PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE"

Transcription

1 This article was downloaded by: [University of Konstanz] On: 6 May 2009 Access details: Access Details: [subscription number ] Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: Registered office: Mortimer House, Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK West European Politics Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: Strategic Voting under Proportional Representation: Threshold Insurance in German Elections Susumu Shikano; Michael Herrmann; Paul W. Thurner Online Publication Date: 01 May 2009 To cite this Article Shikano, Susumu, Herrmann, Michael and Thurner, Paul W.(2009)'Strategic Voting under Proportional Representation: Threshold Insurance in German Elections',West European Politics,32:3, To link to this Article: DOI: / URL: PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: This article may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

2 West European Politics, Vol. 32, No. 3, , May 2009 Strategic Voting under Proportional Representation: Threshold Insurance in German Elections SUSUMU SHIKANO, MICHAEL HERRMANN and PAUL W. THURNER Does proportional representation imply incentives for strategic voting? This article investigates whether adherents of the major German parties voted against their preference in order to increase the chance of a majority coalition between their favourite party and the preelectorally declared junior coalition partner. Focusing exclusively on the PR vote, the authors test whether strategic voting is guided by expectations with regard to the coalition formation stage. To that end they use a two-step estimation procedure to simultaneously predict (in-)complete party preferences and sincere and strategic voting in a random utility framework. Their results show that voters preferences, rather than mapping directly into party choice, are affected by their expectations on small parties re-entry chances. Voting under proportional representation (PR) is often viewed as genuinely sincere, that is, voters are assumed to simply vote for whichever party or candidate they most prefer. While scholars of voting behaviour have repeatedly focused on the possibility of insincere or so-called strategic voting in majority systems, such behaviour has largely been dismissed in the context of PR systems. Strategic voting theory posits that voters cast their vote in order to maximise their influence on government formation. In contrast to sincere voting, this may or may not involve voting for the most preferred alternative, depending on the electoral situation faced by the individual voter. Given the situation of simple plurality elections, for example, a voter who expects her preferred candidate to come in third place might decide to cast a strategic vote for the relatively more preferred among the candidates or parties in order to avoid the victory of a worse alternative (Fisher 2004). Similar incentives for strategic voting have been shown to exist under various other election schemes, such as approval voting Correspondence Address: Susumu.Shikano@uni-konstanz.de; miherrma@rumms.uni-mannheim.de; paul.thurner@gsi.uni-muenchen.de ISSN Print/ Online ª 2009 Taylor & Francis DOI: /

3 Strategic Voting in German Elections 635 (Hoffman 1982), multimember elections (Cox 1984), or runoff elections (Niou 2001). Only recently, however, scholars have begun to recognise the possibility of incentives for strategic voting in PR systems (van Holsteyn and Irwin 2003; Blais et al. 2006; Bargsted and Kedar 2009; Meffert and Gschwend 2008). Assessing these incentives is of great importance as PR is one of the most commonly applied election systems worldwide. If voters change their PR vote according to their perception of the likely outcome of the election, then polls, campaigns and coalition announcements may have profound influences on voters short-term behaviour. In this article we add to the recent literature on strategic voting under PR by presenting evidence for sophisticated vote switching. We analyse the 1994 German federal election because of the existence of a unique data set for testing our hypotheses. Specifically, we show that supporters of major parties often opted for their preferred party s designated junior coalition partner to increase the chance of a majority coalition led by their preferred party. The next section gives an idea about the meaning of strategic voting under PR in general as well as in the German context more specifically. We will highlight some of the difficulties in empirically detecting a strategic PR vote. In section two, we propose a modelling approach to infer strategic PR voting from survey data. In section three, we apply the model to data from the 1994 German federal election. Results are given in section four. We conclude with a discussion of the virtues of our approach. Conceptualising Strategic PR Voting Voting can be considered as a choice from a discrete set of parties or candidates. Strategic voting as opposed to sincere voting arises when the optimal choice does not correspond to the first-ranked party of a complete preference ordering: Sincere voting requires each voter to vote according to its preferences in any pairwise comparison of alternatives. An actor casts a sophisticated vote when it votes against its preferences in a pairwise comparison (Morrow 1994: 134, see also Ordeshook 1986: 258 ff.). Strategic voters seek to maximise their expected utility from the outcome of the election. Strategy implies that, in addition to their preferences, individual voters form expectations or probability beliefs about the likely outcome of the election and includes these in their decisions (see Cox 1984: 726). Strategic voting is therefore the result of the total calculus of voting given preferences and beliefs on the probabilities of the relevant states of a specific electoral situation (see McKelvey and Ordeshook 1972; Black 1978; Cain 1978; Cox 1997; Fey 1997). Accordingly, the party that yields the highest expected utility is chosen and this may not always be the party that is most preferred in terms of preferences where expectations are not taken into account. In simple plurality elections, voter expectations are driven by the question of candidates (non-)viability in winning the election because plurality rule

