THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ECONOMIC SHOCKS AND INSURGENT STRATEGY: EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTAN A BACHELOR THESIS SUBMITTED TO

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ECONOMIC SHOCKS AND INSURGENT STRATEGY: EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTAN A BACHELOR THESIS SUBMITTED TO"

Transcription

1 THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ECONOMIC SHOCKS AND INSURGENT STRATEGY: EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTAN A BACHELOR THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS FOR HONORS WITH THE DEGREE OF BACHELOR OF THE ARTS IN ECONOMICS BY MICHAEL GALPERIN CHICAGO, ILLINOIS MAY 216

2 Economic Shocks and Insurgent Strategy Michael Galperin May 216 Abstract Empirical studies of civil conflict often rely on aggregate measures of violence, such as the number of deaths or the number of attacks, to attempt to infer the determinants of conflict. This broad tactic ignores substantial variation in insurgent strategic choice. Using new data on political violence in Pakistan, I examine whether conventional rebel violence and asymmetric rebel violence respond differently to economic shocks. Using the same data, I also perform a general analysis of the determinants of civil conflict overall. Negative shocks to local agricultural revenue are significantly related to increases in insurgent violence, which is consistent with an opportunity cost theory of rebel violence. These results are robust to a number of specifications and outcome measures of violence. I find that the responses of asymmetric and conventional violence to income shocks are similar in magnitude, indicating that rebels reduce all types of conflict activity in response to positive economic shocks rather than substituting to potentially less costly forms of insurgency. I conclude by offering potential directions for future research in evaluating differential effects of violence types to economic shocks. 1 Introduction A broad literature has shown that there is tremendous variation in the forces driving civil war. These include opportunistic greed on the part of rebels (Collier and Hoeffler, 24; Weinstein, 27); ethnic, religious, or linguistic grievances (Horowitz, 1985; DeVotta, 24); ideology (Staniland, 215); political exclusion (Cederman et al., 21); state weakness (Fearon and Laitin, 23); and community forces (Petersen, 21). This variety presents a fundamental estimation problem for empirical studies of conflict: absolute measures University of Chicago. Last updated November 217 as writing sample for application to graduate school. I thank Ethan Bueno De Mesquita for his invaluable advisorship and expertise, which was instrumental at every level of this research project. I also thank Victor Lima and Grace Tsiang for their extremely valuable advice and help throughout this project, and Stephane Bonhomme and Daniel Roberts for many thoughtful comments. 1

3 of conflict intensity, such as the number of deaths, do not provide information on rebel strategic choice or motivation. This inability has led to considerable disagreement among empiricists, and has encouraged efforts to formalize standard regression strategies that include the correct independent variables. 1 Much less attention has been paid, however, to how results differ across different types of conflict. Most empirical studies of conflict estimate their effects either by pooling together disparate types of conflict incidents, such as guerilla violence, terrorism, or conventional attacks by insurgent groups, or by studying these types of conflict in isolation by using datasets that record only a specific type of political violence (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 215). For this reason, little is understood empirically about the causes of variation in insurgent strategy. This variation is tremendous in scope, and has both analytically important consequences for research and operationally valuable implications for counterinsurgency. In this paper, I use new data on political violence in Pakistan to measure the causes of variation in insurgent strategy. I distinguish between conventional violence, which includes highly organized attacks on the state by militant groups and is characterized by high levels of rebel mobilization, and asymmetric violence, which requires far fewer insurgents and includes incidents such as guerilla attacks and terrorist acts. My analysis tests for these differential effects by evaluating the responses of each violence type to exogenous economic shocks. Following Dube and Vargas (213), I proxy for economic variables by interacting the regional production of primary commodity exports with their international price, which is taken as exogenous. Much of my analysis focuses on cotton and rice, two of the largest Pakistani commodity exports. 2 While these exports are a substantial share of Pakistani GDP, the country s low absolute export volume relative to the total global trade in cotton and rice makes it plausible to assume that shocks to international prices are truly exogenous. The distinction between conventional and asymmetric violence, while still a simplification of the myriad of strategies used by rebels, is an improvement over existing literature which studies right-hand-side variables extensively but treats variation in outcome variables as unimportant. In doing so, existing papers measure broad trends in insurgent violence but fail to account for patterns of endogenous substitution by rebels in choosing their strategies. In contrast, I argue that analyzing the differential violence types addressed in this paper is essential to more deeply understand the causes of variation in rebel violence. While the absolute level of rebel violence is also a product of insurgent strategy (Weinstein, 27), the type of violence employed by rebels is intimately tied to their strategic and operational goals. 1 For a review, see Hegre and Sambanis (26). 2 Rice is Pakistan s #2 primary commodity export from 1988 through 1992, and is the #1 export afterwards. Cotton is the #1 export from 1988 through 1992, before being overtaken by rice. Afterwards, in the time window for my analysis, it does not drop below the #4 primary commodity export level. Commodity data is from Bazzi and Blattman (214). 2

4 The paper has two main findings. First, negative local shocks to income, as proxied by shocks to local agricultural revenue, are significantly related to higher levels of conflict. This is consistent with an opportunity cost model of insurgent violence, in which positive shocks to income decrease violence by increasing the opportunity cost of rebellion. Second, and more surprisingly, the effects of these shocks are remarkably similar on conventional and asymmetric conflict when the outcome measure of violence is disaggregated to consider both violence types. This stands in supposed contrast to accounts of conventional and asymmetric insurgencies different operational strategies and goals, and suggests that economic shocks are relevant concern in determining the level of conflict across multiple types. More importantly, this result can be interpreted as running counter to the notion that rebel leaders endogenously substitute from one type of conflict to another in response to transitory changes in mobilization an assumption commonly invoked in the political science literature on political violence (see, e.g. Fortna, 215). Rather, the lack of a substantial difference in effects on asymmetric and conventional violence is evidence that rebel leaders scale all types of violence in response to economic shocks. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides a review of the empirical literature on the determinants of civil conflict, and establishes the theoretical motivations for testing for heterogeneity in the responses of different political violence types to economic shocks and environmental conditions. Section 3 discusses data sources and provides descriptive statistics. Section 4 describes my estimation methodology and provides regression results, and Section 5 interprets them in the context of insurgent strategy and concludes. 2 The Determinants of Civil Conflict 2.1 Economic Incentives and Rebel Types Economic theory yields two competing predictions of income shocks effects on the incidence of conflict. In one prediction, positive income shocks increase the opportunity cost of participating in insurgency, and therefore make conflict less likely by decreasing labor supplied to violence. This opportunity cost effect mirrors a fundamental prediction from the seminal Becker (1968) crime model: improvement of the outside alternative to violence should decrease the amount of violence. On the other hand, positive economic shocks increase the value of contestable goods, and could thus make conflict more likely as the increased spoils of violence present incentives for violent appropriation. This is the rapacity effect. Dal Bo and Dal Bo (211) formalize this distinction in an equilibrium trade model which predicts that positive shocks to labor intensive industries decrease conflict, while positive shocks to capital intensive industries increase 3

