Interindustry Goods Market Networks and Industry Lobbying for Trade Policy

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Interindustry Goods Market Networks and Industry Lobbying for Trade Policy"

Transcription

1 Foreign Policy Analysis (2017) 13, Interindustry Goods Market Networks and Industry Lobbying for Trade Policy HAK-SEON LEE James Madison University This study investigates how interindustry goods market networks influence industry lobbying as foreign firms direct investment and local production increase in the United States. The goods market networks consist of each sector s procurement of inputs from other sectors and the sectoral destinations of its outputs. I found that domestic upstream sectors modify their lobbying in ways dissimilar to those of downstream sectors when foreign firms local production and sales increase. Upstream sectors lobby more when US affiliates of foreign firms that procure inputs from their own supply chains gain market share at the expense of domestic firms in investment-receiving sectors. In contrast, downstream sectors lobby less when they save input procurement costs as domestic and foreign firms compete to produce quality goods at a lower price. The empirical results imply that goods market networks provide another theoretical framework, in addition to that provided by factor or sector models, in the analysis of demand side of trade policy. Introduction Foreign direct investment (FDI) by multinational corporations (MNCs) into the United States has significantly increased since the mid-1970s. 1 While previous research in political economy focused largely on how existing or threat of building trade barriers incur tariff-jumping investment (Hamada 1974; Brecher and Diaz- Alejandro 1977) 2 or quid pro quo investment that preempts protectionist measures (Bhagwati 1987; Dinopoulos 1989; Wong 1989; Bhagwati, Dinopoulos, and Wong 1992; Grossman and Helpman 1994), inward investment s impact on the demand side of trade politics has received attention only recently. Existing research shows mixed results on firms reactions to inward FDI. Regarding domestic firms political reactions to FDI inflows, researchers find that local firms lobbying for trade protection decreases because the benefits of pre-existing protectionist rents diminish once foreign firms enter US market and produce locally (Bhagwati and Irwin 1991; Hillman and Ursprung 1993; Blonigen and Feenstra 1996; Thomas 1997; Blonigen and Ohno 1998; Ellingsen and Warneryd 1999). This logic is closely related to the Mundell equivalence: Crossborder factor movement should lead to factor price equalization, just as international trade does (Mundell 1957; Svensson 1984). In contrast to these previous 1 The stock of inward FDI in the United States rose from $51.5 billion in the mid-1970s (2.6% of the total United States nonfinancial corporate net worth) to $425.6 billion in the early 1990s (11.6% in the same measure). See Graham and Krugman (1995). 2 The tariff-jumping FDI argument posits that MNCs have an incentive to engage in direct investment, so as to avoid trade barriers by local production and gain access to a local market. Lee, Hak-Seon. (2017) Interindustry Goods Market Networks and Industry Lobbying for Trade Policy. Foreign Policy Analysis, doi: /fpa VC 2014 International Studies Association

2 HAK-SEON LEE 51 works, more recently Zeng and Sherman (2009) argue that inward FDI may bring in a higher level of competition between foreign and domestic firms, and, as a result, domestic firms are more likely to increase demand for trade protection. These contradictory findings suggest that future research should revisit the linkage between inward FDI and firms lobbying for trade protection in host countries. Regarding the trade policy preference of US affiliates of foreign firms, Goodman, Spar, and Yoffie (1996) find that these firms advocate free trade when they engage in intrafirm trade with their parent firms, but begin to demand trade protection when they replace imports with local production in the United States. This finding complements the conventional wisdom that MNCs advocate free trade in home countries because home-country trade barriers may trigger retaliation by foreign governments, which in turn hurt multinationals intrafirm trade (Helleiner 1977; Milner 1988). Unlike these studies, which focus on how domestic or foreign firms react to inward FDI in their own sectors, Hiscox (2004) investigates how other sectors react to increasing cross-border investment. He finds that once FDI-receiving sectors expand production and pull labor from other sectors, the latter experience decreased returns and then lobby more for compensation. Focusing on interindustry labor flows between FDI-receiving sectors and other sectors, Hiscox (2004) expands the scope of investigation on FDI s impacts on industry lobbying. Moreover, his analysis that borrows a specific factor model by Jones and Neary (1984) permits an empirical test that closely corresponds to the theoretical model. 3 However, it still offers an incomplete explanation of the political impacts from inward FDI on the real economy, which is composed of multiple industries connected not only by labor flows but also by intermediate goods sales and purchases. This study adds another perspective to the approach by Hiscox (2004): It incorporates interindustry goods sales networks in the analysis of FDI and industry lobbying. The networks are represented by an input output (I-O) table that shows each sector s procurement of input goods from other sectors and the sectoral destinations of its outputs (Leontief 1983). Industries that sell their products to final goods producers are upstream of these producers. And industries that purchase intermediate goods from upstream producers are downstream of the sellers. The I-O linkage has been employed for the analysis of interest groups lobbying in trade politics. For example, Gawande and Bandyopadhyay (2000) argue that upstream and downstream sectors have conflicting interests related to trade policies in upstream sectors; upstream sectors demand trade protection while downstream sectors advocate free trade. In a similar vein, Cadot, de Melo, and Olarreaga (2004) and Gawande, Krishna, and Olarreaga (2012) find that upstream sectors pursuit of trade protection is affected by counter-lobbying by downstream sectors, which would experience higher input procurement costs if upstream sectors lobbying for protection succeeded. To analyze how inward FDI and interindustry goods market networks affect industry lobbying, this study sheds light on two elements of the network structure: (i) a given industry s level of goods sales (or purchases) dependencies upon other sectors; and (ii) the industry s position (i.e., upstream or downstream) in the network structure. First, the I-O linkage implies the existence of interindustry interdependencies of goods sales and purchases. Some sectors are more closely 3 The model assumes a domestic economy with three factors (labor and two kinds of capital) in two sectors that produce two goods. In the model, both kinds of capital are specific to sectors in which they are employed, while labor is mobile across sectors in the domestic economy. However, one kind of capital is assumed to be mobile across borders, while the other is not. Labor is not mobile internationally, either. See Hiscox (2004).

3 52 Interindustry Networks and Trade Policy Lobbying connected to each other because of a relatively large volume of goods sales between them. It is these nearby sectors for example, the ones with the strongest goods market connections that disturbances such as inward FDI into a given sector should most affect. In contrast, distant sectors that have few sales to (or purchases from) a FDI-receiving sector would not receive a substantial impact from the investment. As a result, nearby sectors will respond to inward FDI more strongly than distant sectors do. Second, a given industry s position is also important, because whether the industry in question is upstream or downstream of inward FDI may determine positive or negative impacts from the investment to the industry. Inward FDI into various US industries can illustrate how positive or negative impacts can be generated to upstream or downstream sectors. When foreign automobile firms undertake a greenfield investment and produce cars and trucks in the United States, the investment may affect the business environments of domestic suppliers of automobile parts (i.e., upstream of the US automobile industry) in different ways. Some domestic suppliers businesses are highly dependent upon their shipments to the automobile industry. Although in some cases the new arrivals become customers for existing US suppliers, foreign automobile companies producing in the United States usually procure the majority of their inputs from their parent firms via intrafirm trade or from home-country suppliers. Once US automobile producers lose market share to foreign entrants, US suppliers to domestic producers will receive a negative demand shock, and suppliers will then devote more resources to lobbying for compensation, ceteris paribus. 4 In contrast, downstream sectors reaction to inward FDI will differ from that of upstream sectors. For example, if the steel industry receives greenfield investment and increases output, the price of steel products in the domestic market will decrease, ceteris paribus. In this case, domestic automobile producers that are highly dependent upon the steel industry for their procurement of steel products should experience an increased rate of effective protection due to lowered procurement costs. In addition, more severe competition between new foreign entrants and domestic firms in the steel industry may benefit the automobile industry by providing quality products at a lower price. Then the automobile industry will be less likely to increase, or will even decrease, lobbying for trade protection, ceteris paribus. The empirical findings of this study confirm that a given sector s lobbying in trade politics is decisively influenced by its position in interindustry sales networks: Upstream sectors lobby more, and downstream sectors lobby less. Given two facts that inward FDI into the United States has been increasing since the 70s, and that the United States is currently the largest recipient of cross-border direct investment in the world the empirical findings of this study suggest that foreign firms investment into upstream sectors are more beneficial to US economy than investment into downstream sectors and thus should be encouraged by US foreign economic policies. This study proceeds as follows. The following section explains how inward FDI generates demand and supply shocks to upstream and downstream sectors via interindustry networks. Next, a set of hypotheses regarding industry demand for trade protection are empirically tested and the results are presented. The concluding section discusses the implications of this study on the trade politics literature and suggests directions for future research. 4 I assume that when foreign investment takes place, the affected sectors have a purely political reaction and do not respond by changing some aspects of their business or, at the extreme, exiting from the sector.