4 636 S. Shikano et al. renders all votes for hopeless candidates essentially wasted. By contrast, in the context of PR elections, voter expectations and strategic voting do not rest so much on the conversion of votes into seats than on the anticipation of post-election coalition building. Coalition governments usually are the norm in systems employing proportional seat allocation rules. While in some elections and countries it is hard to tell, beforehand, which coalitions are likely to form, most of the time it is nevertheless clear that certain constellations emerge as more likely than others prior to election day. Now, if voters perceive certain coalitions as more likely to form than others then this might create an incentive to vote for a party, other than the most preferred one. There is an emerging literature emphasising the possibility for strategic voting under PR (see Van Holsteyn and Irwin 2003; Blais et al. 2006, Bargsted and Kedar 2009; Bowler et al. 2008; Duch 2008; Marsh 2008; Meffert and Gschwend 2008). Bargsted and Kedar (2009), for example, suggest that centre-right voters expecting a centre-left coalition government choose to defect from their preferred centre-right party and instead vote for the most rightist of parties in the prospective coalition in an attempt to balance out the government. 1 They find evidence for this type of coalition balancing with respect to the three major parties in the 2006 Israeli Knesset election. Blais et al. (2006) in their analysis of the 2003 Knesset election found that almost 10 per cent of voters defected from their first preference due to coalition considerations. Coalition preferences turned out to be a strong predictor of vote choice, even controlling for other factors such as party evaluation or ideology. Van Holsteyn and Irwin (2003) examine coalition expectations in the 2002 Dutch parliamentary election. They demonstrate that even in systems with very many parties and various options for coalition building, voters still hold fairly clear expectations about which coalitions are likely to form. They also show that, given different hypothetical coalition scenarios, some voters alter their vote to endorse parties that are more likely to participate in the preferred coalition government. Taken together, these studies suggest the possibility that voters might cast their PR vote for a party other than their most preferred one. In the next section we shall address the idea of a strategic PR vote in the context of German Bundestag elections. Our focus will be on a particular form of voting, namely on the deviation from a first party preference in order to increase the probability that a voter s most preferred party actually is part of the government. Strategic PR Voting in German Elections The German electoral system is commonly designated as a mixed electoral system (Massicotte and Blais 1999; Shugart and Wattenberg 2001). It combines PR with plurality rule in single-member districts, giving two votes to each voter: the first vote (Erststimme) is cast for a constituency candidate,

5 Strategic Voting in German Elections 637 the second vote (Zweitstimme) for a list of party representatives from a given state. PR votes, aggregated at the national level, determine the total number of seats to which a party is entitled. The district vote has only very little impact on the allocation of party seats, as district winners do not receive extra seats but fill the seats allocated to their party according to the PR vote. 2 Like many other PR systems, Germany employs a threshold of representation that bars parties obtaining less than 5 per cent of second votes nationwide from entering into parliament. 3 It is common for German parties to declare informal pre-electoral coalitions (Golder 2005), whereby usually the smaller parliamentary parties Free Democratic Party (FDP) and Greens commit themselves in advance to one of the larger parties, i.e. FDP to Christian Democratic Union (CDU) and the Greens to Social Democratic Party of Germany (SPD). Thus voters know beforehand which coalitions are likely to form (provided those coalitions are majority coalitions). The tendency of small parties to form pre-electoral coalitions with either one of the large parties creates an incentive for supporters of CDU and SPD to defect from their first preference, if they are unsure whether their party s coalition partner will overcome the 5 per cent threshold. If its coalition partner fails to enter parliament while the other party s coalition partner succeeds, the opposing coalition would assume government. If neither of the two small parties enters parliament, both large parties would most likely form a grand coalition. Thus, by casting a vote for a small party, supporters of major parties employ a coalition insurance strategy (see Pappi and Thurner 2002; Gschwend 2007), i.e. they insure against a 5 per cent loss of the coalition lead by their most preferred party. We are not the first to mention the possibility of a strategic PR vote in the German elections. In fact, the idea is widely known among scholars and observers of German electoral politics and has also been invoked in prior work on voter behaviour in Germany (e.g. Roberts 1988; Schoen 1999; Thurner and Pappi 1999, Blais et al. 2001; Gschwend 2007). Only a few studies have thus far attempted to provide evidence for this kind of behaviour. Most notably, Pappi and Thurner (2002) found that coalition preferences induce certain types of split-ticket voting. Gschwend (2007) extends these findings, demonstrating for the first time that voter expectations regarding small-party entry into parliament have a significant impact on voters propensity to split their vote. Departing from these studies we intend to infer strategic PR voting without reference to split-ticket voting. For identifying a strategic PR vote, previous studies chose to rely on the event of a split vote between a major and a minor party, i.e. voters who cast their district vote for a candidate of a larger party, say CDU, and the PR vote for its smaller coalition partner, say FDP, were assumed to be strategically motivated. More precisely, the voters were assumed to cast their district vote for their sincere first preference and the PR vote strategically for their preferred party s junior coalition partner. This, however, is not the only conclusion one could draw: the same pattern