5 it. Much of the empirical literature connecting economic shocks to violence uses large, cross national datasets to evaluate this relationship. A fairly robust and agreed upon conclusion is that higher national incomes and rates of economic growth are negatively correlated with conflict (Blattman and Miguel, 21; Miguel et al., 24). Beyond this general conclusion, however, there is considerable disagreement on the mechanism linking economic shocks to rebellion. For example, Fearon and Laitin (23) take per capita income as a proxy for state strength, and argue that state weakness (proxied by low per capita GDP) encourages insurgency by increasing the probability that rebellion is successful. This stands in contrast to an influential paper by Collier and Hoeffler (24), who claim that low per capita incomes make rebellion less costly by reducing the income that insurgents forego by choosing to rebel. There is also considerable disagreement on the role of natural resources in financing or encouraging rebellion. A common proxy variable for the value of natural resources, and one that I employ, is the value of primary commodity exports. Collier and Hoeffler document a significant link between civil conflict and high levels of dependence on primary commodity exports in constituting a country s wealth. This relationship, taken as evidence of the rapacity effect, is interpreted by the authors as evidence that rebels are greedy and are motivated primarily by material wealth, although this interpretation is disputed by some (see, e.g. Humphreys, 25). Oil is commonly invoked in particular as a natural resource linked to conflict; while the causal link of oil to conflict is fairly robust across studies, the connection of agricultural commodities to conflict is less so (Ross, 24). More recently, Bazzi and Blattman (214) have used new data on international commodity prices to evaluate the relationship between economic shocks and conflict. The authors find that shocks to commodity prices do not affect the incidence of conflict, but may affect its duration. Despite these results, a number of problems endemic to large, cross national studies of conflict limit their predictive power. Regressions of civil war onset on various country level characteristics must address the issue of comparing a highly transitory variable (the onset of civil war) with factors that are often less likely to change drastically (e.g. population), forcing researchers to make arbitrary choices of the time scale on which they evaluate wars. 3 Such regressions are also unable to incorporate country-specific elements, such as government policies, which are instrumental in shaping the dynamics of war but difficult to quantify or compare across nations. Finally, since the specification of cross country regressions studying conflict requires the use of time scales that are often quite broad (for example, Collier and Hoeffler use civil war 3 For example, Fearon (25) shows that the influential result of Collier and Hoeffler (24) is sensitive to the time scale on which the dependent variable, civil war onset, is considered. While Collier and Hoeffler use 5-year periods in their analysis, the result is not robust to other specifications of timeframe. 4

6 onset within a five-year window as their outcome variable), such studies are often subject to significant endogeneity concerns. Civil war often has devastating effects on countries economies, and frequently also drastically affects common regressors such as ethnic composition and population. This endogeneity issue has led some researchers to study conflict by attempting to instrument for economic variables (see, e.g. Miguel et al., 24). One increasingly popular response to the issues inherent to cross national conflict studies is to instead study within country variation in violence due to localized shocks. Interestingly, results at the subnational level frequently differ from national level results. Berman and Couttenier (213) find that although income shocks do not affect conflict at the national level, local shocks (including those occurring as a result of shocks to commodity prices) are significantly related to the incidence and intensity of conflict. There is also mixed support at the subnational level for the opportunity cost rebellion mechanism. While Berman et al. (211a) finds no relationship between unemployment and insurgent violence in Afghanistan, Iraq, and the Philippines, Berman et al. (211b) finds that government counterinsurgency efforts aimed at increasing employment in Iraq are robustly linked to decreasing conflict. An especially relevant empirical within country study is Dube and Vargas (213), who use municipalitylevel data on Colombia to show that while positive shocks to coffee production (a labor intensive industry) decrease conflict, positive shocks to oil production (which is capital intensive) increase it. This distinction allows the authors to empirically test for the existence both of opportunity cost effects of income shocks on conflict in labor intensive industries such as coffee, and of opposite-direction rapacity effects in capital-intensive industries such as oil. The authors proxy for economic shocks to individual economic sectors by interacting local production of oil and cotton with their exogenous international commodity prices. Thus, variations in the international commodity price can be interpreted as causing revenue shocks to local economies. The authors find consistent evidence that labor intensity determines the balance of the opportunity cost and rapacity effects. For labor intensive goods, a positive shock to income reduces conflict by increasing the implicit costs of foregoing market labor. For capital-intensive goods, the increase in contestable value from a positive income shock increases conflict by making it more potentially lucrative. Using district level data on the production of rice and cotton, I perform a similar analysis on Pakistan. 2.2 Dependent Variables Despite the mixed results of this empirical literature, one well-documented phenomenon is the sensitivity of empirical results on civil conflict to differential empirical specifications or codings of outcome variables. 5

7 Difficulties in these codings include the definition of a threshold at which a given conflict is deemed a civil war, information on when conflicts start and end, and clear identification of the distinct actors involved in conflict (Sambanis, 24). These difficulties often influence empirical results; for example, Fearon (25) demonstrates that the hugely influential result of Collier and Hoeffler is undermined by small changes in sample framing. While studies frequently attempt to make up for potential data deficiencies or coding errors by running a number of robustness checks, most of these tests are ad hoc and seldom use a variety of data sources to test their predictions. This risks faulty conclusions due to coding practices inherent to the data (Hegre and Sambanis, 26). However, concerns over the proper coding of outcome variables mask a deeper conceptual problem in the empirical study of civil conflict. Studies that treat conflict as a unitary action without meaningfully distinguishable types ignore the substantial variation in insurgent strategy that occurs within conflict, and in particular fail to measure patterns of endogenous substitution in rebel strategy in response to external shocks to mobilization. While this distinction has been largely ignored by the economics literature on civil conflict, endogenous variation in insurgent strategy shaped by external contingencies is a well established phenomenon among political scientists. The tremendous variation in the degree of insurgent violence, for example, is taken as a result of strategic choices stemming from insurgent groups initial endowments of wealth and social capital (Weinstein, 27). Insurgents also frequently vary in the degree to which they collude with state governments, owing either to strategic choices of group survival or materialistic calculations of potential gain (Staniland, 212; Seymour, 214). In the case of terrorism, insurgent groups may endogenously choose to engage in small-scale asymmetric conflict instead of confronting states directly as a strategy aimed at coercing states into ceding territory (Pape, 23). These examples are but a small sample of the significant dimensions along which insurgent conflict varies and none of these analytically important factors are captured by empirical studies that do not attempt to identify insurgent strategic choices. Furthermore, the attempt to create datasets that correctly set thresholds to classify events as civil wars, while useful for large cross national studies, ignores this important variation in the technology of conflict pursued by insurgent groups. Even among studies using datasets that carefully specify civil wars, this represents a potentially significant sample selection problem. For example, it is unclear whether empirical studies that use outcome data only on certain types of violent incidents have relevance for understanding civil violence in general, as this strategy for inference samples on the dependent variable by only including the conflict type of interest (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 215; Ashworth et al., 28) Bueno de Mesquita (213) formalizes the notion of insurgent strategic substitution in a game theoretic 6

