayores, gobiernos políticos y militares, asi realengos como órdenes, abadengo y señorío. Imprenta Real. Ministerio de Educación, Cultura y Deporte, Spain, Biblioteca Virtual de Prensa Histórica: Vegas, A., Diccionario Geográfico Universal. Imprenta de Don Joseph Doblado. BIBLIOGRAPHY: Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J.A., Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge University Press. Ai, Ch., Norton, E.C., Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economic Letters 80 (1), Albertus, M Autocracy and Redistribution. The Politics of Land Reform. 37

38 Cambridge University Press. Albertus, M., Brambor, T., Ceneviva, R., Land Inequality and Rural Unrest: Theory and Evidence from Brazil. Forthcoming in the Journal of Conflict Resolution. DOI: / Albertus, M., Kaplan, O., Land Reform as a Counterinsurgency Policy: The Case of Colombia. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 5 (2): Alston, L. J., Libecap, G., Mueller, B., A model of rural conflict: violence and land reform policy in Brazil. Environmental and Development Economics (4), 2: Alston, L. J., Libecap, G., Mueller, B., Land Reform Policies, the Sources of Violent Conflict, and Implications for the Deforestation of the Brazilian Amazon. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 39 (2): Bardhan, P., Mookherjee, D., Determinants of Redistributive Politics: An Empirical Analysis of Land Reforms in West Bengal, India. American Economic Review, 100 (4): Beck, N., Time-series cross-sectional data: what have we learned in the past? Annual Review of Political Science, 4: Beck, N., Katz, J What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-sectional analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science, 42 (4): Bernal, A. M., Economía e historia de los latifundios. Espasa-Calpe. Biswanger, H. P., Deininger, K., Feder, G., Power Distorsions, Revolt and Reform in Agricultural Land Relations. In Behrman, J., Srinivasan, T. N. (eds.). Handbook of Development Economics, volume 3, part B. North-Holland: Blair, R., Blattman, Ch., Hartman, A., Predicting Local Violence. Unpublished 38

39 manuscript, available at Boone, C., Property and Political Order in Africa. Land Rights and the Structure of Politics. Cambridge University Press. Brady, N. C., Weil, R.R., The Nature and Property of Soils. Prentice Hall. Brel, M. P., González, G.L., El censo de campesinos ( ): una base de datos de alcance municipal. In De Dios, S., Infante, J., Torijano, E., En torno a la propiedad. Estudios en homenaje al profesor Robledo: Universidad de Salamanca. Carmona, J., Rosés, J.R., Simpson, J., Spanish Land Reform in the 1930s: Economic Necessity or Political Opportunism? London School of Economics, Department of Economic History, working paper number 225. Carrión, P., Los latifundios en España. Ariel. Casanova, J., The Spanish Republic and the Civil War. Cambridge University Press. Cobo, F., Labradores, campesinos y jornaleros. Protesta social y diferenciación interna del campesinado jiennense en los orígenes de la Guerra Civil. Publicaciones del Ayuntamiento de Córdoba. Cobo, F De campesinos a electores: modernización agraria en Andalucía, politización campesina y derechización de los pequeños propietarios. Biblioteca Nueva. Cobo, F Revolución campesina y contrarrevolución franquista en Andalucía: conflictividad social, violencia política y represión. Universidad de Granada. Díaz del Moral, J., Historia de las agitaciones campesinas andaluzas. Alianza Editorial. 39