6 638 S. Shikano et al. of ticket splitting could also result from strategic voting on the district level, i.e. by supporters of the candidates of small parties who intend to avoid wasting their district vote. The latter kind of strategic voting can be found among significant parts of German voters (Herrmann and Pappi 2008). Accordingly, the district vote for a large party might well be strategic and the PR vote for a small party sincere. Thus we cannot decide, prima facie, which kind of strategic voting is being observed in a split ticket. This is in line with Cox s (1997: 82) argument that casting a list vote for the FDP and a candidate vote for, say, the Christian Democratic Union (CDU) is not unambiguous evidence of ordinary strategic voting, however. It may be that the voter truly prefers the CDU, casts a sincere vote for the CDU candidate, but casts her list vote strategically for the FDP, because the FDP is both in alliance with the CDU and in danger of falling below the 5% national threshold (in which case the FDP would get no seats and the CDU might not be able to form a government)... So how is one to tell whether some component of the discrepancy between the FDP s candidate and list votes is due to ordinary strategic voting, intended to avoid wasting the constituency vote? The ambiguity inherent in measures of split voting and described by Cox makes previous results somewhat less convincing. Ticket splitting is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for the identification of a strategic PR vote. In order to overcome these problems, we propose a solution that statistically infers cardinal utility from voters stated preference orderings and their determinants. This inferred cardinal utility enables us to account for the moderating impact of strategy-relevant expectations at the same time taking account of the inherent uncertainty of utility. Modelling Strategic Voting under PR: A New Approach In the following, we shall focus exclusively on the PR vote thus avoiding the pitfalls of split-vote measures. Given the conventional definition of a strategic vote as a decision deviating from first preference, a straightforward way to investigate strategic voting is to model the actual vote decision by reference to the voters preference orderings of alternatives. We thus propose a two-step estimation framework in which voter preference formation is modelled together with the subsequent vote decision. In this set-up the vote choice is explained on the basis of a multiplicative expected utility model in which party utility is endogenously derived from sincere preference orders. Observed (in-)complete preference orders and the stated choice are assumed to be the outcome of a single underlying utility function where expectations on coalition formation are the relevant motives of the deviation from first preference. Figure 1 depicts the two-step estimation process.

7 Strategic Voting in German Elections 639 FIGURE 1 A TWO-STAGE ANALYSIS OF STRATEGIC AND SINCERE VOTING In the first step, party utility is modelled as a function of voters retrospective evaluation of government activity and their issue-based prospective evaluation of party positions. Applying the so-called rank ordered logit model, we estimate voter utility for each party on the basis of the observed party rankings. In a second step those estimates are used in combination with variables on voters expectations in order to model their actual voting decision which comes closest to usually employed expected utility framework. The estimation of voter utility from other explanatory variables allows us to construct a cardinal measure for voter utility that can be combined with measures of voter expectations to account for the potential moderating impact of expectations on the final voting decision. Thus, our framework is fully consistent with the concept of expected utility, which posits a multiplicative relationship between party preference and voter beliefs. Furthermore we are able to simultaneously explain sincere and strategic voting within one and the same model. The innovative part of our two-step framework consists in using for the first time rank ordered logit (ROL) analysis for modelling strategic voting. Whereas ROL analysis, in essence, results from a straightforward expansion of the multinomial logit model for multiple responses (rankings), ROL has almost never been applied in electoral research. 4 Since it is central to our theoretical argument and the following empirical analysis, we give a short introduction. More detailed presentations can be found in Chapman and Staelin (1982), Allison and Christakis (1994), or Skrondal and Rabe- Hesketh (2003). The Statistical Model Multinomial logit and conditional logit are now accepted tools for the modelling of voters confronted with multiple choices, e.g. the choice of a party from a given set of parties (see Thurner 2000). Rank ordered logit, on

8 640 S. Shikano et al. the other hand, can be used to model voters (in-)complete rankings of all parties in a given choice set. This is accomplished by treating the assignment of each rank as a choice process itself, thus decomposing rank orderings into sequences of choices, where at each stage the alternative with the highest utility is picked from the choice set and ranked according to some ordinal numbering scheme. Consider the following random utility model: U ij ¼ V ij þ e ij with V ij ¼ x ij b þ z i g j ð1þ where U ij is the utility of party j to voter i, which is decomposed into a deterministic component V ij and a stochastic error term e ij. The deterministic component V ij is modelled as a function of characteristics of party j relative to voter i, x ij, with corresponding parameter vector b, and characteristics of voter i, z i, with respective, alternative specific, parameter vector g j. Accordingly, b and g j can be interpreted as importance weights in voter i s utility function. Utility maximisation implies that i votes for the party j if it yields a higher utility than any other party k in his choice set S. Since utility is assumed to be subject to unobservable random error, we do not know which party actually yields the highest utility, so we can only make a probabilistic statement about whether i votes for party j, i.e. the probability that j yields the highest utility of all parties in the choice set S PrðjjSÞ ¼Pr½U j max k2s ðu k ÞŠ; 8k 6¼ j. For some specified error distribution, this probability can be expressed as a multinomial logit (see McFadden 1974; Ben-Akiva and Lerman 1985; Train 1986). Thus multinomial logit is an expression for the probability that party j is most preferred, i.e. that j yields the highest utility of all parties in S. In electoral research, voters stated party choice is usually taken as the observational equivalent to their first preference and modelled with multinomial logit. On the other hand, multinomial logit can also be used to model observed voter preferences. For instance, assume that voter i s choice set S consists of four parties S ¼ {a, b, c, d} and that her preferences are given by the relation c a b d. As a consequence, the probability of observing party c on first rank can be expressed by multinomial logit. To obtain probability statements for the remaining party ranking, simply note that the second most preferred party a yields the highest utility among the remaining parties (excluding c). Hence the probability of observing a on second rank can again be expressed with multinomial logit, this time, for the set of parties a, b and d. Likewise the probability of observing party b in third rank can be expressed with a multinomial logit model for a set of parties b and d. The probability of the entire preference ordering is given by the product of those multinomial logit probabilities: 5 Prðc a b dþ ¼ ev c P j2se V j e V a e P V b P j¼fa;b;dge V j j¼fb;dge V j ð2þ