4 HAK-SEON LEE 53 Inward FDI and Interindustry Goods Market Networks I assume that the domestic economy is in equilibrium, and that the only relevant disturbance to the equilibrium is inward FDI. 5 I then address how the investment can trigger demand and supply shocks to upstream and downstream sectors, and how these sectors modify lobbying as a response to the investment. A given sector s reaction to events in FDI-receiving sectors is an increasing function of its input or output dependency on the sectors in question. I treat interindustry dependency as the proportion of a given sector s total purchases (or sales) that involve transactions with its upstream (or downstream) sector. A detailed explanation on the operationalization of interindustry dependencies is provided in the following empirical analysis section. Upstream Sectors Reaction to Inward FDI In specific circumstances, inward FDI may generate a positive or negative demand shock to domestic upstream sectors. In other circumstances, though, there can be no demand shock. Below, I explain a number of situations in which upstream sectors receive different demand shocks and how they modify lobbying accordingly. Once inward FDI occurs, two factors interact and may generate a demand shock to domestic upstream sectors. First, foreign firms procurement patterns of intermediate inputs need attention. On the one hand, foreign firms procurement may have supply rigidities for example, no change in quantity of goods supplied in the short run in the face of changes in the price of the good, which is a typical result of either intrafirm trade between parent firms and foreign affiliates or long-term supply contracts between multinationals and home-country suppliers. On the other hand, foreign firms may procure inputs from the most competitive suppliers without supply rigidities. The second factor that should influence the formation of a specific demand shock is changes in domestic market share between US and foreign firms in FDI-receiving sectors. If there is no significant change in domestic market share, no demand shock is generated to upstream sectors, ceteris paribus. A gain or loss in market shares by domestic firms vis-à-vis newly entered foreign firms may transmit positive or negative demand shocks to upstream sectors. Once specific demand shocks are generated, upstream sectors may modify their lobbying as a response to the shocks. In this process, upstream sectors level of competitiveness (i.e., import-competing or exporting) may also affect the modification of industry lobbying. Table 1 presents a summary of hypothesized changes in political efforts by upstream sectors responding to downstream FDI inflows. The table shows how (i) the presence or absence of supply rigidities by US affiliates of foreign firms; and (ii) domestic firms market share changes in FDI-receiving sectors should determine types of demand shocks transmitted to import-competing or exporting upstream sectors. Subsequently, the upstream sectors receiving different kind of demand shocks modify their lobbying accordingly. Cases of each demand shock are explained below. 5 Since this study deals with the effects of inward FDI, outward FDI by US multinationals is assumed to be in equilibrium as well. I consider only FDI rather than portfolio investment, which, by definition, does not alter the control of corporate assets. Nor do I investigate strategic alliances or licensing agreements between foreign competitors and domestic firms, because they do not involve flows of capital across borders. The Commerce Department defines a foreign investment as direct when a single investor has acquired a stake of 10% or more in a US firm. See Graham and Krugman (1995).

5 54 Interindustry Networks and Trade Policy Lobbying Table 1. Hypothesized Changes in Political Effort by Upstream Producers as a Consequence of Downstream Foreign Direct Investment Downstream Foreign Firms Procurement Patterns Supply Rigidities No Supply Rigidities Market Share Change in Downstream Sector Type of Demand Shock to Upstream Producers Upstream Producers Competitiveness Upstream Producers Response Loss of Market Share by Downstream Domestic Producers Negative Shock Increase lobbying Exporting Increase lobbying or Take no action Take no action Take no action N/A Importcompeting No Change or Gain in Market Share by Downstream Domestic Producers No Shock or Positive Shock* Importcompeting Exporting No Shock or Positive Shock Importcompeting Take no action or Increase lobbying** Exporting Take no action (Notes. *In a case of a gain in market share. In a case of an increase in total industry shipments after inward FDI. This assumes that upstream suppliers do not initially possess a long-term supply contract with arriving foreign firms downstream. If not substantially dependent upon downstream sectors. In a case of no shock. **In a case of positive shock.) No Demand Shock Before discussing cases of a positive or negative demand shock, it is necessary to point out that in some situations inward FDI transmits no shock to upstream sectors. First, in a case in which there are no supply rigidities, if there is no increase in total industry shipments in FDI-receiving sectors, domestic upstream sectors may not receive any demand shock regardless of their level of competitiveness. In this case, market share changes between domestic and foreign firms in FDI-receiving sectors are irrelevant because any firm in the receiving sectors will simply procure the most competitive inputs regardless of place of origin. 6 If domestic upstream sectors are competitive (and thus exporting), newly entered foreign firms are more likely to purchase inputs from the competitive producers. Since we assume there is no increase in total industry shipments in FDI-receiving sectors, the competitive suppliers simply have new customers (i.e., US affiliates of foreign firms) that replace previous customers (i.e., US firms). Nor will importcompeting upstream sectors receive any new demand shock from changes in ownership structure and market shares between domestic and foreign firms in FDI-receiving sectors. If the import-competing upstream producers have been lobbying for trade protection, they simply continue to do so, ceteris paribus. In a case in which supply rigidities do exist, if domestic upstream sectors still sell the same amount of inputs to domestic firms in FDI-receiving sectors, then no shock will be generated, ceteris paribus. This result may occur when US affiliates simply substitute previous exports to the United States with local production. In 6 An assumption is that international trade is relatively open so that importation of inputs is not restricted.

6 HAK-SEON LEE 55 this case, upstream sectors level of competitiveness makes no difference, because even competitive upstream suppliers cannot sell their products to newly entered foreign firms that rely on their own supply chains, such as parent firms or homecountry suppliers. When inward FDI generates no demand shock to domestic upstream sectors, they will have no incentive to modify their lobbying and thus take no action, because the sectors in question experience no change in business environments, ceteris paribus. Positive Demand Shock There are a few cases in which inward FDI may trigger a positive demand shock to upstream suppliers. First, in a case in which there are no supply rigidities, there will be a positive demand shock to domestic upstream sectors when there is an expansion of goods production in sectors receiving FDI, ceteris paribus. In this case, a positive demand shock to upstream suppliers will trigger contrasting responses from import-competing and exporting suppliers. Import-competing suppliers will have an incentive to lobby more because the positive demand shock increases the value of protection; once imports are excluded, there are more customers for the domestic suppliers, and hence more to gain by achieving protection (Ellingsen and Warneryd 1999). In contrast, exporting suppliers producing competitive inputs are more likely to increase sales to expanding sectors receiving FDI, and they are less likely to modify lobbying, ceteris paribus. Second, in a case in which supply rigidities do exist, domestic upstream sectors will receive a positive demand shock when US firms gain market share at the expense of foreign firms that rely on their own supply chains. In this case, domestic suppliers (regardless of their level of competitiveness) will be able to increase sales to FDI-receiving sectors and thus have no incentive to modify lobbying, ceteris paribus. The positive demand shock of this case can be generated either with or without an expansion in total industry shipment in FDI-receiving sectors, provided that supply rigidities exist. Negative Demand Shock Inward FDI will generate a negative demand shock to upstream sectors when two conditions are met: (i) if newly entered foreign firms have supply rigidities in procurement patterns; and (ii) if the foreign firms gain market share at the expense of domestic producers in FDI-receiving sectors. Procurement patterns by US affiliates are mandated by foreign ownership of the firms, which usually rely on intrafirm trade with parent firms, long-term supply contracts with home-country suppliers, and the suppliers accompanying investment into the United States. All of these procurement patterns provide supply rigidities. Foreign firms in the United States import more inputs than domestic firms do. The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) reports that US affiliates rely on imported inputs to a much greater degree than do US-owned firms. In 1989, the import share of inputs by US affiliates was 17%, while that of US-owned firms was 11%. 7 The significant difference in import propensity between foreign and USowned firms arises because MNCs usually undertake intrafirm trade when they engage in FDI, particularly at the early stage of the investment, to procure input goods unavailable from host country suppliers (Goodman et al.1996; Crystal 1998). Furthermore, the portion of intrafirm trade in total US imports has been substantial. In 1982, intrafirm trade accounted for 32% of total US imports of goods and services, increasing to 37% in 1993 (Whichard and Lowe 1995). 8 7 In 1994, the portion of imported inputs increased to 19% for US affiliates, while that of US-owned firms remained at 11%. See Zeile (1998). 8 This measurement includes imports from foreign affiliates to US parent firms and those from foreign parent firms to US affiliates.