8 model of insurgent tactical choice, which I incorporate into my design. In the model, rebel leaders observe insurgent mobilization among the population and choose between conventional action, which is highly labor intensive; asymmetric conflict, which requires fewer participants but is less effective at high levels of mobilization, and withdrawal from conflict. The model predicts that while the degree of conventional violence is linear in mobilization, the effect of mobilization on asymmetric violence is nonmonotone. At very low levels of mobilization, rebel leaders choose to withdraw from conflict rather than fighting, and at high levels, they choose to substitute to conventional violence rather than pursuing less effective asymmetric strategies. This differential effect highlights the need for empirical studies that distinguish between different types of political violence. In the particular case of insurgent substitution among violence types, a study that measures only total numbers of conflict incidents may measure violence as decreasing overall when insurgents are merely substituting among different strategic possibilities. The main innovation of this paper is to measure these differential effects empirically. 3 Data and Descriptive Statistics 3.1 Data Sources and Coding For data on conflict outcomes, I use the BFRS Political Violence in Pakistan Dataset (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 215). The dataset records over 28, conflict events in Pakistan between 1988 and 211, and is coded from regional editions of The Dawn, the largest syndicated newspaper in Pakistan. An innovation of the BFRS data, and one that is important for my analysis, is that the data distinguishes among different types of politically violent acts. In particular, each observation in the BFRS dataset reports information on the specific violent actor(s) involved, the number of casualties, the location of the event, and a classification of the type of violence reported (e.g. terrorism ), whenever this information is available. This represents a significant improvement over previous databases recording political violence, which rely mostly on death toll measures to report on the severity of conflict while ignoring the specific details of the technologies of violence used by rebels in each case. Furthermore, the data provides conflict information at the event level, a degree of specificity that is unusual among datasets on political violence that rely on aggregate measures. Using the violence categories included in the data, I follow Bueno de Mesquita et al. (215) in grouping conflict events into a number of categories in order to distinguish between conventional and asymmetric insurgent violence. Militant Attacks, used in the first model to evaluate broad patterns of violent response to economic shocks, are coded as including attacks on state targets, conventional attacks on military, paramil- 7

9 itary, police or intelligence targets, and guerilla attacks on military, paramilitary, police or intelligence targets. I continue by evaluating differential effects on two different violence categories. Militant Asymmetric Attacks include terrorist attacks by militants and guerilla attacks on military, paramilitary, police or intelligence targets. Militant Conventional Attacks include conventional attacks on military, paramilitary, police or intelligence targets and militant attacks on the state. The unit of my analysis is the district year. After cleaning, this results in 242 unique district year observations in the baseline specification. Agricultural data is taken from the UN Food and Agriculture Organization s Global Agro-ecological Zones (GAEZ) database (FAOUN, 212). In particular, I use total production levels for cotton and rice, assumed to be fixed over the timespan of my analysis. I then aggregate agricultural data at the district level using the shapefile boundaries from the U.S. Census Bureau population data. These production measures are interacted with international commodity price data, released publicly by Bazzi and Blattman (214). Panel A of Figure 1 plots the evolution of commodity prices over time. There is considerable variation in the commodity price for both goods. There is also evidence of differential trends: for example, the price of rice increases sharply after the year 2, while the price of cotton oscillates but does not seem to have a clear trend upwards or downwards. Panel B of Figure 1 plots the evolution of each commodity s export weight over time, defined as the proportion of total Pakistani export value represented by the commodity. While cotton is a hugely important Pakistani export at the beginning of the sample period, its relative importance in exports declines significantly over time. On the other hand, the export weight of rice remains relatively constant and high in absolute terms. 3.2 Descriptive Statistics and Figures For ease of interpretation, Figure 5 in Appendix A provides a descriptive map of Pakistan, subdivided into provinces and showing surrounding countries. Table 1 reports descriptive statistics for the outcome variables used in my analysis, which are the number of attacks and the number of deaths in a given district in a given year. Roughly 38.5% of district years have at least one militant attack in a given year, and roughtly 54.7% of district years have at least one reported death due to political violence. There is substantial variability in the degree of violence across district years: while some years in some districts are entirely peaceful, other districts experience as many as 317 attacks in a single year. Figure 2 shows the number of recorded militant attacks in each district over the entire time window of the BFRS data. As the map shows, there is also substantial variablility in conflict intensity by geographic 8

10 Figure 1: Cotton and Rice Commodity Prices by Panel A: Commodity Prices by Commodity Price Rice Cotton Panel B: Export Weights by Export Weight Rice Cotton Note: Panel (A) shows the evolution of international commodity prices for rice and cotton over time. The price of rice is given by the thick black line, and the price of cotton is given by the dashed line. Panel (B) plots the evolution of each commodity s export weight over time, measured as the share of total export value represented by the given commodity. International commodity price data is taken from Bazzi and Blattman (214). 9

11 Table 1: District-Level Violence Statistics Variable Mean (Std. Dev.) Min. Max. N Number of attacks (11.741) Number of attacks, if at least one attack occurred 7.26 (18.72) {At least one attack occurred}.385 (.487) Number of Deaths (57.997) Number of Deaths, if at least one death occurred (77.81) {At least one death occurred}.547 (.498) Note: This table shows average violence statistics by district year. The expression 1{At least one attack occurred} is the indicator function, and evaluates to 1 if an attack occurred in the given district in the given year, and otherwise. region. In particular, high counts of violent incidents are recorded in the Federally Administered Tribal Areas (FATA) to the country s northwest, as well as the Azad Jammu and Kashmir (AJK) territory in the northeast bordering the disputed Kashmir territory. Comparatively lower levels of violence are reported in Gilgit-Baltistan and immediately south of FATA, with intermediate levels throughout most of Balochistan and Punjab. The spatial distribution of violence also differs considerably between conflict types if militant attacks are disaggregated into conventional and asymmetric events. Figure 6 in Appendix B demonstrates this heterogeneity graphically. There is also substantial geographic variability in the production intensity of agricultural commodities. Figure 3 shows cotton and rice production along with Pakistani administrative district boundaries. The most intense production occurs in the central and northern part of Pakistan, with particularly intense production occurring in northern Punjab. Notably, GAEZ does not report agricultural data in AJK, as this is considered part of the disputed Kashmir territory by some accounts. This lapse in data is unfortnate, especially given the high incidence of conventional militant attacks in AJK reported by the BFRS data. As described in Appendix E, I correct for this omission in some regression specifications by imputing crop production data to missing value districts from adjacent nonmissing districts. The imputation does not significantly change the regression results. In addition to the substantial geographic variation exhibited in Figure 2, the level of militant violence is highly variable over time. Figure 4 demonstrates this phenomenon by plotting the evolution of violence over time separately for each Pakistani province. Violence generally increases over time for most provinces, especially in FATA and Khyber Pakhtunkhwa. Two notable exceptions are AJK and Gilgit-Baltistan, which see increases in violence followed by subsequent declines. In the case of Gilgit-Baltistan, this observed pattern might be due to a low number of observed violent incidents in general in that province. I account for the possibility that secular trends in the overall level of violence differ across provinces by including 1