9 Strategic Voting in German Elections 641 This model is also called exploded logit (Chapman and Staelin 1982), as the ranking of the four parties is exploded into a sequence of three separate logit models. There is also a behavioural interpretation of equation (2): assume rank orderings as being generated by a process in which a voter first chooses her most preferred party from all available parties. From the remaining parties she again chooses his most preferred one, and so on, until there is only one party left in the choice set. Thus, an observed preference ordering can be understood as being generated by a repeated selection process in which an individual sequentially picks the best alternative from an ever shrinking choice set. Likewise, the probability of any given rank ordering can be expressed as a product of multinomial logit probabilities. Let S denote voter i s choice set containing J parties j ¼ 1, 2,..., J, and let r ¼ 1, 2,..., R denote the preference ranks i assigns to the parties in S. Then, for any preference ordering O, the rank ordered logit model is given by: PrðO j SÞ ¼ YR 1 exp V jr ½Š P J l¼r exp V ð3þ j½lš r¼1 (Beggs et al. 1981; Chapman and Staelin 1982; Hausman and Ruud 1987; Allison and Christakis 1994; Skrondal and Rabe-Hesketh 2003, Train 2003). Mathematically, multinomial logit can be considered a special case of rank ordered logit: when only one alternative is ranked first and all other alternatives remain unranked (3) reduces to a multinomial logit model. 6 Estimation of the rank ordered logit model is carried out by maximum likelihood estimation. The likelihood function is obtained by taking the product of (3) over all observed preference orderings. Interpretation of results (i.e. logit coefficients, odds ratios, predicted probabilities) is identical to multinomial logit, with the exception that the outcome to be explained is not the probability of choosing party j, but the probability that party j is most preferred (or ranked first). 7 So far we have assumed that each voters preferences are complete and strictly transitive, i.e. that every party in S is assigned a unique rank. However, rank ordered logit analysis is not restricted to this type of preference ordering. Allison and Christakis (1994) discuss these issues in detail and propose some modifications of the model to incorporate ties in preference rankings as well as incomplete rankings. 8 Rank ordered logit and multinomial logit are not different behavioural models but are based on the same random utility framework. Both models aim at estimating an underlying utility function that accounts either for the voting decision or for voter preference. Thus, it is possible to use rank ordered logit in order to estimate a utility ^V ij of each party for individual voters that accounts for voters sincere party preferences, conditional on such variables as retrospective evaluation of government performance or party policy distances, and then reuse those estimates of cardinal utility for a subsequent multinomial logit analysis of strategic voting behaviour, by

10 642 S. Shikano et al. further conditioning on voters expectations about parties electoral success. This approach differs significantly from previous applications in which party preferences are treated as exogenous and are directly used as proxy for utility. Instead, the approach above allows us to incorporate other theoretically relevant variables, thus combining sincere and strategic voting in one empirical model of voter behaviour. In the following we will apply this framework to explain strategic list voting in German federal elections. Testing for Strategic PR Voting in the 1994 German Federal Election Hypotheses Strategic PR voting mainly implies that supporters of a major party cast their party list vote for the prospective junior coalition partner in order to help it overcome the 5 per cent threshold, a phenomenon that is also known as Leihstimme (lend vote) (Pappi and Thurner 2002). The 1994 Bundestag election provides an appropriate context to test for this kind of behaviour. In the previous period, the governing coalition was formed by the CDU and FDP. Both parties asserted beforehand their willingness to keep up with the coalition for another election period. An alternative pre-electoral coalition was declared by SPD and Greens, respectively. The former communist Party of Democratic Socialism (PDS), however, a party, which obtained about as many seats as the FDP or Greens, was excluded from pre-electoral coalition formation. One may argue that this is not applicable to East German voters since the PDS had supported the formation of a minority coalition of the SPD and Greens in an East German federal state (Saxony-Anhalt) a couple of months prior to the 1994 election. This is, however, the unique exception at that time and not comparable with the other federal states where the FDP and the Greens have been established coalition partners of the CDU and SPD, respectively. Hence, the PDS was not considered a real option for strategic voting by large party supporters seeking to ensure a majority coalition. Taking these arguments together, we expect the FDP and Greens to be more likely to attract strategic votes if voters are unsure about their entry into parliament. We do not expect this effect for the PDS, as it was not part of any pre-electoral coalition. Restated in terms of our two-stage modelling framework, we expect that, in the second stage, the (expected) utility of strategically voting for the FDP or Greens should be higher for voters who are not certain about the respective party s entry into parliament than for other voters. Data and Measurement Voter preference can be measured in various ways: For example, one could ask respondents directly about their most preferred party, their second most