40 Dobby, E. H. G., Agrarian Problems in Spain. Geographical Review, 26 (2): Domenech, J., Rural labour markets and rural unrest in Spain before the Civil War ( ). Economic History Review, 66 (1): Domenech, J., Land Tenure Inequality, Harvests, and Rural Conflict. Evidence from Southern Spain during the Second Republic ( ). Social Science History, 39 (2): Esteban, J., Schneider, G., Polarization and conflict: theoretical and empirical issues. Journal of Peace Research, 45 (2): Esteban, J., Ray, D., Polarization, fractionalization and conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 45 (2): Finkel, E., Ghelbach, S., Olsen, T., Does Reform Prevent Rebellion? Evidence from Russia s Emancipation of the Serfs. Comparative Political Studies, 48 (8): Garrido, L., Colectividades agrarias en Andalucía. Jaén ( ). Siglo XXI. Garrido, L., Riqueza y tragedia social. Historia de la clase obrera en la provincia de Jaén ( ). Diputación Provincial de Jaén. Hirschman, A. O., Journeys Toward Progress. Studies of Economic-Policy Making in Latin America. The Twentieth Century Fund. Hobsbawm, E. J., Rudé, G., Captain Swing. Penguin. López, A., R. Mata, R Propiedad de la tierra y reforma agraria en Córdoba ( ). Servicio de Publicaciones de la Universidad de Córdoba. Luebbert, G. M., Liberalism, Fascism, or Social Democracy. Social Classes and the Political Origins of Regimes in Interwar Europe. Oxford University Press. Malefakis, Edward E. (1970). Agrarian Reform and Peasant Revolution in Spain. Origins of the Civil War. New Haven: Yale University Press. 40

41 Markoff, J The social geography of rural revolt at the beginning of the French Revolution. American Sociological Review, 50 (6): Markoff, J Contexts and forms of rural revolt: France in Journal of Conflict Resolution, 30 (2): Martínez Ruiz, E., El campo en guerra: organización y producción agraria. In Martín-Aceña, P., Martínez Ruiz, E. (2006). La economía de la Guerra Civil. Marcial Pons. Pérez Yruela, M., La conflictividad campesina en la provincia de Córdoba ( ). MAPA. Plümper, Th., Troeger, V., Manow, P., Panel data analysis in comparative politics: linking method to theory. European Journal of Political Research, 44 (2): Pro, J Estado, geometría y propiedad: orígenes del Catastro en España, Centro de Gestión Catastral. Robledo, R. 2012, La expropiación agraria de la Segunda República ( ). In de Dios, S., Infante, J., Robledo, R., Torijano, E.. La historia de la Propiedad: la expropiación. Ediciones Universidad de Salamanca: Robledo, R Sobre el fracaso de la reforma agraria andaluza en la Segunda República. In González de Molina, M.L. (ed.). La cuestión agraria en la historia de Andalucía: nuevas perspectivas. Fundación Pública Andaluza-Centro de Estudios Andaluces:

42 GRAPHS Map 1 Count of peasants strikes in Córdoba and Jaén This map displays the total count of strikes in each municipality adding the number of recorded events from April 1931 to June 1934 (both included) and from March 1936 to July The two capital cities and Linares are excluded from the universe of towns in the two provinces. Darker means a higher number of strikes. 42

43 Map 2 Count of invasions and collective trespassing in Córdoba and Jaén This map displays the total count of recorded events of invasion and collective trespassing in each municipality from April 1931 to June 1934 and from March 1936 to July The two capital cities and Linares are excluded from the universe of towns in the two provinces. Darker means higher counts of events. 43

44 Map 3 Total number of days on strike in Córdoba and Jaén This map displays the total number of days on strike from April 1931 to June 1934 and from March 1936 to July The two capital cities and Linares are excluded from the universe of towns in the two provinces. Darker means a higher number of days on strike. 44

45 Figure 1 Mean probability of strikes in May and June for the 2 nd and 4 th quartiles of the share of laborers in the local population, % laborers The figure shows the mean probability of recording at least one peasant strike event (extensive margin) in May-June 1931, May-June 1932, May-June 1933, May-June 1934 and May-June 1936 in the second and fourth quartile of municipalities in Córdoba and Jaén (except the two provincial capitals and Linares) ranked by from lower to higher percentage of laborers in the local population (% laborers, the demandside proxy of INEQUALITY! ). Strikes in May and June are considered to make years comparable. Averages are calculated for the second and fourth quartiles of % laborers, Vertical bars display the 95 % confidence intervals of the estimated mean propensities. The vertical striped line separates the pretreatment and treatment periods. There are no strikes recorded for year meanq2strikes meanq4strikes 45