12 province level linear time trends in my empirical specification. Similar plots to Figure 2, disaggregated to separately record different violence types, are given in Appendix C. In general, there asymmetric and conventional violence are highly correlated; provinces with high levels of one violence type in a given year typically are also high in the other type. This suggests that the observed levels of both violence types in a given province are likely to at least in some part be the result of actions by the same organizations in other words, it is likely that some organizations engage both in conventional and asymmetric violence, and that the violence types are complements from the perspective of rebel leaders. Differential responses of the violence types to economic shocks are therefore likely to represent endogenous substitution on the part of rebel leaders, who strategically choose their violence type in response to external shocks to mobilization. If, on the other hand, the effect of shocks is the same for asymmetric and conventional conflict, then rebel leaders are not substituting but instead decreasing activity across all types. Province AJK Balochistan FATA Gilgit Baltistan KPK Punjab Sindh Table 2: Descriptive Statistics by Province Cotton Prod. Rice Prod. Ruggedness Num. Eth. Frac. (Tons/) (Tons/) (1 km) Districts (8.811) (11.251) (.87) (1.926) (3.613) (.47) (.19) (3.198) (.162) (.7) (.25) (4.997) (1.872) (.31) (2.943) (1.171) (.28) (.56) (1.81) (14.739) (.3) (.19) (9.661) (11.38) (.56) (.1) Note: This table reports means of key district level variables by province, with standard errors in parentheses. Due to low data availability, all variables in this table are assumed fixed over the time period of analysis. Ethnic fractionalization is the probability that two randomly chosen individuals from a given district will belong to different ethnolinguistic groups, and ranges between and 1. Ethnic fractionalization data is unavailable for AJK and Gilgit-Baltistan. Also, the reported agricultural production data for these regions is imputed from adjacent districts, as described in Appendix E Pakistan s provinces also vary significantly along other dimensions which may contribute significantly to the observed level of conflict. Table 2 provides descriptive statistics at the province level for a number of variables of interest. There is substantial variation in crop production across regions of Pakistan; Punjab is by far the highest-producing region of both cotton and rice over the sample period. In addition, the 11

13 relationship between cotton and rice production varies by province FATA, for example, is a relatively large producer of cotton but produces little rice, while Sindh produces far more rice than cotton. Also reported in Table 2 are descriptive statistics on Ethnic Fractionalization and Terrain Ruggedness, two frequently cited determinants of conflict intensity. Appendix D details the sources of these data. Because of the lack of available time-series data on ethnic fractionalization and the mostly time invariant properties of terrain ruggedness, these variables are not included in my primary regression specification, as they are absorbed into the included district level fixed effects. Furthermore, any regression that includes fixed effects at the province level and uses the variables in Table 2 as regressors to estimate conflict is unable to report anything beyond correlational estimates; in particular, the variation in ethnic fractionalization and terrain ruggedness is not necessarily exogenous with respect to the level of conflict. For this reason, I include results from this regression type in an Appendix (D), but do not report them in the main body of the paper. The results should be interpreted with this caveat in mind. 4 Methodology and Results I model insurgent violence as a function of economic shocks, district and time fixed effects, and province level linear time trends. Variables are aggregated to the district year level for the analysis. I estimate two regression designs. The first is intended to measure the effect of these variables on aggregate measures of conflict, such as the total number of militant attacks in a district in a given year. This specification allows for identification of broad trends in insurgent violence. The within country nature of my analysis offers a potential improvement over cross national studies of conflict, as many unobservable characteristics are likely to remain relatively constant over Pakistan s small geographic area. The second regression design aims to disaggregate this effect into effects on conventional and asymmetric violence. This decomposition is the main innovation of this paper, and allows testing for heterogeneity in the response of violence to its economic and population-level determinants. I make a number of assumptions throughout the analysis. First, due to the unavailability of time series data for these variables, I assume crop production to be fixed over the sample period. As Dube and Vargas (213) argue, while this assumption is an unfortunate consequence of poor data availability, it may also improve the validity of regression results by not recording the endogenous response of crop production to civil conflict. Second, I assume that Pakistan is a price-taker in the international market for cotton and rice, and that price shocks can be considered exogenous. This assumption follows established trends in the 12

14 Figure 2: Militant Attacks by District Total Number of Militant Attacks, Notes: This figure shows the total number of recorded militant attacks recorded in the BFRS dataset, over the entire timespan covered by the data. Militant attacks include attacks on state targets, conventional attacks on military, paramilitary, police or intelligence targets, and guerilla attacks on military, paramilitary, police or intelligence targets. Shapefile information for administrative boundaries is taken from the U.S. Census Bureau s Demobase Pakistan Project (U.S. Census Bureau, 21). 13

15 Figure 3: Cotton Production in Pakistan with District-Level Boundaries Total Cotton Production Total Rice Production Tons High : Tons High : Low : Low : Notes: This figure shows cotton and rice production throughout the country of Pakistan, as reported in raster data from the UN Global Agro-ecological Zones (GAEZ) database. Shapefile information for administrative boundaries is taken from the U.S. Census Bureau s Demobase Pakistan Project (U.S. Census Bureau, 21). 14

16 Total Militant Attacks by, by Province 2 Azad Jammu and Kashmir 3 Balochistan Federally Administered Tribal Areas 4 Khyber Pakhtunkhwa Punjab Sindh Gilgit Baltistan Figure 4: Province-Specific Violence Trends Notes: This figure shows the evolution of violence over time for every province in Pakistan. Violence is measured as the total number of militant attacks recorded in the BFRS dataset in the given year. Militant attacks include attacks on state targets, conventional attacks on military, paramilitary, police or intelligence targets, and guerilla attacks on military, paramilitary, police or intelligence targets. The trends given are optimal bandwidth Nadaraya-Watson kernel regression estimates, with symmetric 95% confidence intervals. 15

17 conflict literature. On average over the time frame of my analysis, Pakistani exports of cotton are 4.5% of global export volume, and exports of rice are 8.8%. Both of these values fall below the 1% cuttoff used by Bazzi and Blattman (214) in their analysis Model 1: The Effect of Economic Shocks on Political Violence Given provinces j, districts i within these provinces, and time t indexed by year, the primary initial OLS specification for testing for broad violence trends is the following: y ijt = α i + β t + δ j t + (Crops i P t ) λ + ɛ ijt (1) Here, y ijt is a measure of conflict. I consider two outcome variables: the number of attacks in a given district in a given year, and the total number of deaths from conflict in a given district in a given year. The coefficients α i and β t represent district and time fixed effects, respectively. The term δ j t is a province specific linear time trend, and is intended to capture differential trends in insurgent violence over time at the province level for reasons external to changes in agricultural revenue. As Figure 4 demonstrates, there is substantial variation in insurgent violence across provinces and over time, and the temporal trend in violence differs across provinces. This differential trend motivates my inclusion of this trend. The economic coefficient of interest is λ, the regression coefficient for the variable (Crops i P t ). This variable interacts the district level production of crops with their time varying international price. Therefore, λ measures the effect of a unit increase in revenue from crops, which in my analysis are cotton and rice, on the conflict measure y ijt. I take changes in the international commodity price P t to be exogenous, and therefore interpret changes in the variable (Crops i P t ) as local income shocks at the district year level. I consider two crops, cotton and rice, in my analysis. For this reason, the variable (Crops i P t ) and the coefficient λ are actually two-component vectors (one component for each crop), and λ = (λ c, λ r ) records the effect of shocks to cotton and rice revenue separately Results Table 3 records the results of OLS estimation of Equation 1. Column (1) is a simple baseline specification that does not include the province-specific time trend δ j t. Columns (3) and (5) correct for missing crop 4 There are some years in which Pakistani exports of rice exceed the 1% threshold used by Bazzi and Blattman (214), though this share never exceeds 15%. An interesting direction for further study would be a paper that accounts directly for the possibility of endogeneity by instrumenting for shocks in the international price of rice. 16