11 Strategic Voting in German Elections 643 preferred party, etc. Such questions are rarely asked in election surveys. Essentially the same information is contained in reactions to party feeling thermometers. Therefore, researchers often construct party rankings from feeling thermometer scores or treat thermometer scores as cardinal measures of party/candidate utility. In general this approach is acceptable in the absence of other measures of voter preference. However, we will rely on a more thorough measurement of preferences asking survey participants for a pairwise comparison of all combinations of parties (see Pappi and Eckstein 1998). The main advantage of this approach, compared with thermometer-based measurements, is that it allows for intransitivity in voter preferences. 9 While transitive preferences are a necessary assumption underlying all strategic voting research, the extent to which this assumption actually holds remains an empirical question. In the usual feeling thermometer-based approach, transitivity of preferences is forced by the response format, which makes it impossible to discern transitive from intransitive preferences. To avoid artificial rankings by voters with intransitive preferences, we use paired comparison data which allow for identifying patterns of intransitivity or random response. Furthermore we expect paired comparisons to elicit sincere party preferences in a much more valid way than thermometer rankings. Research on strategic voting is essentially concerned with the deviation of the voting decision from party preference. Therefore it is crucial that preference measures are exogenous to the voting decision, i.e. that respondents who are unsure about their first preference do not anchor their response to their voting decision. Direct questions about party rankings, such as feeling thermometers, should bias responses more easily towards the voting intention and thus introduce a higher level of endogeneity than paired comparisons. 10 Accordingly, we will use survey data from the 1994 German federal election that contain paired comparisons of all combinations of following parties: 11 CDU (Christian Democrats), 12 SPD (Social Democrats), FDP (Liberals), the Greens and PDS (Socialists). The following question wording was used: In the following, I will provide you several times with the names of two parties and I would like to ask you to say which of the parties you prefer if you have to decide only between the two. CDU or SPD CDU or FDP... The Greens or PDS. Respondents either named the party they preferred or stated their indifference towards the two parties ( I can t decide ). Comparisons were sought for five parties; accordingly respondents stated their preference for 10 pairs of parties (5 6 4/2). Rank orderings were constructed for all respondents whose preference judgements were transitive and complete (cf. Pappi and Eckstein 1998). The percentage of those respondents was

12 644 S. Shikano et al. remarkably high in West Germany with 79.5 per cent and somewhat lower in East Germany with 72.1 per cent. From this group of respondents we had to further subtract those that did not provide information on their voting decision. 13 Also not considered in the analysis are respondents who are completely indifferent between all five parties, which leaves us with a final sample of 1013 West German and 234 East German respondents. Results To get an impression of the distribution of stated preferences and stated choices in the data consider Table 1 which gives relative frequencies of stated preferences and stated party choice for PR votes in the East and West German sample, respectively. As a reference, we also include vote shares for the district vote, although in this article we are mainly concerned with the PR vote. Actually, there is a clear regularity between preference and choice: parties shares of first preferences are, except for the PDS in East Germany, always between that of PR and district votes. The two large parties CDU and SPD receive more votes for their district candidates than would be expected from their share of first preferences. Conversely, small parties receive more PR votes than their shares of first preference indicate. Hence there are deviations of voters stated choices from their stated party preferences. Furthermore, we can observe differences between East and West German voters with respect to their preferences for CDU and PDS. Specifically in the East German sample, voters preferences for CDU and PDS show a bimodal pattern, with each party scoring high on first and last preference but much lower on intermediate preference ranks. In the West German sample preferences for CDU and PDS are distributed rather unimodally, with CDU being mostly in first rank and PDS predominantly in fifth. This suggests a stronger polarisation of the East German electorate with respect TABLE 1 FREQUENCIES OF STATED CHOICE AND STATED PREFERENCE (%) List Vote District Vote 1st 2nd Preference 3rd 4th 5th West (n ¼ 1013) CDU/CSU SPD FDP Greens PDS East (n ¼ 234) CDU SPD FDP Greens PDS

13 Strategic Voting in German Elections 645 to a left right ideological dimension, where the CDU takes a conservative right-most and the PDS a left-most position. The relationship between vote choice and party preference is further clarified by looking at their bivariate distribution, which is given in Table 2. The row marginals of the individual tables give the number of respondents who cast their list/district vote for their first, second, third, etc. preference, respectively. About per cent of all voters deviated from their first TABLE 2 JOINT DISTRIBUTION OF VOTE CHOICE AND PREFERENCE West Germany PR Vote 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total CDU/CSU SPD FDP Greens PDS Total Deviation from first preference: 17.6%. District Vote 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total CDU/CSU SPD FDP Greens PDS Total Deviation from first preference: 13.2%. East Germany PR Vote 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total CDU SPD FDP Greens PDS Total Deviation from first preference: 21.4%. District Vote 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total CDU SPD FDP Greens PDS Total Deviation from first preference: 12%.