7 56 Interindustry Networks and Trade Policy Lobbying Moreover, during the 1980s, two-thirds of total imports by the US affiliates came from their parent firms or other foreign affiliates (Zeile 1997). The US affiliates thus have had higher import propensities, and the majority of their imports have been supplied through intrafirm trade. Long-term supply contracts between multinationals and home-country suppliers are another source of supply rigidity. If transaction costs for switching suppliers are substantial, firms usually sign long-term contracts with their suppliers (Caves 1996). In such a situation, US affiliates would rely on previously contracted suppliers instead of US suppliers. When foreign firms invest in the United States, their home-country suppliers may undertake their own FDI following their customers. 9 Foreign suppliers have two incentives to do so. First, when foreign firms produce in host countries, they may require specifically designed parts that local suppliers cannot provide. Thus, the dependence of the original investing firm on differentiated products along with requirements for close communication and easy goods movement between supplier and purchaser, as well as substantial investment from both sides in a long-term relationship creates incentives for suppliers to choose a location close to their customers. The second incentive to spur home-country suppliers to follow their customer firms abroad is provided by domestic content regulations that require firms to use a certain amount of domestically produced inputs in producing outputs. 10 The US upstream suppliers may have several options in their response to a negative demand shock. First, in an extreme case, they might close their business. This exit option would be the last resort, though, and less likely to be a short-term response to inward FDI. A more plausible short-term solution would be to lobby the US government to set up policies that discourage inward FDI by foreign multinationals. However, the United States has adopted relatively liberal and open FDI policies from post-world War II till now, with the notable exception of regulations on inward FDI in US national security-related industries (Graham and Marchick 2006). Thus, lobbying the US government to restrict inward FDI would not be a realistic option for upstream suppliers. Firms or industries more frequently choose to lobby for trade protection in order to get relief from an unfavorable business environment. When import-competing upstream suppliers receive a negative demand shock triggered by inward FDI and foreign firms supply rigidities, the upstream sectors are more likely to increase lobbying for trade protection, ceteris paribus. If an import-competing upstream sector is highly dependent upon FDI-receiving sectors, the sector will accordingly devote substantial resources to lobbying. In contrast, if the sector is not highly dependent upon investment-receiving sectors, it would not modify lobbying in a significant way. An exporting supplier s reactions to a negative demand shock will hinge on the level of sales dependency upon FDI-receiving sectors. If the supplier experiences a significant negative demand shock because its sales to the investment-receiving sectors are critical to its business, even the exporting supplier may increase lobbying for compensation. In contrast, if the exporting supplier targets primarily foreign markets and is not highly dependent upon domestic customers, a negative shock after inward FDI will be negligible. In this case, the exporting supplier will be less likely to modify its lobbying, ceteris paribus. 9 The arrival of foreign input providers might also involve increased competition for the domestic firms supplying inputs in markets other than the sector receiving the original FDI. 10 Domestic content requirements to MNCs have usually been imposed by developing countries to encourage the host countries industrialization. Yet Japanese automobile companies practice of using Japanese parts when they produce cars overseas brought the issue to Europe and the US. See Krugman and Obstfeld (2003).

8 HAK-SEON LEE 57 To summarize various cases discussed above, when MNCs produce in the United States, domestic upstream sectors will either take no action or increase lobbying for protection. Also, as shown in Table 1, import-competing upstream sectors have more numerous circumstances in which they increase lobbying for trade protection. My theory of interindustry goods market networks and supply rigidities along with FDI-receiving sectors market share changes and upstream producers competitiveness yields two hypotheses: Hypothesis 1: The more an upstream sector depends upon sales to FDI-receiving sectors, the more effort it will devote to lobbying for trade protection, ceteris paribus. Hypothesis 2: An import-competing upstream sector will lobby more for trade protection than does an exporting sector when foreign firms production and sales increase in the United States, ceteris paribus. Downstream Sectors Reactions to Inward FDI When inward FDI occurs, domestic downstream sectors that procure inputs from FDI-receiving sectors may realize economic gains. First, in a case of greenfield FDI that involves newly established production facilities, there will be an increase in industry shipments in FDI-receiving sectors, ceteris paribus. 11 This increase will lower the price of the goods FDI-receiving sectors produce, and downstream sectors have economic gains because they can save procurement costs. Another source of gain to downstream sectors is intensified competition between domestic and foreign firms in FDI-receiving sectors. Previous studies suggest that more severe competition between foreign and domestic firms in host countries should encourage both to produce high-quality products at a lower price. As a result, downstream sectors gain as more foreign firms undertake local production (Pack and Saggi 1997; Blomstrom and Kokko 2001; Barrios, Goerg, and Strobl 2005; Kugler 2006). 12 The level of purchase dependency of a downstream sector upon FDI-receiving sectors will determine the relative size of gains. Sectors purchasing a relatively large amount of inputs from FDI-receiving sectors will gain more, while other sectors purchasing a smaller amount gain less. Any gain from lower procurement cost may decrease downstream sectors vulnerability to international competition, ceteris paribus. If the marginal savings from decreased lobbying exceeded the marginal losses in effective protection caused by lower trade barriers, downstream sectors might actually decrease lobbying for protection, ceteris paribus Some or all of that increase can be exported. However, as an empirical matter this assumption is unrealistic, because foreign investors usually undertake market-oriented FDI to sell output in the United States, which is the largest national market. 12 A caveat is that there may be potential changes in industry concentration ratio after inward FDI occurs. If all of inward FDI takes the form of mergers and acquisitions, then not only would there be no initial increase in output, but the resulting investment might also increase market concentration in upstream sectors, which would then subject downstream sectors to stronger oligopoly pricing. Under these circumstances, downstream sectors might be worse off. This prospect would give them a motive to seek higher levels of protection on their own outputs. These sectors might also seek redress by raising antitrust objections to M&A or seeking to impose or invoke barriers to the investment. In contrast, greenfield foreign investment would result in no increase in market concentration, as it involves no M&A, and industry output would increase. If the investing firm is a new arrival, it will actually reduce market concentration, ceteris paribus. 13 If we assume a minimal fixed cost for lobbying, the gains from lowering procurement cost and the magnitude of decreasing lobbying efforts will be a step function rather than a linear function. However, I assume that if a sector is spending a substantial amount of resources for lobbying, there should be a net decrease of lobbying, ceteris paribus.