46 Figure 2 Mean probability of strikes in May and June for towns in the 2 nd and 4 th quartile of the share of expropriable land (% expropriable) The figure shows the mean probability of recording at least one peasant strike event (extensive margin) in May-June 1931, May-June 1932, May-June 1933, May-June 1934 and May-June 1936 in the second and fourth quartile of municipalities in Córdoba and Jaén (except the two provincial capitals and Linares) ranked by from lower to higher percentage of the share of expropriable land in the area of the municipality (% expropriable, one of the supply-side proxies of INEQUALITY! ). Strikes in May and June are considered to make years comparable. Averages are calculated for the second and fourth quartiles of % expropriable. Vertical bars display the 95 % confidence intervals of the estimated mean propensities. The vertical striped line separates the pre-treatment and treatment periods. There are no strikes recorded for year meanq2_exp strikes mean q4_exp strikes 46

47 Figure 3 Mean probability of invasion events May-June for the 2 nd and 4 th quartiles of the % laborers The figure shows the mean probability of recording at least one invasion or collective trespassing event (extensive margin) in May-June 1931, May-June 1932, May-June 1933, May-June 1934 and May-June 1936 in the second and fourth quartile of municipalities in Córdoba and Jaén (except the two provincial capitals and Linares) ranked by from lower to higher percentage of the share of laborers in local population (% laborers, one of the demand-side proxies of INEQUALITY! ). Only invasions in May and June are considered to make years comparable. Averages are calculated for the second and fourth quartiles of % laborers, Vertical bars display the 95 % confidence intervals of the estimated mean propensities. The vertical striped line separates the pre-treatment and treatment periods. There are no invasions recorded for year meanq2invasion meanq4invasion 47

48 Figure 4 Coefficient estimates of β 1 for different months This figure displays the point estimates of coefficient β! when estimating equation [1] separately for each month of the year. Dependent variable is the extensive margin of strikes in each municipality and the main independent variable is the share of laborers ( % laborer ). The estimated coefficients capture the effect of % laborer in the first treatment period (April 1933 to June 1934). 48

49 Figure 5 Mean strikes prevalence May-July in the pre-reform and first treatment period This figure displays estimated average propensities to strike (extensive margin) for towns in Córdoba ranked in the top two quartiles of the share of landless laborers. We only consider May and June to make the pre-reform and reform periods comparable. The pre-reform period starts in April 1931 and finishes in March 1933 and, therefore, includes strikes in May-June 1931 and May-June The reform period starts in April 1933 and finishes in June 1934, it therefore includes strikes in May-June 1933 and May- June Vertical bars represent the 95 % confidence intervals of the mean pre-reform top quartiles no plan pre-reform top quartiles plan post-reform top quartiles no plan post-reform top quartiles plan

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Richard Disney*, Andy McKay + & C. Rashaad Shabab + *Institute of Fiscal Studies, University of Sussex and University College,

More information

Caught in the Crossfire: Land Reform, Death Squad Violence, and Elections in El Salvador

Caught in the Crossfire: Land Reform, Death Squad Violence, and Elections in El Salvador Caught in the Crossfire: Land Reform, Death Squad Violence, and Elections in El Salvador T. David Mason Amalia Pulido Jesse Hamner Mustafa Kirisci Castleberry Peace Institute University of North Texas

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant

More information

From Banerjee and Iyer (2005)

From Banerjee and Iyer (2005) From Banerjee and Iyer (2005) History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 4 (Sep., 2005), pp. 1190-1213 Similar

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland Online Appendix Laia Balcells (Duke University), Lesley-Ann Daniels (Institut Barcelona d Estudis Internacionals & Universitat

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

! # % & ( ) ) ) ) ) +,. / 0 1 # ) 2 3 % ( &4& 58 9 : ) & ;; &4& ;;8;

! # % & ( ) ) ) ) ) +,. / 0 1 # ) 2 3 % ( &4& 58 9 : ) & ;; &4& ;;8; ! # % & ( ) ) ) ) ) +,. / 0 # ) % ( && : ) & ;; && ;;; < The Changing Geography of Voting Conservative in Great Britain: is it all to do with Inequality? Journal: Manuscript ID Draft Manuscript Type: Commentary