14 646 S. Shikano et al. preference when they cast their vote, which suggests a substantial amount of strategic voting. Most of those who deviate from their first preference cast their vote for their second most preferred party or party district candidate. Therefore, we need to take at least voters second preference into consideration to model their vote choice. Interestingly, the PR vote shows a higher degree of deviation from the first preference than the district vote. 14 Thus, the district vote corresponds more closely to voters preferences over party lists than the PR vote. This finding should be counter-intuitive for those assuming that the PR vote more closely reflects voter preferences than the district vote. It is not so surprising, however, if one expects strategic voting on the PR ballot as well. If strategic voting occurs on both ballots, then there is nothing that would prevent defection rates from being higher on the PR vote than on the district vote. In particular, preferences could be distributed in favour of larger parties but some of the larger parties adherents could vote for small parties for strategic reasons. Thus, a substantive amount of small party voters, for example FDP voters, might actually prefer the larger potential coalition partner but cast a strategic vote to increase the chances for a particular coalition to form. To test for this kind of strategic voting, we model first voters stated preferences with rank ordered logit in order to obtain individual utility estimates ^V ij for each voter and each party (linear prediction: ^b 0 x). We assume that party preference formation is determined by retrospective as well as prospective considerations. Correspondingly, the independent variables used in the first step are respondents retrospective judgement of government work (1: satisfied; 0: not satisfied) and absolute policy distances between voters and parties on the following three issues: bugging operations, highway speed limit and job-creation programmes. For each issue respondents were asked for their individual positions as well as the position of all parties on a seven point scale. In the second step, PR vote was modelled with conditional logit on the basis of the estimated utility values and voters beliefs about the entry into parliament of the FDP and Greens. 15 For rank ordered logit estimation we used voter preferences with varying lengths. Results are given in the appendix. To account for possible voter heterogeneity, estimations were conducted separately for East and West German respondents. We ran several analyses on the basis of first preference only, first and second preference, first to third preference and for the full rank order of parties. Using first preference only reduces the analysis to a simple multinomial logit model. With the inclusion of later preference ranks the estimation equation is exploded to include those additional selection stages as well. One reason not to rely on voters full rank orderings is that the accuracy of their judgements may decrease with lower preference. For instance, a voter may be certain about her most preferred and second most preferred parties but hold only diffuse preferences among less preferred parties. In particular, a German voter usually casts two votes in an election which may

15 Strategic Voting in German Elections 647 promote the formation of a clear first and second preference, but not necessarily an elaboration of a definite preference ordering for all parties. The fact that, since 1957, federal governments in Germany have been twoparty coalitions may further contribute to this tendency. On the other hand, if strategic PR voting is to mean anything, then it would be at least voting for a second preference party in order to improve the outcome in terms of the coalition that will form. 16 Thus, while we cannot be certain that voters hold clear preferences beyond their stated first and second preference, a minimal requirement for strategic voting is that voters hold a clear preference between their top two choices. Their assignment of lower ranks may, however, involve more randomness which would cause coefficient estimates based on lower ranks to be closer to zero than those based on higher ranks (Chapman and Staelin 1982; Allison and Christakis 1994). An informal way to assess this kind of heteroscedasticity across preference rankings, suggested by Chapman and Staelin, is to plot values of model fit, such as McFadden s R 2, from the individual model estimations and look for sharp decreases between ranking stages. In Figure 2 we plot McFadden s pseudo R 2 for different depths of preference in order to know up to which rank we should take preference into consideration. As can be seen, pseudo R 2 declines constantly with longer preference rankings, which suggests that the assignment of later ranks is less well captured by our model than the assignment of earlier ranks. Furthermore, model estimations for the West German sample show a larger decline of pseudo R 2 between the second and third ranking stage. This suggests terminating the analysis of preference after second rank. Accordingly, in the first step, we rely only on ranks one to three, i.e. on the first two ranking stages. 17 In using estimation results from rank ordered logit in the second step, we have to note that the estimated utility should not be regarded as a point estimate but as an estimated distribution. Simply taking the estimated values as measures for voter utility in the second step would assume that we knew these values with certainty. This would be no problem if we were only interested in obtaining parameter estimates. Generally, such estimates would be unbiased, however their standard errors would be too small. Because there is estimation error and hence uncertainty in our estimates from the first step, we need to ensure that some of this uncertainty is carried over into the second step analysis to avoid artificially deflated standard errors. Therefore, we drew 1000 coefficient vectors from a normal distribution with mean vector ^b and variance covariance matrix equal to the variance covariance matrix of the estimated coefficients. For each set of coefficients (i.e. each coefficient vector) we computed predicted voter utilities for each party and used these values in order to model the vote choice with multinomial logit. Hence the vote choice estimation is repeated 1000 times, each time with different predicted values for party utility and each time yielding different coefficient values and associated standard errors. Results