9 58 Interindustry Networks and Trade Policy Lobbying Consideration of potential economic gains generated by foreign firms local production and sales transmitted to a downstream sector produces the third hypothesis. Hypothesis 3: The more a downstream sector depends upon FDI-receiving sectors for procurement of inputs, the less effort it will devote to lobbying for trade protection, ceteris paribus. 14 Testing Hypotheses To test my hypotheses, I adopt a quantitative approach for a comprehensive analysis of multiple interindustry goods sales networks and industry lobbying. The unit of analysis is an individual US manufacturing industry in a given time period. A total of 18 manufacturing industries are covered: two-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes from 20 to 38, with the exception of These industries are tradable sectors and data are readily available. 16 The time period is from 1981 to 1990, which spans five US Congresses (from the 97th to the 101st). This study focuses on the experiences of the 1980s for a practical reason: Data for the dependent variable industry level campaign contributions to candidates for US House of Representatives is readily available only for this decade. 17 In addition to the data-availability issue, the 1980s provides a suitable timeframe because inward FDI into the United States increased at a noticeably larger pace in the 1980s than in previous decades. While FDI inflows were less than half a percent of gross national production in the 1970s, they reached 1% at the beginning of the 1980s, and almost one and a half percent by the end of the decade (Graham and Krugman 1995). Table 2 provides a comparison chart on intra- and interindustry transactions for each manufacturing sector at the SIC two-digit level. As shown, interindustry transactions constitute the majority of these types of transactions, even though the ratio varies across sectors. The cross-industry variation implies each sector s level of dependency on other sectors, and my hypotheses predict that the level of dependency affects each sector s lobbying propensities. As explained below, a sector s sales and purchase dependencies upon other sectors are measured to represent cross-industry variation. To analyze industry campaign contributions, I employ the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimation with time period dummies that control for unexplained period and trend effects. In addition, OLS with panel-corrected standard errors (PCSEs) estimation is adopted because all of the error processes cannot be independent of one another in a panel data set with time variances (Beck and Katz 1995). Each model is estimated with one-period lagged independent variables to allow extra time for independent variables to influence the dependent variable. Most campaign contributions are made before members of Congress are elected and before they vote in the next congressional period. Thus, to test my theory empirically, it is essential to investigate how independent variables in the previous period affect campaign contributions in the current period. This paper focuses on impacts from different levels of foreign firms market share in the United States across industries, rather than on impacts from changing levels of inward 14 Supply rigidities in the upstream sector arising from intrafirm trade or long-term supply contracts are irrelevant to the downstream sector it is concerned only with price and availability of inputs. 15 SIC code 21 is the tobacco industry, and FDI into the industry is included in the SIC For the primary sectors (agriculture, forestry, and fishing), I-O Benchmark data cannot be converted to SIC two-digit codes. The service and construction sectors are not included because they were not tradable in the 1980s. 17 Data for other periods are available, but the cost of mapping it into SIC categories and coding it is very high. See Fordham and McKeown (2003).

10 HAK-SEON LEE 59 Table 2. Comparison of Intra- and Interindustry Transactions Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) Ratio of Intra-industry Transactions Ratio of Interindustry Transactions* 20 Food Textile Apparel Lumber and Wood Furniture Paper Printing and Publishing Chemicals Petroleum and Coal Rubber and Plastics Leather Stone, Clay and Glass Primary Metals Fabricated Metals Industry Machinery Electrical Machinery Transportation Equipment Instruments (Notes. *Interindustry transactions include each manufacturing sector s transactions with other manufacturing sectors and also those with nonmanufacturing sectors such as service sectors.) investment in a given industry across different periods. Still, industry fixed effects analyses are added for a reverse causality test: Generalized methods of moments (GMM) and error correction model (ECM). I measure industry lobbying for trade protection by calculating the total dollar amount of campaign contributions made by each manufacturing industry to electoral candidates for the House of Representatives who voted for protectionist bills in each of the five Congresses. The existing literature suggests that interest groups lobbying may target different groups of legislators. Interest groups lobby not just friend but also foe legislators in order either to counteract the influence of opposition interest groups (Austen-Smith and Wright 1994), 18 or target fence-sitters to persuade them to vote for favored policies by contributors (Rothenberg 1992). Interest groups campaign contributions have been employed for the analysis of lobbying in trade politics (Grossman and Helpman 1994; Grossman and Helpman 2002; Gawande 1998; Fredriksson 1999; Baldwin and Magee 2000; Gawande and Hoekman 2006; Leibman and Reynolds 2006; Gawande, Krishna, and Olarreaga 2009; Gilbert and Oladi 2012). Political action committees (PACs) are private interest groups organized to support political candidates to promote legislation that represents the PACs special interests. For example, Magee (2002) found that PACs reward candidates for adopting favorable policy positions in various economic and social issues, such as trade policy and gun control. In addition to contributions via PACs, interest groups lobby legislators through soft-money spending (Drope and Hansen 2004). However, in the case of soft money, it is not easy to identify direct links between interest groups and candidates, because the money is given to political parties first and then sent to specific candidates (Ansolabehere and Snyder 2000). A majority of PACs in the 1980s were individual corporations such as Kraft Foods or General Electric. Still, there exist business associations representing each manufacturing industry at the two-digit SIC level. Examples include the 18 Baumgartner and Leech (1996) argue that findings from Austen-Smith and Wright (1994) are erroneous because they use cross-sectional variance models where a longitudinal one is needed.

11 60 Interindustry Networks and Trade Policy Lobbying Association of Food Industries (20), the American Textile Manufacturers Institute (22), the American Apparel Manufacturers Association (23), the American Chemical Council (28), the American Petroleum Institute (29), and the Rubber Manufacturers Association (30). Other trade associations represent the SIC three-digit level, though, such as the American Iron and Steel Institute (331 & 332), the Alliance of Automobile Manufacturers (371), etc. Recently, Fordham and McKeown (2003) coded all corporate PAC campaign contributions between 1981 and 1990 into the two-digit SIC categories. The original data, though, includes all contributions made to any candidates regardless of those candidates preferences over trade policy. Yet, it is reasonable to assume that some candidates prefer protectionist policies while others advocate free trade. From the original data, I compiled data comprising campaign contributions made only to candidates who voted for protectionist bills, assuming that these contributions are a measurement of each industry s lobbying efforts for protectionist trade policies. In this paper, protectionist candidates are defined and measured in two ways candidates (i) who voted for any protectionist trade bills; and (ii) who voted for all of those bills in each Congress. Campaign contributions to protectionist candidates can be considered political efforts either to realize rents from protectionist trade policies or to compensate for a loss caused by the surge of imports. A caveat is that pressure groups might have made financial contributions to their favored candidates seeking benefits from other policies, not necessarily from trade policy. Still, industry contributions to protectionist candidates can be a valid measurement of corporate lobbying activities in trade politics because we can infer contributors lobbying purpose from their recipients voting records. 19 While some researchers found that campaign contributions do not directly affect legislative members voting patterns (Chappell 1982; Wright 1990; Hall and Wayman 1990; Wawro 2001), other researchers found not only that campaign contributions are a reflection of friendly giving to electoral candidates, but also that monetary contributions have independent impacts on the roll call voting of representatives (Fleisher 1993; Bronars and Lott 1997; Fellowes and Wolf 2004; Gordon 2005; Roscoe and Jenkins 2005). I employ three main explanatory variables: a given sector s own inward FDI as well as the sector s sales and purchase dependencies upon FDI-receiving sectors. The BEA publishes records of the total assets and sales values of both US affiliates of foreign firms and foreign affiliates of US firms at two- and three-digit SIC levels. 20 While the asset measurement of inward FDI is the portion of assets owned by foreign firms in total industry assets, the sales measurement indicates the portion of sales by US affiliates of foreign firms in total industry sales. Of the two measurements of FDI, the sales measurement is more relevant for the purpose of this paper, which is to investigate political impacts from the local production and goods sales by US affiliates. The own-sector inward FDI variable is employed to examine whether increasing foreign firms local production reduces incentives to lobby for protection or increase protectionist demand by domestic firms. This variable is constructed by the portion of shipments of US affiliates in total industry shipments. NIFDI i ¼ IFDI i =K i where IFDI is inward FDI measured by sales of US affiliates; NIFDI is normalized IFDI, and K is total industry shipments. Inward FDI variable in the regression models (Tables 5 and 6) indicates NIFDI. 19 The list of protectionist bills used to create the dependent variable is provided in Appendix The BEA collects data on FDI by means of mandatory surveys of the US affiliates of foreign firms and foreign affiliates of US firms.