More information

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES CHAIR OF MACROECONOMICS AND DEVELOPMENT Bachelor Seminar Economics of the very long run: Economics of Islam Summer semester 2017 Does Secular

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003 Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run Mark R. Rosenzweig Harvard University October 2003 Prepared for the Conference on The Future of Globalization Yale University. October 10-11, 2003

More information

Executive summary. Part I. Major trends in wages

Executive summary. Part I. Major trends in wages Executive summary Part I. Major trends in wages Lowest wage growth globally in 2017 since 2008 Global wage growth in 2017 was not only lower than in 2016, but fell to its lowest growth rate since 2008,

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

Explaining differences in access to home computers and the Internet: A comparison of Latino groups to other ethnic and racial groups

Explaining differences in access to home computers and the Internet: A comparison of Latino groups to other ethnic and racial groups Electron Commerce Res (2007) 7: 265 291 DOI 10.1007/s10660-007-9006-5 Explaining differences in access to home computers and the Internet: A comparison of Latino groups to other ethnic and racial groups

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Laura Montenegro Helfer. Forming State Through Land Reform Policy: The Dynamics of Baldío Allocation in Peripheral Colombia

Laura Montenegro Helfer. Forming State Through Land Reform Policy: The Dynamics of Baldío Allocation in Peripheral Colombia Laura Montenegro Helfer Forming State Through Land Reform Policy: The Dynamics of Baldío Allocation in Peripheral Colombia Forming State through Land Reform Policy: The Dynamics of Baldío Allocation in

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? José Luis Groizard Universitat de les Illes Balears Ctra de Valldemossa km. 7,5 07122 Palma de Mallorca Spain

More information

Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective

Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective s u m m a r y Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective Nicole M. Fortin and Thomas Lemieux t the national level, Canada, like many industrialized countries, has Aexperienced

More information

PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee.

PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee. PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee December 2005 The experience of West Bengal with respect to Panchayat Raj has been

More information

Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. Cloth $35.

Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. Cloth $35. Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006. 416 pp. Cloth $35. John S. Ahlquist, University of Washington 25th November

More information

Rainfall and Migration in Mexico Amy Teller and Leah K. VanWey Population Studies and Training Center Brown University Extended Abstract 9/27/2013

Rainfall and Migration in Mexico Amy Teller and Leah K. VanWey Population Studies and Training Center Brown University Extended Abstract 9/27/2013 Rainfall and Migration in Mexico Amy Teller and Leah K. VanWey Population Studies and Training Center Brown University Extended Abstract 9/27/2013 Demographers have become increasingly interested over

More information

The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform

The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform By SARAH BOHN, MATTHEW FREEDMAN, AND EMILY OWENS * October 2014 Abstract Changes in the treatment of individuals

More information

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern Chapter 11 Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Do Poor Countries Need to Worry about Inequality? Martin Ravallion There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern in countries

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

European Social Survey ESS 2004 Documentation of the sampling procedure

European Social Survey ESS 2004 Documentation of the sampling procedure European Social Survey ESS 2004 Documentation of the sampling procedure A. TARGET POPULATION The population is composed by all persons aged 15 and over resident within private households in Spain (including

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1 Abstract: Growing income inequality and labor market polarization and increasing

More information

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa International Affairs Program Research Report How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa Report Prepared by Bilge Erten Assistant

More information

Support for Peaceable Franchise Extension: Evidence from Japanese Attitude to Demeny Voting. August Very Preliminary

Support for Peaceable Franchise Extension: Evidence from Japanese Attitude to Demeny Voting. August Very Preliminary Support for Peaceable Franchise Extension: Evidence from Japanese Attitude to Demeny Voting August 2012 Rhema Vaithianathan 1, Reiko Aoki 2 and Erwan Sbai 3 Very Preliminary 1 Department of Economics,

More information

Access to agricultural land, youth migration and livelihoods in Tanzania

Access to agricultural land, youth migration and livelihoods in Tanzania Access to agricultural land, youth migration and livelihoods in Tanzania Ntengua Mdoe (SUA), Milu Muyanga (MSU), T.S. Jayne (MSU) and Isaac Minde (MSU/iAGRI) Presentation at the Third AAP Conference to