16 648 S. Shikano et al. FIGURE 2 McFADDEN S PSEUDO R 2 FOR DIFFERENT DEPTH OF PREFERENCE from those 1000 estimations are then combined according to Rubin s rules to yield the quantities of interest, i.e. coefficients and their respective standard errors. According to Rubin (1987), the unbiased parameter estimate from a series of multiply imputed datasets is simply the mean of the individual parameter estimates. 18 The unbiased variance of the parameter estimate is the mean of the individual parameter variances within each dataset plus the variance of the parameter estimates between datasets, with an adjustment for the number of imputations, s 2 ¼ 1 X M k s2 k þ 1 þ 1 M 1 M 1 X ^b k k b 2 ð4þ (cf. Allison 2001; King et al. 2001), where M denotes the number of replications k, s the standard error of a given coefficient estimate ^b, and b the mean coefficient estimate across all M datasets. Table 3 summarises the estimation results for West German voters. Model 1 measures utility generically for every party assuming the impact

17 Strategic Voting in German Elections 649 TABLE 3 RESULTS FROM REPEATED a ESTIMATION OF MULTINOMIAL LOGIT DEPEN- DENT VARIABLE: VOTE INTENTION FOR PARTY LIST WEST GERMAN SAMPLE (N ¼ 1313) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Coef. SE Coef. SE Coef. SE Constant b SPD FDP Greens PDS Utility CDU SPD FDP Greens PDS Interaction with uncertainty FDP Greens PDS a Number of replications: b Reference category: CDU. (coefficient) of party utility on party choice to be constant across parties. The coefficient is significant (p 5.05), which suggests that our estimates of voters party preferences predict the vote intention well. Model 2 allows the effect of utility on party choice to vary across alternatives, by estimating separate alternative-specific coefficients of voter utility for each party. Comparing coefficients with each other, the value for the FDP stands out as relatively low. This suggests that the vote for the FDP is motivated less by sincere party preference than the vote for the other parties. In contrast, the vote for the Greens seems to be more strongly driven by sincere preferences. In order to test whether this lower coefficient for the FDP can be balanced off by accounting for strategic voting based on the expectation that the FDP enters parliament, we add interaction terms between utility and the entry expectation for the FDP as well as for the other two small parties, Greens and PDS. Respondents were asked: How likely do you assess the entry of FDP/Greens/PDS into the Bundestag to be?, with answers on a five point scale ranging from very unlikely to very likely. Answers falling in the middle category were taken as an indication of uncertainty. The expectation variable is thus coded 1 if respondents are uncertain about the entry of the respective party and 0 otherwise. In accordance with the Leihstimmen (lendvote) hypothesis we expect a positive coefficient for this interaction term for FDP and Greens, respectively (see section two above), while we do not expect a significant interaction for PDS as they were not part of any preelectoral coalition.

18 650 S. Shikano et al. The estimation result of Model 3 confirms our hypotheses with regard to the FDP and the PDS vote, but not with regardtothegreenvote.voterswhoare uncertain about the FDP s entry into parliament are more likely as compared with other voters to cast their PR vote for this party, as indicated by the significant (p ) interaction coefficient for the FDP. 19 The interaction coefficient for the PDS does not reach statistical significance, which is as expected, since the PDS was not part of a pre-electoral coalition and hence should not attract strategic PR votes. Our expectations are not confirmed, however, for the Green vote, as indicated by the insignificant interaction term. This might be due to the fact that in 1994, the Greens formed for the first time a pre-electoral coalition with the SPD at the federal level. So far, they had traditionally been in opposition to the established party system. Therefore, the Greens may not yet have been considered as a mature partner for SPD in a coalition government. Conversely, the FDP, at that time, had been in office with the CDU for three election periods, making it a credible option for strategic list voting. 20 Discussion This study aimed at providing evidence for strategic list voting in German Bundestag elections by applying an innovative modelling framework. Previous research often inferred the extent of strategic list voting from split-ticket voting, i.e. voting for a district candidate of a major party and for a small party list. Such reasoning, however, runs the risk of confounding strategic voting on the party list ballot with strategic voting on the district ballot two entirely different notions of strategic voting that are both present in mixed electoral systems. The framework presented in this paper departs from previous studies by considering the party PR vote alone. Furthermore, we allowed for the incorporation of (in-)complete preference orders and vote choice within the same discrete choice model. Our analysis shows that this approach works well in predicting strategic list voting in German federal elections. In particular, it can be shown that German voters adjust their voting behaviour with regard to the future governmental alternatives as presented to them by informal pre-electoral coalitions of CDU together with FDP. Uncertainty about the FDP s entry into parliament the junior partner of the CDU in a prospective coalition government made voters more likely to vote for the FDP than voters who were certain about the FDP s entry into parliament. Due to the peculiar data requirements of our theoretical argument, our analysis had to be restricted to one particular election. However, the mechanism of strategic list voting which we propose, should apply to most of the German Bundestag elections, before and after In the election of 1994 the Green party, for the first time, announced a pre-electoral commitment towards the SPD. Before, the only small party forming any pre-electoral coalition was the FDP. This might explain why we found evidence of strategic voting for the FDP but not for the Green party. We would expect, though, that strategic voting for the Green party has