12 HAK-SEON LEE 61 To investigate how interindustry goods market networks affect industry lobbying, two explanatory variables are created: a given sector s sales dependency, and its purchase dependency upon other sectors. These variables are compiled from the I-O accounts data by the BEA. The I-O data have their own industry classification codes, and I have converted them into two-digit SIC codes that are used for other main variables industry campaign contributions and inward FDI. 21 Sales dependency of sector i is the portion of shipments from sector i to sector j in sector i s total shipments; purchase dependency is similarly defined as SD ij ¼ s ij =s i and PD ij ¼ p ij =p i where SD ¼ sales dependency; s ¼ sales; PD ¼ purchase dependency, and p ¼ purchases. Own sector and another sector are indexed by i and j, respectively. 22 The impact of FDI in a given sector (sector i) on downstream purchases or upstream sales is taken to be proportional to the normalized investment into an investment-receiving sector (sector j). Inward investment s impact on an upstream or downstream sector will then be proportional to SD ij ðnifdi j Þ and PD ij ðnifdi j Þ respectively, where NIFDI j is a normalized shipment measure of inward investment in sector j. To arrive at the total impact of inward FDI on a given sector i, I then sum up the entire individual sector impacts: NSTOT i ¼ X j SD ijðnifdi j Þ and NPTOT i ¼ X j PD ijðnifdi j Þ where NSTOT i is the normalized total sales impact and NPTOT i is the normalized total purchase impact. A given sector s sales dependency variable (NSTOT) is employed to investigate how the sector s sales dependency upon FDI-receiving sectors will affect the sector s lobbying (Hypothesis 1). To test my conditional hypothesis (Hypothesis 2), which is to investigate import-competing upstream sectors reaction to inward FDI, I create an interaction term between NSTOT and the level of total industry imports. A given sector s purchase dependency (NPTOT) is employed to investigate how the sector s purchase dependency upon FDI-receiving sectors will influence the sector s lobbying (Hypothesis 3). Control variables that are conventionally believed to affect industrial trade policy preferences are also included in the regression models. The industry total shipments variable, which represents the size of an industry, is employed to test whether larger industries receive more attention from the government and thus are more likely to be active in lobbying (Lavergne 1983). A sector s import penetration level is predicted to be positively associated with industrial lobbying for trade protection because a higher level of import penetration is likely to trigger domestic import-competing producers to demand a higher level of trade protection, ceteris paribus. Total industry exports are predicted to be negatively related to industrial lobbying for protection, because export-oriented sectors are more concerned with global markets than with domestic markets; these sectors are less likely to lobby for trade protection due to potential retaliation in foreign markets 21 Background information for the I-O data is provided in Appendix These measures implicitly ignore the elasticity of demand and supply, an assumption generally consistent with input output analysis.

13 62 Interindustry Networks and Trade Policy Lobbying Table 3. Descriptive Statistics Obs. Mean Standard Deviation Minimum Maximum Industrial Campaign Contributions to , ,901 1,967 2,377,794 Protectionist Candidates (who voted for any protectionist bills) Industrial Campaign Contributions to , ,775 1,400 2,377,794 Protectionist Candidates (who voted for all protectionist bills) Inward FDI Sales Dependency Purchase Dependency Imports (1995 $bn) Exports (1995 $bn) Shipments (1995 $bn) Government Sales (1995 $bn) Capacity Utilization Industry Concentration once trade barriers are set up in the domestic market. A sector s total sales to the federal government is employed because an industry that sells heavily to the government is hypothesized to lobby more because of its sensitivity to government procurement patterns (Lichtenberg 1989; Zaleski 1992; Hansen, Mitchell, and Drope 2005). Another control variable is industry capacity utilization. Researchers have found that a lower level of industry capacity utilization is more likely to be associated with a higher level of protectionist demand (Strange 1979; Cassing, McKeown, and Ochs 1986; Hansen 1990). Lastly, the conventional wisdom in analyzing the demand side of trade politics is that a highly concentrated industry is better able to overcome the collective action problem between firms in the industry than are less concentrated industries. Acknowledging that industry preferences and actual lobbying activities cannot be equated because of the free-rider problem, this paper adopts another control variable: industry concentration ratio (measured by the market share of the four largest firms in each industry). Tables 3 and 4 provide basic statistics for each variable and the correlation matrix between variables, respectively. Tables 5 and 6 report the regression results on the analysis of industrial campaign contributions. The dependent variable is measured differently in each table. In Table 5, the variable is total industry contributions to candidates who voted for any protectionist bills in each election cycle. In Table 6, the variable is contributions to candidates who voted for all protectionist bills in each period. A smaller number of representatives did vote for all of protectionist trade bills, and thus, the total amount of contributions made by industries is relatively smaller in the latter. Each table adopts a total of six regression models. Model I is a baseline model including only control variables. The main explanatory variables are employed in Model II, and an interaction term is added in Model III. Model IV adopts the same variables as Model III, but PCSEs estimation is used. Models V and VI adopt industry fixed effects models: GMM and ECM, respectively. A given sector s inward FDI is seen to be negatively associated with contributions for trade protection, as shown in Models II through IV in both tables. This result shows that increased local production and sales by foreign firms in the United States should weaken industry lobbying, confirming the conventional argument that cross-border capital flows reduce industries incentives to lobby for

14 HAK-SEON LEE 63 Table 4. Correlation Matrix Inward FDI Sales Dependency Purchase Dependency Sales Dependency * Imports Imports Exports Shipments Gov t Sales Capacity Utilization Industry Concentration Inward FDI 1.0 Sales Dependency Purchase Dependency Sales Dependency * Imports Imports Exports Shipments Gov t Sales Capacity Utilization Industry Concentration

15 64 Interindustry Networks and Trade Policy Lobbying Table 5. Interindustry Goods Sales Network Structure and Industry Campaign Contributions, I II III IV V VI Lagged Industrial Contributions (0.126) Inward FDI (0.396)*** (0.376)*** (0.295)*** 0.33 (0.745) (0.774) Sales Dependency 10.2 (1.726)*** (2.072)** (1.401)*** (6.189) (6.479) Purchase Dependency (0.523)*** (0.483)*** (0.388)*** (1.157) (1.317) Sales Dependency* Imports (0.223)*** 0.89 (0.086)*** 0.52 (0.256)** (0.319)* Imports, (0.005)*** (0.004)*** (0.004) (0.002)*** (0.005) (0.005) Exports, (0.008)*** (0.006)*** (0.006)*** (0.003)*** (0.011)** (0.011)** Shipments, (0.0009)*** (0.0008)*** (0.0007)*** (0.0003)*** (0.001)* (0.001)* Government Sales, (0.003)*** (0.002)*** 0.02 (0.002)*** 0.02 (0.001)*** (0.04)*** (0.042)*** Capacity Utilization 0.02 (0.006)*** (0.005)*** 0.01 (0.004)** (0.002)*** (0.003) (0.003) Industry Concentration (0.004)*** (0.004)*** (0.003)*** (0.002)*** (0.005) (0.008) Observations Adjusted R-squared N/A 0.50 (Notes. Dependent variable: Industrial Campaign Contributions to Protectionist Candidates (who voted for any protectionist bills). Standard errors in parentheses. All estimations include constant. I, OLS with period dummies with control variables only; II, OLS with period dummies; III, OLS with period dummies with an interaction term; IV, OLS with PCSEs; V, GMM; VI, ECM. Significance at *10%, **5%, ***1%. Coefficients shown in millions US billion dollars.)

INTER-SECTORAL GOODS AND LABOR MARKET RELATIONSHIPS, INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY, AND US TRADE POLITICS IN THE 1980S.

INTER-SECTORAL GOODS AND LABOR MARKET RELATIONSHIPS, INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY, AND US TRADE POLITICS IN THE 1980S. INTER-SECTORAL GOODS AND LABOR MARKET RELATIONSHIPS, INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY, AND US TRADE POLITICS IN THE 1980S Hak-Seon Lee A dissertation submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina

More information

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter Organization Introduction The Specific Factors Model International Trade in the Specific Factors Model Income Distribution and the Gains from

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito The specific factors model allows trade to affect income distribution as in H-O model. Assumptions of the

More information

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins Cletus C Coughlin and Howard J. Wall 13. January 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30758/ MPRA

More information

The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Empirical Approaches

The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Empirical Approaches The Political Economy of Trade Policy Empirical Approaches Kishore Gawande University of New Mexico Pravin Krishna Brown University Political Economy of Trade Policy ² Trade Policy: Historically Never

More information

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Protection for Free? The Political Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Rodney Ludema, Georgetown University Anna Maria Mayda, Georgetown University and CEPR Prachi Mishra, International Monetary Fund Tariff

More information

Trade Costs and Export Decisions

Trade Costs and Export Decisions Chapter 8 Firms in the Global Economy: Export Decisions, Outsourcing, and Multinational Enterprises Trade Costs and Export Decisions Most U.S. firms do not report any exporting activity at all sell only

More information

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms Southeast Asian Journal of Economics 3(2), December 2015: 43-59 Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms Tanapong Potipiti Assistant professor, Faculty of Economics, Chulalongkorn University, Bangkok,

More information

Competitiveness: A Blessing or a Curse for Gender Equality? Yana van der Muelen Rodgers

Competitiveness: A Blessing or a Curse for Gender Equality? Yana van der Muelen Rodgers Competitiveness: A Blessing or a Curse for Gender Equality? Yana van der Muelen Rodgers Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium s (IATRC s)

More information

International Trade Lecture 25: Trade Policy Empirics (I)

International Trade Lecture 25: Trade Policy Empirics (I) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 25: Trade Policy Empirics (I) 14.581 Spring 2013 14.581 Trade Policy Empirics Spring 2013 1 / 19 Plan for 2 lectures on empirics of trade policy 1 Explaining trade policy

More information

The "New Economy" and Efficiency in Food Market System: -A Complement or a Battleground between Economic Classes?