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Chad Kendall Department of Economics University of British Columbia Marie Rekkas* Department of Economics Simon Fraser University mrekkas@sfu.ca 778-782-6793

More information

Comments on Ansell & Samuels, Inequality & Democracy: A Contractarian Approach. Victor Menaldo University of Washington October 2012

Comments on Ansell & Samuels, Inequality & Democracy: A Contractarian Approach. Victor Menaldo University of Washington October 2012 Comments on Ansell & Samuels, Inequality & Democracy: A Contractarian Approach Victor Menaldo University of Washington October 2012 There s a lot to like here Robustness to Dependent Variable (Regime Type)

More information

Community Well-Being and the Great Recession

Community Well-Being and the Great Recession Pathways Spring 2013 3 Community Well-Being and the Great Recession by Ann Owens and Robert J. Sampson The effects of the Great Recession on individuals and workers are well studied. Many reports document

More information

Phenomenon of trust in power in Kazakhstan Introduction

Phenomenon of trust in power in Kazakhstan Introduction Phenomenon of trust in power in Kazakhstan Introduction One of the most prominent contemporary sociologists who studied the relation of concepts such as "trust" and "power" is the German sociologist Niklas

More information

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities By Elsie Echeverri-Carroll and Sofia G Ayala * The high-tech boom of the last two decades overlapped with increasing wage inequalities between men

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective. Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden

Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective. Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden December 17, 2010 1 Data Below we list information regarding the source of our

More information

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants? What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants? Una Okonkwo Osili Indiana University Purdue University Indianapolis Anna Paulson Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago *These are the views of the

More information

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil Peter Brummund Laura Connolly University of Alabama July 26, 2018 Abstract Many countries continue to integrate into the world economy,

More information

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France No. 57 February 218 The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France Clément Malgouyres External Trade and Structural Policies Research Division This Rue

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Appendix to Sectoral Economies Appendix to Sectoral Economies Rafaela Dancygier and Michael Donnelly June 18, 2012 1. Details About the Sectoral Data used in this Article Table A1: Availability of NACE classifications by country of

More information

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test Axel Dreher a and Hannes Öhler b January 2010 Economics Letters, forthcoming We investigate the impact of government ideology on left-wing as

More information

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings Part 1: Focus on Income indicator definitions and Rankings Inequality STATE OF NEW YORK CITY S HOUSING & NEIGHBORHOODS IN 2013 7 Focus on Income Inequality New York City has seen rising levels of income

More information

Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795)

Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795) Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795) Carlos Rodríguez-Castelán (World Bank) Luis-Felipe López-Calva (UNDP) Nora Lustig (Tulane University) Daniel Valderrama

More information

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE WP 2015: 9 Reported versus actual voting behaviour Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE Chr. Michelsen Institute (CMI) is an independent, non-profit research institution and a major international centre in

More information

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries?

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries? African Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 2, No. 1, Dec 2010 The Author(s). Published by Print Services, Rhodes University, P.O.Box 94, Grahamstown, South Africa Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage

More information

Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain

Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain Facundo Albornoz Antonio Cabrales Paula Calvo Esther Hauk March 2018 Abstract This note provides evidence on how immigration

More information

Oxfam Education

Oxfam Education Background notes on inequality for teachers Oxfam Education What do we mean by inequality? In this resource inequality refers to wide differences in a population in terms of their wealth, their income

More information

Women s Education and Women s Political Participation

Women s Education and Women s Political Participation 2014/ED/EFA/MRT/PI/23 Background paper prepared for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report 2013/4 Teaching and learning: Achieving quality for all Women s Education and Women s Political Participation

More information

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States Charles Weber Harvard University May 2015 Abstract Are immigrants in the United States more likely to be enrolled

More information

RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION

RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION Working Paper #201 POLITICAL POLARIZATION AND INCOME INEQUALITY Nolan McCarty Keith T. Poole Howard Rosenthal February 2003 Russell Sage Working Papers have not been reviewed by