18 data in some districts by imputing these values from adjacent districts, in a procedure that is detailed in Appendix E. Columns (4) and (5) lag the price shock to revenue by one year. Column (5) is my preferred specification. The regression yields two main results. First, increased agricultural revenue due to rice production is significantly and negatively related to conflict. This result is robust across all specifications, and is consistent with an opportunity cost model of insurgent choice in which positive shocks to income increase the opportunity cost of rebellion, and therefore decrease its amount. The magnitude of this effect is large: in the preferred specification, a standard deviation increase in the international price of rice is responsible, in the average rice producing district, for approximately.91 fewer militant attacks in a given year. This decrease is approximately equal to 32.9% of the average district year level of violence. Second, shocks to agricultural revenue from the production of cotton are not estimated to have statistically significant effects on the degree of violence in a given district year. A number of factors may explain the difference in this effect. First, the variance of the price of rice is slightly higher than the price of cotton, 5 so the larger economic shocks due to this fluctuation may be responsible for higher responsiveness of outcome violence measures. Second, and more importantly, the export weight of cotton declines substantially over the analysis period as shown in Figure 1, while the export weight of rice remains relatively constant over time. The sharp decline in the importance of cotton exports in total Pakistani export volume over the time period is consistent with the result that international cotton price shocks have less importance in determining the degree of violence. 4.2 Model 2: Differential Responses by Conflict Type Theory predics that the responses of conventional and asymmetric violence to shocks to mobilization may be different in magnitude or even opposite in sign (Bueno de Mesquita, 213). I test this theory by estimating the following equation relating asymmetric and conventional violence to economic shocks and local characteristics: y ijt = α i + β t + δ j t + Conventional i ρ + (Crops i P t ) λ + [Conventional i (Crops i P t )] η + ɛ ijt (2) As in Equation 1, y ijt is a measure of violence in district i, belonging to province j, at time t. The model includes district-level fixed effects α i and time fixed effects β t, as well as the province-specific linear time 5 The variance of the log price of rice is.274. The variance of the log price of cotton is

19 Table 3: Results of OLS Differences in Differences Regression Dependent Variable: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Cotton Production * log Price (.2) (.26) (.25) (.27) (.26) Rice Production * log Price (.23) (.21) (.23) (.23) (.23) Dependent Variable: Number of Deaths Cotton Production * log Price (.92) (.13) (.124) (.136) (.129) Rice Production * log Price (.19) (.176) (.168) (.214) (.23) Province level linear time trend no yes yes yes yes Imputed crop values for KPK and GB no no yes no yes Price shock lagged one year no no no yes yes Observations Adjusted R 2 Panel Adjusted R 2 Panel Notes: p <.5, p <.1, p <.1. Standard errors are clustered at the division level, and are reported in parentheses. Divisions are administrative divisions of Pakistan which are supersets of districts but subsets of provinces. Columns (2) through (5) differ from the baseline specification by including province-level linear time trends in the regression. Columns (4) and (5) differ from the baseline specification by lagging the price shock by one year. Columns (3) and (5) differ from the baseline specification by including districts for which crop data is initially missing, but is imputed according to the crop production of neighboring districts. Appendix E describes this imputation process. 18

20 trend δ j t. As in Equation 1, the variable ( ) Crops ij P t is interpreted as a local shock to agricultural revenue, and is decomposable into shocks from cotton and rice production. The methodology for estimating Equation 2 differs slightly from that required to estimate Equation 1. In particular, rather than using a dataset with one observation for every district year, the data is first stacked to contain two observations per district year: one measuring violent outcomes from asymmetric violence, and one measuring these outcomes from conventional violence. The dummy variable Conventional i indicates whether a given observation records conventional or asymmetric violence. In this construction, the estimate of the coefficient λ will record the effect of local income shocks on asymmetric violence. The estimate of η will measure the violence premium from conventional violence that is, it is a measure of the difference between the effects of local income shocks on conventional conflict and the effects on asymmetric conflict. Therefore, the sum λ + η gives the effect of agricultural price shocks on the level of conventional violence. Table 4 provides estimates from estimation of Equation 2. As in Table 3, columns (2) through (5) include province-specific linear time trends, columns (3) and (5) impute missing crop data for some districts, and columns (4) and (5) lag shocks to crop prices by one year. Column (5) is my preferred specification. Estimation of Equation 2 yields a number of conclusions. First, in every specification, positive shocks to local revenue from the production of rice are significantly and negatively correlated with the incidence and intensity of asymmetric violence. I interpret this as evidence of an opportunity cost mechanism in the production of violence. The effects are far less significant for price shocks to cotton than they are due to rice, which again may be due to the relatively larger importance of rice in Pakistani exports. The scaling parameter ρ is negative and significant in all specifications, and reflects the lower frequency of conventional attacks relative to asymmetric attacks. Second, the effect of shocks to agricultural revenue on the degree of violence is remarkably similar for conventional and asymmetric conflict. Indeed, in every specification the estimates of the conventional premium, η, are statistically identical to zero. This is a surprising result given the substantial qualitative differences between the technology of asymmetric and conventional violence in particular, asymmetric attacks typically require smaller levels of mobilization than conventional attacks, and insurgencies relying primarily on asymmetric tactics are on average less explicilty regimented and bureaucratic than primarily conventional insurgencies. Furthermore, the goals of asymmetric and conventional fighters may be different while conventional insurgencies are typically explicitly concerned with wresting territorial control from incumbent governments (DeVotta, 24), asymmetric insurgencies are often aimed at producing smaller scale territorial concessions (Pape, 23). 19

21 Table 4: OLS Estimation of Differential Effects by Violence Type Dependent Variable: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Conventional Dummy (ρ) (.684) (.684) (.83) (.684) (.85) Cotton Production * log Price (λ c ) (.11) (.13) (.13).14) (.13) Rice Production * log Price (λ r ) (.11) (.11) (.12) (.11) (.12) Conventional Cotton Revenue (η c ) (.2) (.2) (.2) (.2) (.2) Conventional Rice Revenue (η r ) (.1) (.1) (.1) (.1) (.1) Dependent Variable: Number of Deaths Conventional Dummy (ρ) (.654) (.655) (.713) (.656) (.715) Cotton Production * log Price (λ c ) (.12) (.15) (.14) (.14) (.13) Rice Production * log Price (λ r ) (.23) (.19) (.19) (.22) (.21) Conventional Cotton Revenue (η c ) (.3) (.3) (.2) (.3) (.2) Conventional Rice Revenue (η r ) (.2) (.2) (.2) (.2) (.2) Province level linear time trend no yes yes yes yes Imputed crop values for KPK and GB no no yes no yes Price shock lagged one year no no no yes yes Observations Adjusted R 2 Panel Adjusted R 2 Panel Notes: p <.5, p <.1, p <.1. Standard errors in parentheses. Columns (2) through (5) differ from the baseline specification by including province-level linear time trends in the regression. Columns (4) and (5) differ from the baseline specification by lagging the price shock by one year. Columns (3) and (5) differ from the baseline specification by including districts for which crop data is initially missing, but is imputed according to the crop production of neighboring districts. Appendix E describes this imputation process. 2