The New Economy and Efficiency in Food Market System: -A Complement or a Battleground between Economic Classes? The "New Economy" and Efficiency in Food Market System: -A Complement or a Battleground between Economic Classes? by Gerald Schluter and Chinkook Lee Economic Research Service U.S. Department of Agriculture

More information

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009 Appendix to Attitudes Towards Highly Skilled and Low Skilled Immigration: Evidence from a Survey Experiment: Formal Derivation of the Predictions of the Labor Market Competition Model and the Fiscal Burden

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and Wages in Indonesian Manufacturing

Foreign Direct Investment and Wages in Indonesian Manufacturing Foreign Direct Investment and Wages in Indonesian Manufacturing Robert E. Lipsey, National Bureau of Economic Research and City University of New York and Fredrik Sjöholm, National University of Singapore

More information

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting By: Stuart D. Allen and Amelia S. Hopkins Allen, S. and Hopkins, A. The Textile Bill of 1990: The Determinants of Congressional

More information

Main Tables and Additional Tables accompanying The Effect of FDI on Job Separation

Main Tables and Additional Tables accompanying The Effect of FDI on Job Separation Main Tables and Additional Tables accompanying The Effect of FDI on Job Separation Sascha O. Becker U Munich, CESifo and IZA Marc-Andreas Muendler UC San Diego and CESifo November 13, 2006 Abstract A novel

More information

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization 3 Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization Given the evidence presented in chapter 2 on preferences about globalization policies, an important question to explore is whether any opinion cleavages

More information

Nominal and Effective Rates of Protection by Industry in Pakistan: A Tariff Based Analysis

Nominal and Effective Rates of Protection by Industry in Pakistan: A Tariff Based Analysis NUST JOURNAL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AND HUMANITIES Vol.3 No.1 (January-June 2017) pp.1-45 Nominal and Effective Rates of Protection by Industry in Pakistan: A Tariff Based Analysis Abstract: Nadeem Ul Haque

More information

Multinational Corporations in Indonesia and Thailand: An Overview of Effects on Wages, Productivity, and Exports

Multinational Corporations in Indonesia and Thailand: An Overview of Effects on Wages, Productivity, and Exports Multinational Corporations in Indonesia and Thailand: An Overview of Effects on Wages, Productivity, and Exports Eric D. Ramstetter International Centre for the Study of East Asian Development and Fredrik

More information

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper)

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper) INTERNATIONAL TRADE (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper) J. Peter Neary University College Dublin 25 September 2003 Address for correspondence:

More information

Chapter Ten Growth, Immigration, and Multinationals

Chapter Ten Growth, Immigration, and Multinationals Chapter Ten Growth, Immigration, and Multinationals 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning Chapter Ten Outline 1. What if Factors Can Move? 2 What if Factors Can Move? Welfare analysis of factor movements

More information

Chapter 4: Specific Factors and

Chapter 4: Specific Factors and Chapter 4: Specific Factors and Income Distribution Chapter Organization Introduction The Specific Factors Model International Trade in the Specific Factors Model Income Distribution and the Gains from

More information

Non-tariff Measures in the Lao People s Democratic Republic

Non-tariff Measures in the Lao People s Democratic Republic Chapter 6 Non-tariff Measures in the Lao People s Democratic Republic Amphaphone Sayasenh National Economic Research Institute, Lao People s Democratic Republic April 2016 This chapter should be cited

More information

Trade And Inequality With Limited Labor Mobility: Theory And Evidence From China Muqun Li and Ian Coxhead APPENDIX

Trade And Inequality With Limited Labor Mobility: Theory And Evidence From China Muqun Li and Ian Coxhead APPENDIX A-1 Trade And Inequality With Limited Labor Mobility: Theory And Evidence From China Muqun Li Ian Coxhead Contents: APPENDIX A.1. Proof of lemma 1... 1 A.2. Relative labor dem... 2 A.3. Trade balance conditions...

More information

Explaining Asian Outward FDI

Explaining Asian Outward FDI Explaining Asian Outward FDI Rashmi Banga UNCTAD-India ARTNeT Consultative Meeting on Trade and Investment Policy Coordination 16 17 July 2007, Bangkok SOME FACTS Outward FDI -phenomenon of the developed

More information

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity Chapter 2 A. Labor mobility costs Table 1: Domestic labor mobility costs with standard errors: 10 sectors Lao PDR Indonesia Vietnam Philippines Agriculture,

More information

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Economics 8413 International Trade James R. Markusen August 2004 Phone: 492-0748 Office: 216 Office hours: Monday, Wednesday, 1:30-3:00 e-mail: james.markusen@colorado.edu

More information

2 EU exports to Indonesia Malaysia and Thailand across

2 EU exports to Indonesia Malaysia and Thailand across 1 EU exports to Indonesia Malaysia and In 2017, the EU exported goods to Indonesia Malaysia and worth EUR 39.5 billion. This is equivalent to 2.1 per cent of total EU exports of goods to non-eu countries.

More information

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N November Vertical FDI Revisited. Henrik Braconier * Pehr-Johan Norback **

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N November Vertical FDI Revisited. Henrik Braconier * Pehr-Johan Norback ** CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N. 167 November 2002 Vertical FDI Revisited Henrik Braconier * Pehr-Johan Norback ** Dieter Urban *** * National Institute of Economic Research,

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT WITH SOUTH KOREA

IMPLICATIONS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT WITH SOUTH KOREA JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 27 Volume 33, Number 1, June 2008 IMPLICATIONS OF U.S. FREE TRADE AGREEMENT WITH SOUTH KOREA RENAN ZHUANG AND WON W. KOO * North Dakota State University This paper examines

More information

Trade Patterns in the SADC Region: Key Issues for the FTA

Trade Patterns in the SADC Region: Key Issues for the FTA Trade patterns in the SADC region key issues for the FTA Development Policy Research Unit University of Cape Town Trade Patterns in the SADC Region: Key Issues for the FTA DPRU Policy Brief No. 00/P9 March

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

AFTA as Real Free trade Area

AFTA as Real Free trade Area 1 Executive Summary AFTA as Real Free trade Area Submitted to Department of Business Economics Ministry of Commerce By Kwanjai Sothitorn Nualnoi Pongsa Arunsmith Mallikamas Treerat Pornchaiwiseskul January

More information

EU exports to Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand

EU exports to Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand EU exports to Indonesia, Malaysia and Note prepared for the Malaysian Palm Oil Council May 2018 EU exports of goods to Indonesia, Malaysia and amounted to EUR 39.5 billion in 2017 and supported at least

More information

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each) Question 1. (25 points) Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, 2009 Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each) a) What are the main differences between

More information

Working Paper no. 8/2001. Multinational Companies, Technology Spillovers and Plant Survival: Evidence for Irish Manufacturing. Holger Görg Eric Strobl

Working Paper no. 8/2001. Multinational Companies, Technology Spillovers and Plant Survival: Evidence for Irish Manufacturing. Holger Görg Eric Strobl Grupo de Economía Europea European Economy Group Working Paper no. 8/2001 Multinational Companies, Technology Spillovers and Plant Survival: Evidence for Irish Manufacturing Holger Görg Eric Strobl The