More information

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization 3 Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization Given the evidence presented in chapter 2 on preferences about globalization policies, an important question to explore is whether any opinion cleavages

More information

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. World Politics, vol. 68, no. 2, April 2016.* David E. Cunningham University of

More information

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook

Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook Digital Commons @ George Fox University Student Scholarship - School of Business School of Business 1-1-2016 Impact of Human Rights Abuses on Economic Outlook Benjamin Antony George Fox University, bantony13@georgefox.edu

More information

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, 1960-2006 Sources: Data based on UCDP/PRIO armed conflict database (N. P. Gleditsch et al., 2002; Harbom & Wallensteen, 2007).

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

The Impact of Licensing Decentralization on Firm Location Choice: the Case of Indonesia

The Impact of Licensing Decentralization on Firm Location Choice: the Case of Indonesia The Impact of Licensing Decentralization on Firm Location Choice: the Case of Indonesia Ari Kuncoro 1 I. Introduction Spatial centralization of resources and spatial concentration of manufacturing in a

More information

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W. A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) by Stratford Douglas* and W. Robert Reed Revised, 26 December 2013 * Stratford Douglas, Department

More information

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom June 1, 2016 Abstract Previous researchers have speculated that incumbency effects are

More information

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad? Economics Letters 69 (2000) 239 243 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad? * William J. Collins, Robert A. Margo Vanderbilt University

More information

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey Katrina Washington, Barbara Blass and Karen King U.S. Census Bureau, Washington D.C. 20233 Note: This report is released to

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies

Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies Corruption: Costs and Mitigation Strategies Presented by Bernardin AKITOBY Assistant Director INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND SEPTEMBER 2017 Motivation Corruption has been identified as one of the most important

More information

The Supporting Role of Democracy in Reducing Global Poverty

The Supporting Role of Democracy in Reducing Global Poverty The Supporting Role of Democracy in Reducing Global Poverty Joseph Connors Working Paper no. 16 Department of Economics Wake Forest University connorjs@wfu.edu November 10, 2011 Abstract The Washington

More information

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations Amparo Castelló and Rafael Doménech 2016 Annual Meeting of the European Economic Association Geneva, August 24, 2016 1/1 Introduction

More information

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA Mahari Bailey, et al., : Plaintiffs : C.A. No. 10-5952 : v. : : City of Philadelphia, et al., : Defendants : PLAINTIFFS EIGHTH

More information

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes 2009/ED/EFA/MRT/PI/19 Background paper prepared for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report 2009 Overcoming Inequality: why governance matters A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in

More information

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians I. Introduction Current projections, as indicated by the 2000 Census, suggest that racial and ethnic minorities will outnumber non-hispanic

More information

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph Thesis For the Degree of Bachelor of Arts in Liberal Arts and Sciences College

More information

REPORT ON THE STATUS OF IMPLEMENTATION OF THE COLOMBIA FINAL ACCORD

REPORT ON THE STATUS OF IMPLEMENTATION OF THE COLOMBIA FINAL ACCORD REPORT ON THE STATUS OF IMPLEMENTATION OF THE COLOMBIA FINAL ACCORD KROC INSTITUTE FOR INTERNATIONAL PEACE STUDIES UNIVERSITY OF NOTRE DAME EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This report presents the results of monitoring

More information

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty 43 vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty Inequality is on the rise in several countries in East Asia, most notably in China. The good news is that poverty declined rapidly at the same

More information

Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia. June Abstract

Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia. June Abstract Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia June 2003 Abstract The standard view in the literature on wage inequality is that within-group, or residual, wage

More information

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily! MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily! Philipp Hühne Helmut Schmidt University 3. September 2014 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/58309/

More information

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration. Unfinished Draft Not for Circulation

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration. Unfinished Draft Not for Circulation Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration Unfinished Draft Not for Circulation October 2014 Eric D. Gould Department of Economics The Hebrew

More information

The Impact of Legal Status on Immigrants Earnings and Human. Capital: Evidence from the IRCA 1986