22 This result can be interpreted as evidence against the theory that rebel leaders make significant endogenous strategic substitutions in violence type in response to exogenous shocks to mobilization. Rather, while the level of conventional violence is lower on average than the level of asymmetric violence, the two violence types respond very similarly to economic shocks. Under the assumption of a unitary rebel leader choosing between two different types of violence given a level of mobilization, this would imply a broad organizational response to these shocks across all strategies rather than internal substitution based on the labor intensivity of different violence types. 5 Discussion of Results and Conclusion I begin by discussing the results relating economic variables to conflict. Negative shocks to agricultural revenue are significantly related to increased conflict incidence, as measured by the number of attacks, and conflict intensity, as measured by the number of deaths. The effect of revenue shocks due to cotton is much less significant, both in magnitude and statistically, than the effect of shocks due to rice. I argue that this discrepancy is due to the large export share of rice in Pakistan relative to the export share of cotton. In particular, this difference is especially severe towards the end of the sample period, when violence is most severe; while rice exports remain relatively constant, exports of cotton fall almost to zero, as demonstrated in Figure 1. For this reason, I argue that the difference in the effects of cotton and rice revenue on the degree of violence acts almost as a placebo exercise that demonstrates that the observed relationship between crop price fluctuations and the degree of violence depends on the crop s actual importance in Pakistani exports. The very low export weight of cotton towards the end of the estimation sample implies that shocks to the international price of cotton should have less bearing on local economies. As the results in Table 4 demonstrate, the effect of local revenue shocks on violence persists at almost the same level of magnitude for both asymmetric and conventional conflict. This homogeneity is surprising given the differences in the technology of conflict employed in conventional and asymmetric insurgencies, and provides a number of promising directions for future empirical research. While the distinction between asymmetric and conventional violence is useful for the purposes of my study, these broad categories are far from capturing the immense degree of heterogeneity in the strategies pursued by rebel groups. A finer characterization of differential violence types may provide deeper insights on the question of which types of violence respond particularly strongly to economic shocks. In particular, a relevant consideration that I largely exclude from my analysis is collusion between insurgent groups and the state, a consideration that 21

23 certainly has implications for the degree of rebel violence, but may affect conventional and asymmetric groups differently (Staniland, 212; Carey et al., 215). The main empirical difficulty in attempting to distinguish between different rebel strategies, however, is that the analyst is usually only able to observe the outcome of rebel strategy (for example, an actual attack) but not the strategic calculations that produce it. Data that classifies insurgent violence in great detail may therefore be hugely valuable in proxying for a wide range of rebel strategic choices. A second limitation of the current study is the paucity of high quality data available on Pakistan. In particular, the lack of time series agricultural data on cotton and rice production forces the assumption that these production levels are fixed. In reality, there is reason to believe that there exist substantial endogeneities between the level of conflict and agricultural income; for example, destructive attacks may make farming a dangerous activity, or lower the value of affected land. While this time series data did not exist for almost the entire duration of this project, it has very recently become available on a provisional basis as part of a collaboration between the government of Pakistan, the USDA, and a number of independent and academic institutions. 6 Incorporation of this data could potentially allow for approaches that directly address endogeneities in agricultural production as they respond to conflict levels for example, the level of rainfall could be used to instrument for production levels or economic variables under the assumption that these shocks do not affect conflict, as in Miguel et al. (24). Further studies could also incorporate other exports, such as wheat and sugar, to test for the persistence of these effects across agricultural categories. Despite these limitations, the current study does provide useful insight into the relationship between economic shocks and the level of conflict. In particular, positive shocks to income are robustly and negatively related to the number of attacks. This is consistent with an opportunity cost model of conflict, in which positive shocks to income decrease labor supplied to violence by increasing the opportunity cost of leaving conventional work. My results replicate the results of Dube and Vargas (213) in this regard, which find a similar relationship between income shocks due to changes in the international price of coffee and the level of insurgency in Colombia. As mentioned earlier in this report, Dube and Vargas also distinguish between opportunity cost effects, and the opposite rapacity effect in which positive shocks increase the value of contestable goods, and therefore increase conflict. The authors test for this effect by using changes in the international commodity price of oil, a capital intensive good. As Pakistan is also an exporter of oil, data on these exports could allow testing for similar rapacity effects in a different institutional setting, and offers another promising direction for future research. 6 See the Pakistan Agriculture Information System, accessible at 22

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict, 1960-2006 Sources: Data based on UCDP/PRIO armed conflict database (N. P. Gleditsch et al., 2002; Harbom & Wallensteen, 2007).

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland Online Appendix Laia Balcells (Duke University), Lesley-Ann Daniels (Institut Barcelona d Estudis Internacionals & Universitat

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Trade and civil conflict: Revisiting the cross-country evidence *

Trade and civil conflict: Revisiting the cross-country evidence * Trade and civil conflict: Revisiting the cross-country evidence * Massimiliano Calì and Alen Mulabdic This version: December 2014 We revisit and expand the evidence on the impact of trade shocks on intra-state

More information

Measuring political violence in Pakistan

Measuring political violence in Pakistan The Pearson Institute Discussion Paper No. 17 Measuring political violence in Pakistan Insights from the BFRS Dataset Ethan Bueno de Mesquita C. Christine Fair Jenna Jordan Rasul Bakhsh Rais Jacob N. Shapiro

More information

The BFRS Political Violence in Pakistan Dataset 1. Ethan Bueno de Mesquita C. Christine Fair Jenna Jordan Rasul Bakhsh Rais Jacob N.

The BFRS Political Violence in Pakistan Dataset 1. Ethan Bueno de Mesquita C. Christine Fair Jenna Jordan Rasul Bakhsh Rais Jacob N. The BFRS Political Violence in Pakistan Dataset 1 Ethan Bueno de Mesquita C. Christine Fair Jenna Jordan Rasul Bakhsh Rais Jacob N. Shapiro This version: July 7, 2013 Abstract This article presents the

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE EMPLOYMENT, WAGES AND VOTER TURNOUT Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration Means Online Appendix Table 1 presents the summary statistics of turnout for the five types of elections

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset. World Politics, vol. 68, no. 2, April 2016.* David E. Cunningham University of

More information

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be he Nonlinear Relationship Between errorism and Poverty Byline: Poverty and errorism Walter Enders and Gary A. Hoover 1 he fact that most terrorist attacks are staged in low income countries seems to support

More information

Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World

Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World Xiao 1 Yan Xiao Final Draft: Thesis Proposal Junior Honor Seminar May 10, 2004 Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World Introduction Peace and prosperity are

More information

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities National Poverty Center Working Paper Series #05-12 August 2005 Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities George J. Borjas Harvard University This paper is available online at the National Poverty Center

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Violent Conflict and Inequality Violent Conflict and Inequality work in progress Cagatay Bircan University of Michigan Tilman Brück DIW Berlin, Humboldt University Berlin, IZA and Households in Conflict Network Marc Vothknecht DIW Berlin

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 11217 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11217 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization

5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization 5 Chapter 8 Appendix 5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization We now turn to our primary focus that is the link between the long-run patterns of conflict and various measures of fractionalization.