More information

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival WWW.DAGLIANO.UNIMI.IT CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N. 350 April 2013 Export Growth and Firm Survival Julian Emami Namini* Giovanni Facchini** Ricardo A. López*** * Erasmus

More information

Recent trade liberalization efforts, including the North American Free Trade Agreement

Recent trade liberalization efforts, including the North American Free Trade Agreement Industries important in nonmetro areas, such as agriculture, food processing, and tobacco products, have benefited from increasingly open markets and increased exports. However, the textile and apparel

More information

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS microreport# 117 SEPTEMBER 2008 This publication was produced for review by the United States Agency for International Development. It

More information

Macroeconomic Determinants of Tariff Policy in Pakistan

Macroeconomic Determinants of Tariff Policy in Pakistan Macroeconomic Determinants of Tariff Policy in Pakistan Dr. Mohammed Nishat Professor and Chairman, Department of Finance and Economics Institute of Business Administration-IBA University Road, Karachi

More information

Outward foreign direct investment from New-Wave Emerging Countries: A shift of newly emerging multinational companies

Outward foreign direct investment from New-Wave Emerging Countries: A shift of newly emerging multinational companies EACES Conference, Regensburg, 8-10 September, 2016 OEETurin panel New challenges in large emerging economies Outward foreign direct investment from New-Wave Emerging Countries: A shift of newly emerging

More information

Book Review. Foreign Direct Investment and the Regional Economy

Book Review. Foreign Direct Investment and the Regional Economy Book Review Foreign Direct Investment and the Regional Economy edited by Jonathan Jones and Colin Wren Ashgate Publishing Co., Burlington, USA, 2006 pp. 260 reviewed by Prodromos Prodromidis * The book

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

WHO BEARS THE BURDEN OF U.S. NONTARIFF MEASURES?

WHO BEARS THE BURDEN OF U.S. NONTARIFF MEASURES? WHO BEARS THE BURDEN OF U.S. NONTARIFF MEASURES? DON P. CLARK and DONALD BRUCE* This article provides evidence on the incidence of U.S. nontariff measures (NTMs) by investigating the relationship between

More information

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade Econ 340 Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade News: Jan 15-21 US and China prepare for trade disputes -- WSJ: 1/17 Canvas "A record Chinese annual trade surplus with the U.S., announced

More information

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana Journal of Economics and Political Economy www.kspjournals.org Volume 3 June 2016 Issue 2 International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana By Isaac DADSON aa & Ryuta RAY KATO ab Abstract. This paper

More information

THE IMPACT OF RISING TRADE ON WAGE INEQUALITY: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ON U.S.-CHINA TRADE FROM

THE IMPACT OF RISING TRADE ON WAGE INEQUALITY: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ON U.S.-CHINA TRADE FROM Clemson University TigerPrints All Theses Theses 5-2013 THE IMPACT OF RISING TRADE ON WAGE INEQUALITY: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ON U.S.-CHINA TRADE FROM 2000-2010 Jie Chen Clemson University, jchen8@clemson.edu

More information

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO BOULDER, COLORADO. Course Outline and Reading List

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO BOULDER, COLORADO. Course Outline and Reading List UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO BOULDER, COLORADO Economics 6413 International Trade James R. Markusen Phone: 492-0748 Office: 216 Office Hours: Tuesday, Thursday 9:30-11:30 August 28, 2000 Course Outline and Reading

More information

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

The Political Economy of Trade Policy The Political Economy of Trade Policy 1) Survey of early literature The Political Economy of Trade Policy Rodrik, D. (1995). Political Economy of Trade Policy, in Grossman, G. and K. Rogoff (eds.), Handbook

More information

Discussion of "Worker s Remittances and the Equilibrium RER: Theory and Evidence" by Barajas, Chami, Hakura and Montiel

Discussion of Worker s Remittances and the Equilibrium RER: Theory and Evidence by Barajas, Chami, Hakura and Montiel Discussion of "Worker s Remittances and the Equilibrium RER: Theory and Evidence" by Barajas, Chami, Hakura and Montiel Andrei Zlate Federal Reserve Board Atlanta Fed Research Conference on Remittances

More information

Two-dimensional Fragmentation in East Asia: Conceptual Framework and Empirics =

Two-dimensional Fragmentation in East Asia: Conceptual Framework and Empirics = Two-dimensional Fragmentation in East Asia: Conceptual Framework and Empirics = Fukunari Kimura and Mitsuyo Ando Faculty of Economics, Keio University Tokyo, Japan (fkimura@econ.keio.ac.jp; m-ando@mbj.nifty.com)

More information

The single European Market, the European Monetary Union and United States and Japanese FDI flows to the EU

The single European Market, the European Monetary Union and United States and Japanese FDI flows to the EU The single European Market, the European Monetary Union and United States and Japanese FDI flows to the EU Irini Smaragdi, Constantinos Katrakilidis and Nikos C. Varsakelis 1 * Key words: foreign direct

More information

The inflow of foreign direct investment to China: the impact of country-specific factors

The inflow of foreign direct investment to China: the impact of country-specific factors Journal of Business Research 56 (2003) 829 833 The inflow of foreign direct investment to China: the impact of country-specific factors Yigang Pan* York University, Toronto, Ontario, Canada The University

More information

Domestic Repercussions of Different Types of FDI: Firm-level Evidence for Taiwanese Manufacturing. by Wan-Hsin Liu and Peter Nunnenkamp

Domestic Repercussions of Different Types of FDI: Firm-level Evidence for Taiwanese Manufacturing. by Wan-Hsin Liu and Peter Nunnenkamp Domestic Repercussions of Different Types of FDI: Firm-level Evidence for Taiwanese Manufacturing by Wan-Hsin Liu and Peter Nunnenkamp No. 1546 Sept. 2009 Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Düsternbrooker

More information

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians I. Introduction Current projections, as indicated by the 2000 Census, suggest that racial and ethnic minorities will outnumber non-hispanic

More information

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL:

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Import Competition and Response Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor Volume

More information

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014 ASIA-PACIFIC RESEARCH AND TRAINING NETWORK ON TRADE ARTNeT CONFERENCE ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity 22-23 rd September

More information

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing Workers Remittances and International Risk-Sharing Metodij Hadzi-Vaskov March 6, 2007 Abstract One of the most important potential benefits from the process of international financial integration is the

More information

A Panel Data Analysis of FDI, Trade Openness, and Liberalization on Economic Growth of the ASEAN-5

A Panel Data Analysis of FDI, Trade Openness, and Liberalization on Economic Growth of the ASEAN-5 The Empirical Economics Letters, 6(1): (January 2007) ISSN 1681 8997 A Panel Data Analysis of FDI, Trade Openness, and Liberalization on Economic Growth of the ASEAN-5 Ramesh Mohan Department of Economics,

More information

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE A Report from the Office of the University Economist July 2009 Dennis Hoffman, Ph.D. Professor of Economics, University Economist, and Director, L.

More information

The Demand for Protectionism: Democracy, Import Elasticity, and Trade Barriers. Timothy M. Peterson University of South Carolina.

The Demand for Protectionism: Democracy, Import Elasticity, and Trade Barriers. Timothy M. Peterson University of South Carolina. The Demand for Protectionism: Democracy, Import Elasticity, and Trade Barriers Timothy M. Peterson University of South Carolina and Cameron G. Thies University of Iowa Verso running head: The Demand for

More information

Volume Author/Editor: Robert C. Feenstra, editor. Volume URL:

Volume Author/Editor: Robert C. Feenstra, editor. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Effects of U.S. Trade Protection and Promotion Policies Volume Author/Editor: Robert

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LOBBYING COMPETITION OVER TRADE POLICY. Kishore Gawande Pravin Krishna Marcelo Olarreaga

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LOBBYING COMPETITION OVER TRADE POLICY. Kishore Gawande Pravin Krishna Marcelo Olarreaga NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LOBBYING COMPETITION OVER TRADE POLICY Kishore Gawande Pravin Krishna Marcelo Olarreaga Working Paper 11371 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11371 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France No. 57 February 218 The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France Clément Malgouyres External Trade and Structural Policies Research Division This Rue

More information

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages by Tuvana Pastine Bilkent University Economics Department 06533 Ankara, Turkey and Ivan Pastine Bilkent University Economics Department 06533 Ankara, Turkey

More information

Volume Title: Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis. Volume URL:

Volume Title: Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis Volume Author/Editor: Robert E. Baldwin, ed. Volume

More information

Which firms benefit more from the own-firm and spillover effects of inward foreign direct investment?