The Impact of Legal Status on Immigrants Earnings and Human. Capital: Evidence from the IRCA 1986 The Impact of Legal Status on Immigrants Earnings and Human Capital: Evidence from the IRCA 1986 February 5, 2010 Abstract This paper analyzes the impact of IRCA 1986, a U.S. amnesty, on immigrants human

More information

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter Organization Introduction The Specific Factors Model International Trade in the Specific Factors Model Income Distribution and the Gains from

More information

The Economic and Political Effects of Black Outmigration from the US South. October, 2017

The Economic and Political Effects of Black Outmigration from the US South. October, 2017 The Economic and Political Effects of Black Outmigration from the US South Leah Boustan 1 Princeton University and NBER Marco Tabellini 2 MIT October, 2017 Between 1940 and 1970, the US South lost more

More information

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1 Inequality and growth: the contrasting stories of Brazil and India Concern with inequality used to be confined to the political left, but today it has spread to a

More information

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections by Stephen E. Haynes and Joe A. Stone September 20, 2004 Working Paper No. 91 Department of Economics, University of Oregon Abstract: Previous models of the

More information

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005) , Partisanship and the Post Bounce: A MemoryBased Model of Post Presidential Candidate Evaluations Part II Empirical Results Justin Grimmer Department of Mathematics and Computer Science Wabash College

More information

Edward L. Glaeser Harvard University and NBER and. David C. Maré * New Zealand Department of Labour

Edward L. Glaeser Harvard University and NBER and. David C. Maré * New Zealand Department of Labour CITIES AND SKILLS by Edward L. Glaeser Harvard University and NBER and David C. Maré * New Zealand Department of Labour [Revised version is forthcoming in Journal of Labor Economics 19(2), April 2000]

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power Eren, Ozlem University of Wisconsin Milwaukee December

More information

Combining national and constituency polling for forecasting

Combining national and constituency polling for forecasting Combining national and constituency polling for forecasting Chris Hanretty, Ben Lauderdale, Nick Vivyan Abstract We describe a method for forecasting British general elections by combining national and

More information

Online Appendix: Unified Language, Labor and Ideology

Online Appendix: Unified Language, Labor and Ideology Online Appendix: Unified Language, Labor and Ideology Yang You Last Updated: Jan. 2018 A. Survey Question Selection This appendix describes the four survey sources used in the paper and explicitly lists

More information

Priming Ideology? Electoral Cycles Without Electoral Incentives Among Elite U.S. Judges

Priming Ideology? Electoral Cycles Without Electoral Incentives Among Elite U.S. Judges Priming Ideology? Electoral Cycles Without Electoral Incentives Among Elite U.S. Judges Carlos Berdejo & Daniel L. Chen February 2013 1 Introduction Motivation/Relevance Background and Data 2 Electoral

More information

Unit 3: Spanish Civil War

Unit 3: Spanish Civil War Unit 3: Spanish Civil War 1936-1939 What will we cover in this unit Long-term causes of the Spanish civil war Short-term causes of the Spanish civil war What occurred during the Spanish Civil War The effects

More information

The Future of Inequality

The Future of Inequality The Future of Inequality As almost every economic policymaker is aware, the gap between the wages of educated and lesseducated workers has been growing since the early 1980s and that change has been both

More information

Household Income and Expenditure Survey Methodology 2013 Workers Camps

Household Income and Expenditure Survey Methodology 2013 Workers Camps Household Income and Expenditure Survey Methodology 2013 Workers Camps 1 Content Introduction 3 Target community: 4 Survey geographical coverage: 4 Sampling method: 4 Survey variables: 5 Survey Questionnaires:

More information

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard RESEARCH PAPER> May 2012 Wisconsin Economic Scorecard Analysis: Determinants of Individual Opinion about the State Economy Joseph Cera Researcher Survey Center Manager The Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

More information

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University February 2010 1 SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas ABSTRACT The employment

More information

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank 1 Around 1980 China had one of the highest poverty rates in the world We estimate that

More information

The Future of Inequality: The Other Reason Education Matters So Much

The Future of Inequality: The Other Reason Education Matters So Much The Future of Inequality: The Other Reason Education Matters So Much The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation

More information