More information

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia by Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware and Thuan Q. Thai Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research March 2012 2

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil Peter Brummund Laura Connolly University of Alabama July 26, 2018 Abstract Many countries continue to integrate into the world economy,

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 56 Number 4 Article 5 2003 Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Chinhui Juhn University of Houston Recommended Citation Juhn,

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict?

Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict? Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict? A GLOBAL ANALYSIS FHI 360 EDUCATION POLICY AND DATA CENTER United Nations Children s Fund Peacebuilding Education and Advocacy Programme Education

More information

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment Manuel Bagues, Pamela Campa May 22, 2017 Abstract Casas-Arce and Saiz (2015) study how gender quotas in candidate lists affect voting behavior

More information

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution Per Krusell Institute for International Economic Studies, CEPR, NBER Anthony A. Smith, Jr. Yale University, NBER February 6, 2015 The project

More information

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015 Powersharing, Protection, and Peace Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm September 17, 2015 Corresponding Author: Yonatan Lupu, Department of Political Science,

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Long-Run Causes of Comparative Economic Development Institutions University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Outline 1 Introduction 2 3 The Korean Case The Korean

More information

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island Raden M Purnagunawan Outline 1. Introduction 2. Brief Literature review 3. Data Source and Construction 4. The aggregate commuting

More information

Trade and Civil Conflict

Trade and Civil Conflict Policy Research Working Paper 7125 WPS7125 Trade and Civil Conflict Revisiting the Cross-Country Evidence Massimiliano Calì Alen Mulabdic Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public

More information

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Axel Dreher a Justina A. V. Fischer b November 2010 Economics Letters, forthcoming Abstract Using a country panel of domestic

More information

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1 USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1 Shigeo Hirano Department of Political Science Columbia University James M. Snyder, Jr. Departments of Political

More information

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust? Comment on Corak (2013) Bradley J. Setzler 1 Presented to Economics 350 Department of Economics University of Chicago setzler@uchicago.edu January 15, 2014 1 Thanks to James Heckman for many helpful comments.

More information

ESTIMATE THE EFFECT OF POLICE ON CRIME USING ELECTORAL DATA AND UPDATED DATA

ESTIMATE THE EFFECT OF POLICE ON CRIME USING ELECTORAL DATA AND UPDATED DATA Clemson University TigerPrints All Theses Theses 5-2013 ESTIMATE THE EFFECT OF POLICE ON CRIME USING ELECTORAL DATA AND UPDATED DATA Yaqi Wang Clemson University, yaqiw@g.clemson.edu Follow this and additional

More information

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa International Affairs Program Research Report How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa Report Prepared by Bilge Erten Assistant

More information

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks Lee Tucker Boston University This version: October 15, 2014 Abstract Observational evidence has shown

More information

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Grantham Research Institute and LSE Cities, London School of Economics IAERE February 2016 Research question Is signaling a driving

More information

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations The Determinants and the Selection of Mexico-US Migrations J. William Ambrosini (UC, Davis) Giovanni Peri, (UC, Davis and NBER) This draft March 2011 Abstract Using data from the Mexican Family Life Survey

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia Ruben Enikolopov, Maria Petrova, Ekaterina Zhuravskaya Web Appendix Table A1. Summary statistics. Intention to vote and reported vote, December 1999

More information

Legislatures and Growth

Legislatures and Growth Legislatures and Growth Andrew Jonelis andrew.jonelis@uky.edu 219.718.5703 550 S Limestone, Lexington KY 40506 Gatton College of Business and Economics, University of Kentucky Abstract This paper documents

More information

Returnees Spark More Violence: The Causal Effect of Refugee Return on Civil Conflict Intensity

Returnees Spark More Violence: The Causal Effect of Refugee Return on Civil Conflict Intensity Returnees Spark More Violence: The Causal Effect of Refugee Return on Civil Conflict Intensity Kara Ross Camarena Prepared for: The 70th Annual MPSA Conference International Relations Poster Session April

More information

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Shan Jiang November 7, 2007 Abstract Recent theories suggest that better information in destination countries could reduce firm s fixed export costs, lower uncertainty

More information

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa Julia Bredtmann 1, Fernanda Martinez Flores 1,2, and Sebastian Otten 1,2,3 1 RWI, Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung

More information

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict Undergraduate Economic Review Volume 8 Issue 1 Article 10 2012 Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict Katharine M. Lindquist Carleton

More information

Measuring the Shadow Economy of Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka ( )

Measuring the Shadow Economy of Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka ( ) Measuring the Shadow Economy of Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka (1995-2014) M. Kabir Hassan Blake Rayfield Makeen Huda Corresponding Author M. Kabir Hassan, Ph.D. 2016 IDB Laureate in Islamic

More information

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Transnational Dimensions of Civil War Kristian Skrede Gleditsch University of California, San Diego & Centre for the Study of Civil War, International Peace Research Institute, Oslo See http://weber.ucsd.edu/

More information

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Industrial & Labor Relations Review Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 60, Issue 3 2007 Article 5 Labor Market Institutions and Wage Inequality Winfried Koeniger Marco Leonardi Luca Nunziata IZA, University of Bonn, University of

More information

Exporters and Wage Inequality during the Great Recession - Evidence from Germany

Exporters and Wage Inequality during the Great Recession - Evidence from Germany BGPE Discussion Paper No. 158 Exporters and Wage Inequality during the Great Recession - Evidence from Germany Wolfgang Dauth Hans-Joerg Schmerer Erwin Winkler April 2015 ISSN 1863-5733 Editor: Prof. Regina

More information

BOOK SUMMARY. Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War. Laia Balcells Duke University

BOOK SUMMARY. Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War. Laia Balcells Duke University BOOK SUMMARY Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War Laia Balcells Duke University Introduction What explains violence against civilians in civil wars? Why do armed groups use violence

More information

John Parman Introduction. Trevon Logan. William & Mary. Ohio State University. Measuring Historical Residential Segregation. Trevon Logan.

John Parman Introduction. Trevon Logan. William & Mary. Ohio State University. Measuring Historical Residential Segregation. Trevon Logan. Ohio State University William & Mary Across Over and its NAACP March for Open Housing, Detroit, 1963 Motivation There is a long history of racial discrimination in the United States Tied in with this is

More information

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector Pierre Mérel and Zach Rutledge July 7, 2017 Abstract This paper provides new estimates of the short-run impacts of

More information

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: 1966-2000 Abdurrahman Aydemir Family and Labour Studies Division Statistics Canada aydeabd@statcan.ca 613-951-3821 and Mikal Skuterud

More information

Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution

Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution Paul Christian (World Bank) and Christopher B. Barrett (Cornell) University of Connecticut November 17, 2017 Background Motivation

More information

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida John R. Lott, Jr. School of Law Yale University 127 Wall Street New Haven, CT 06511 (203) 432-2366 john.lott@yale.edu revised July 15, 2001 * This paper

More information

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA Mahari Bailey, et al., : Plaintiffs : C.A. No. 10-5952 : v. : : City of Philadelphia, et al., : Defendants : PLAINTIFFS EIGHTH

More information

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at American Economic Association Poverty, Political Freedom, and the Roots of Terrorism Author(s): Alberto Abadie Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 2 (May, 2006), pp. 50-56 Published by:

More information

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation: Evidence from Financial Market Participation. Una Okonkwo Osili 1 Anna Paulson 2

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation: Evidence from Financial Market Participation. Una Okonkwo Osili 1 Anna Paulson 2 Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation: Evidence from Financial Market Participation Una Okonkwo Osili 1 Anna Paulson 2 1 Contact Information: Department of Economics, Indiana University Purdue

More information

Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia. June Abstract

Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia. June Abstract Residual Wage Inequality: A Re-examination* Thomas Lemieux University of British Columbia June 2003 Abstract The standard view in the literature on wage inequality is that within-group, or residual, wage

More information

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India Chattopadhayay and Duflo (Econometrica 2004) Presented by Nicolas Guida Johnson and Ngoc Nguyen Nov 8, 2018 Introduction Research

More information

Repression or Civil War?