Which firms benefit more from the own-firm and spillover effects of inward foreign direct investment? Which firms benefit more from the own-firm and spillover effects of inward foreign direct investment? First draft, please do not quote Priit Vahter University of Tartu 1 Abstract An interesting issue in

More information

THE AEC PROGRESS, CHALLENGES AND PROSPECTS

THE AEC PROGRESS, CHALLENGES AND PROSPECTS THE AEC PROGRESS, CHALLENGES AND PROSPECTS Siow Yue CHIA Singapore Institute of International Affairs Conference on Future of World Trading System: Asian Perspective ADBI-WTO, Geneva 11-12 March 2013 Drivers

More information

AID FOR TRADE: CASE STORY

AID FOR TRADE: CASE STORY AID FOR TRADE: CASE STORY THE INTERNATIONAL TRADE CENTRE Gender sensitisation of trade policy in India 1 AID FOR TRADE CASE STORY: ITC CASE STORY ON GENDER DIMENSION OF AID FOR TRADE GENDER SENSITISATION

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

CRS-2 Production Sharing and U.S.-Mexico Trade When a good is manufactured by firms in more than one country, it is known as production sharing, an ar

CRS-2 Production Sharing and U.S.-Mexico Trade When a good is manufactured by firms in more than one country, it is known as production sharing, an ar CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web 98-66 E January 27, 1998 Maquiladoras and NAFTA: The Economics of U.S.-Mexico Production Sharing and Trade J. F. Hornbeck Specialist in International

More information

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H. The China Syndrome Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson AER, 2013 presented by Federico Curci April 9, 2014 Autor, Dorn,

More information

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients) Section 2 Impact of trade on income inequality As described above, it has been theoretically and empirically proved that the progress of globalization as represented by trade brings benefits in the form

More information

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View 1. Approximately how much of the world's output does the United States produce? A. 4 percent. B. 20 percent. C. 30 percent. D. 1.5 percent. The United States

More information

A Model of Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment à la John Dunning. Josef C. Brada Arizona State University. Zdenek Drabek World Trade Organization

A Model of Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment à la John Dunning. Josef C. Brada Arizona State University. Zdenek Drabek World Trade Organization A Model of Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment à la John Dunning Josef C. Brada Arizona State University Zdenek Drabek World Trade Organization Jose A. Mendez Arizona State University M. Fabricio

More information

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014 Online Appendix Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality Mauricio Larrain Columbia University October 2014 A.1 Additional summary statistics Tables 1 and 2 in the main text report summary statistics

More information

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018 Study Importance of the German Economy for Europe A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018 www.vbw-bayern.de vbw Study February 2018 Preface A strong German economy creates added

More information

Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent FTA Bills

Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent FTA Bills KIEP Working Paper 08-08 Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent FTA Bills Hyejoon Im and Hankyoung Sung KIEP Working Paper 08-08 Empirical Analyses of U.S. Congressional Voting on Recent

More information

Analysis of Gender Profile in Export Oriented Industries in India. Bansari Nag

Analysis of Gender Profile in Export Oriented Industries in India. Bansari Nag Analysis of Gender Profile in Export Oriented Industries in India Bansari Nag Introduction The links between gender, trade and development are increasingly being recognised. Women all over the world are

More information

SINO-ASEAN ECONOMIC INTEGRATION AND ITS IMPACT ON INTRA-ASEAN TRADE

SINO-ASEAN ECONOMIC INTEGRATION AND ITS IMPACT ON INTRA-ASEAN TRADE SINO-ASEAN ECONOMIC INTEGRATION AND ITS IMPACT ON INTRA-ASEAN TRADE Sarah Y. TONG & LIM Tin Seng EAI Working Paper No. 144 ISSN 219-1318 ISBN 978-981-8-2359-7 All rights reserved Date of Publication: 8

More information

THE RECENT TREND OF ROMANIA S INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN GOODS

THE RECENT TREND OF ROMANIA S INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN GOODS THE RECENT TREND OF ROMANIA S INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN GOODS Andrei Cristian Balasan * Abstract: The article analyses the recent developments regarding the Romania trade in goods. We highlight how Romania

More information

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach European Journal of Sustainable Development (2014), 3, 3, 149-158 ISSN: 2239-5938 Doi: 10.14207/ejsd.2014.v3n3p149 The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach Marku Megi 1 ABSTRACT Foreign

More information

Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries

Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries Nina PAVCNIK Trade liberalization seems to have increased growth and income in developing countries over the past thirty years, through lower

More information

The poor performance of the rural economy in the

The poor performance of the rural economy in the Robert M. Gibbs and G. Andrew Bernat, Jr. Rural Industry Clusters Raise Local Earnings Industry clusters have become a popular strategy for rural economic development, yet their benefits to the local areas

More information

Globalisation of Markets

Globalisation of Markets Globalisation of Markets Definition of globalisation (1) The geographic dispersion of industrial and service activities, for example research and development, sourcing of inputs, production and distribution,

More information

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances Applied Economics Letters, 2008, 15, 181 185 Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances J. Ulyses Balderas and Hiranya K. Nath* Department of Economics and International

More information

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization... 1 5.1 THEORY OF INVESTMENT... 4 5.2 AN OPEN ECONOMY: IMPORT-EXPORT-LED GROWTH MODEL... 6 5.3 FOREIGN

More information

Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers Vol. 32. No. 1, Summer 2011

Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers Vol. 32. No. 1, Summer 2011 Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers Vol. 32. No. 1, Summer 2011 The Rise of Indian multinationals: Perspective of Indian Outward Foreign Direct Investment, edited by Karl P. Sauvant and Jaya Prakash

More information

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS The Issues wage inequality between skilled and unskilled labor the effects of

More information

on Interstate 19 in Southern Arizona

on Interstate 19 in Southern Arizona The Border Patrol Checkpoint on Interstate 19 in Southern Arizona A Case Study of Impacts on Residential Real Estate Prices JUDITH GANS Udall Center for Studies in Public Policy The University of Arizona

More information

IMPACT OF WTO TRADE FACILITATION AGREEMENT ON TARIFF REVENUES AND BORDER FEE PROCEEDS

IMPACT OF WTO TRADE FACILITATION AGREEMENT ON TARIFF REVENUES AND BORDER FEE PROCEEDS IMPACT OF WTO TRADE FACILITATION AGREEMENT ON TARIFF REVENUES AND BORDER FEE PROCEEDS March 2017 This paper has been prepared for review by the U.S. Agency for International Development under Dexis Consulting

More information

US Exports and Employment. Robert C. Feenstra University of California, Davis and NBER

US Exports and Employment. Robert C. Feenstra University of California, Davis and NBER US Exports and Employment Robert C. Feenstra University of California, Davis and NBER National Press Club, Washington, D.C., October 4, 2018 Global Decline in Manufacturing Employment in manufacturing

More information

Working Papers in Economics

Working Papers in Economics University of Innsbruck Working Papers in Economics Foreign Direct Investment and European Integration in the 90 s Peter Egger and Michael Pfaffermayr 2002/2 Institute of Economic Theory, Economic Policy

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, 1870 1970 IDS WORKING PAPER 73 Edward Anderson SUMMARY This paper studies the impact of globalisation on wage inequality in eight now-developed countries during the

More information

Trade liberalization in South Africa has been a characteristic of trade policy

Trade liberalization in South Africa has been a characteristic of trade policy SOUTH AFRICA S TARIFF LIBERALISATION POLICY: AN APPRAISAL OF DEVELOPMENTS DURING THE 1990S L. Rangasamy * Head: International Economics Research Unit SARB C. Harmse * Professor of Economics, Investment

More information

Foreign Lobbies and US Trade Policy

Foreign Lobbies and US Trade Policy Foreign Lobbies and US Trade Policy Kishore Gawande University of New Mexico Pravin Krishna Brown University Michael Robbins Brown University Abstract In popular discussion much has been made recently

More information

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices Kim S. So, Peter F. Orazem, and Daniel M. Otto a May 1998 American Agricultural Economics Association

More information