Repression or Civil War? Repression or Civil War? Timothy Besley London School of Economics and CIFAR Torsten Persson IIES, Stockholm University and CIFAR January 1, 2009 1 Introduction Perhaps the croning achievement of mature

More information

ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF WAR: EVIDENCE FROM FIRM-LEVEL PANEL DATA

ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF WAR: EVIDENCE FROM FIRM-LEVEL PANEL DATA ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF WAR: EVIDENCE FROM FIRM-LEVEL PANEL DATA Micheline Goedhuys Eleonora Nillesen Marina Tkalec September 25, 2018 Goedhuys et al., 2018 SmartEIZ Conference September 25, 2018 1 /

More information

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter?

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? An Innovative Approach to the Characterisation of the European Political Space. Giovanna Iannantuoni, Elena Manzoni and Francesca Rossi EXTENDED

More information

Statistical Analysis of Endorsement Experiments: Measuring Support for Militant Groups in Pakistan

Statistical Analysis of Endorsement Experiments: Measuring Support for Militant Groups in Pakistan Statistical Analysis of Endorsement Experiments: Measuring Support for Militant Groups in Pakistan Kosuke Imai Department of Politics Princeton University Joint work with Will Bullock and Jacob Shapiro

More information

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States Charles Weber Harvard University May 2015 Abstract Are immigrants in the United States more likely to be enrolled

More information

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit Drivers of Inequality in South Africa by Janina Hundenborn, Murray Leibbrandt and Ingrid Woolard SALDRU Working Paper Number 194 NIDS Discussion Paper

More information

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA Openness and Internal Conflict Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA 17837 cmagee@bucknell.edu Tansa George Massoud Department of Political Science Bucknell

More information

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University February 2010 1 SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas ABSTRACT The employment

More information

democratic or capitalist peace, and other topics are fragile, that the conclusions of

democratic or capitalist peace, and other topics are fragile, that the conclusions of New Explorations into International Relations: Democracy, Foreign Investment, Terrorism, and Conflict. By Seung-Whan Choi. Athens, Ga.: University of Georgia Press, 2016. xxxiii +301pp. $84.95 cloth, $32.95

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

Patterns of Conflicts and Effectiveness of Aid

Patterns of Conflicts and Effectiveness of Aid Patterns of Conflicts and Effectiveness of Aid Arcangelo Dimico * Queen s University of Belfast This Version: 13/05/2012 Abstract The effect of aid on civil war is one of the most debated in economics.

More information

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES CHAIR OF MACROECONOMICS AND DEVELOPMENT Bachelor Seminar Economics of the very long run: Economics of Islam Summer semester 2017 Does Secular

More information

Cross-State Differences in the Minimum Wage and Out-of-state Commuting by Low-Wage Workers* Terra McKinnish University of Colorado Boulder and IZA

Cross-State Differences in the Minimum Wage and Out-of-state Commuting by Low-Wage Workers* Terra McKinnish University of Colorado Boulder and IZA Cross-State Differences in the Minimum Wage and Out-of-state Commuting by Low-Wage Workers* Terra McKinnish University of Colorado Boulder and IZA Abstract The 2009 federal minimum wage increase, which

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada,

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, 1987-26 Andrew Sharpe, Jean-Francois Arsenault, and Daniel Ershov 1 Centre for the Study of Living Standards

More information

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance PRELIMINARY WORK - PLEASE DO NOT CITE Ken Jackson August 8, 2012 Abstract Governing a diverse community is a difficult task, often made more difficult

More information

Online Appendix: The Effect of Education on Civic and Political Engagement in Non-Consolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria

Online Appendix: The Effect of Education on Civic and Political Engagement in Non-Consolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria Online Appendix: The Effect of Education on Civic and Political Engagement in Non-Consolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria Horacio Larreguy John Marshall May 2016 1 Missionary schools Figure A1:

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 8945 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8945 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Ethnic and Religious Polarization and Social

Ethnic and Religious Polarization and Social Ethnic and Religious Polarization and Social Conflict Joan Esteban Laura Mayoral January 13, 2011 First version November 2, 2009 Abstract In this paper we examine the link between ethnic and religious

More information

A Multivariate Analysis of the Factors that Correlate to the Unemployment Rate. Amit Naik, Tarah Reiter, Amanda Stype

A Multivariate Analysis of the Factors that Correlate to the Unemployment Rate. Amit Naik, Tarah Reiter, Amanda Stype A Multivariate Analysis of the Factors that Correlate to the Unemployment Rate Amit Naik, Tarah Reiter, Amanda Stype 2 Abstract We compiled a literature review to provide background information on our

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7019 English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap Alfonso Miranda Yu Zhu November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Practice Questions for Exam #2 Fall 2007 Page 1 Practice Questions for Exam #2 1. Suppose that we have collected a stratified random sample of 1,000 Hispanic adults and 1,000 non-hispanic adults. These respondents are asked whether

More information

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties Wenbin Chen, Matthew Keen San Francisco State University December 20, 2014 Abstract This article estimates

More information

Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes

Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes Decentralized Despotism: How Indirect Colonial Rule Undermines Contemporary Democratic Attitudes Evidence from Namibia Marie Lechler 1 Lachlan McNamee 2 1 University of Munich 2 Stanford University June

More information

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence Philip Keefer All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth

More information

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices Kim S. So, Peter F. Orazem, and Daniel M. Otto a May 1998 American Agricultural Economics Association

More information

Travel Time Use Over Five Decades

Travel Time Use Over Five Decades Institute for International Economic Policy Working Paper Series Elliott School of International Affairs The George Washington University Travel Time Use Over Five Decades IIEP WP 2016 24 Chao Wei George

More information

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival WWW.DAGLIANO.UNIMI.IT CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N. 350 April 2013 Export Growth and Firm Survival Julian Emami Namini* Giovanni Facchini** Ricardo A. López*** * Erasmus

More information

Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution

Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution By PAUL CHRISTIAN* AND CHRISTOPHER B. BARRETT September 2017 revised version A popular identification strategy in non-experimental

More information

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities Job Market Paper Sreenath Majumder Draft: November 2008 Abstract This paper examines the effect of public policy on population

More information

Wage Structure and Gender Earnings Differentials in China and. India*

Wage Structure and Gender Earnings Differentials in China and. India* Wage Structure and Gender Earnings Differentials in China and India* Jong-Wha Lee # Korea University Dainn Wie * National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies September 2015 * Lee: Economics Department,

More information

Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality

Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality In the analysis of weighted voting a scheme may be constructed which apportions at least one vote, per-representative units. The numbers of weighted votes

More information