19 Strategic Voting in German Elections 651 increased since that time. In particular, after the 1998 election, the Green party for the first time assumed government together with the SPD. We would conjecture that the success of this coalition increased the amount of strategic voting among supporters of the SPD who previously might have been doubtful about the feasibility of such an alliance. While the focus of our paper was on strategic PR voting the modelling approach we have taken is not restricted to that particular form of strategic voting. It might also inform research on other forms of sophisticated voting. To see how, note that studies of strategic voting often assume voter behaviour to be guided by some sort of expected utility model, yet they differ in the extent to which they actually apply this model to empirical data. 21 Some studies deviate from the expected utility model by treating party preferences and voter expectations as independent determinants of the voting decision (cf. Alvarez and Nagler 2000; Alvarez et al. 2006; Blais et al. 2005). Thus, voter expectations of party/candidate success are additively combined with determinants of party utility, such as class, age, parties policy stands, etc. While the use of appropriate statistical methods like (multinomial) logit allows for obtaining a cardinal measure of expected utility based on the ordinal measure of the determinants, it clearly deviates from the theoretical model which supposes the multiplicative interaction of utility and expectation. However, in order to multiply utility by expectation, one needs a cardinal measure of utility. Other approaches interpret party preference as measured by so-called feeling thermometer scores as a cardinal measure of utility (Cain 1978; Ordeshook and Zeng 1997), or construct it from proxy variables such as party identification (Gschwend 2007; Karp et al. 2002). In doing so, one imposes the strong assumption of cardinal utility measurement which requires that thermometer scores are comparable between individuals (such that, for example, a value of two means the same thing for every voter). In addition, measurement is also assumed to be free of error as party identification and feeling thermometers are treated as direct measures of utility. The framework we have presented does not suffer from these problems and most closely resembles the form of an expected utility model. We would, therefore, suggest it as a research design for studying strategic voting under other electoral rules as well, such as first-past-the-post as in Britain and Canada, or other mixed electoral rules as, for example, in New Zealand or Italy. Acknowledgements We thank Alexander Herzog and two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments. Notes 1. According to the authors the same logic holds, of course, for the case of moderate-left voters expecting a centre-right government.

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One Chapter 6 Online Appendix Potential shortcomings of SF-ratio analysis Using SF-ratios to understand strategic behavior is not without potential problems, but in general these issues do not cause significant

More information

Electoral Studies. Strategic coalition voting: Evidence from Austria. Michael F. Meffert a, *, Thomas Gschwend b,1. abstract

Electoral Studies. Strategic coalition voting: Evidence from Austria. Michael F. Meffert a, *, Thomas Gschwend b,1. abstract Electoral Studies 29 (2010) 339e349 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Electoral Studies journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Strategic coalition voting: Evidence from Austria Michael

More information

Ticket-splitting and strategic voting under mixed electoral rules: Evidence from Germany

Ticket-splitting and strategic voting under mixed electoral rules: Evidence from Germany European Journal of Political Research 46: 1 23, 2007 1 doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2006.00641.x Ticket-splitting and strategic voting under mixed electoral rules: Evidence from Germany THOMAS GSCHWEND Zentrum

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

Appendix for: The Electoral Implications. of Coalition Policy-Making

Appendix for: The Electoral Implications. of Coalition Policy-Making Appendix for: The Electoral Implications of Coalition Policy-Making David Fortunato Texas A&M University fortunato@tamu.edu 1 A1: Cabinets evaluated by respondents in sample surveys Table 1: Cabinets included

More information

Strategic Voting In British Elections

Strategic Voting In British Elections Strategic Voting In British Elections R. Michael Alvarez California Institute of Technology Frederick J. Boehmke University of Iowa Jonathan Nagler New York University June 4, 2004 We thank Geoff Evans,

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Moshe Bitan 1, Ya akov (Kobi) Gal 3 and Elad Dokow 4, and Sarit Kraus 1,2 1 Computer Science Department, Bar Ilan University, Israel 2 Institute for Advanced

More information

The California Primary and Redistricting

The California Primary and Redistricting The California Primary and Redistricting This study analyzes what is the important impact of changes in the primary voting rules after a Congressional and Legislative Redistricting. Under a citizen s committee,

More information

Online publication date: 21 July 2010 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Online publication date: 21 July 2010 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE This article was downloaded by: [University of Denver, Penrose Library] On: 12 January 2011 Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 790563955] Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in

More information

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design. Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design Forthcoming, Electoral Studies Web Supplement Jens Hainmueller Holger Lutz Kern September

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections Christopher N. Lawrence Department of Political Science Duke University April 3, 2006 Overview During the 1990s, minor-party

More information

Is there a relationship between election outcomes and perceptions of personal economic well-being? A test using post-election economic expectations

Is there a relationship between election outcomes and perceptions of personal economic well-being? A test using post-election economic expectations Is there a relationship between election outcomes and perceptions of personal economic well-being? A test using post-election economic expectations Garrett Glasgow University of California, Santa Barbara

More information

Electoral Studies. Voters and coalition governments. Sara B. Hobolt a, *, Jeffrey A. Karp b,1. abstract. Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Electoral Studies. Voters and coalition governments. Sara B. Hobolt a, *, Jeffrey A. Karp b,1. abstract. Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Electoral Studies 29 (2010) 299 307 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Electoral Studies journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Voters and coalition governments Sara B. Hobolt a, *,

More information

Weighting Parties and Coalitions: How Coalition Signals Influence Voting Behavior

Weighting Parties and Coalitions: How Coalition Signals Influence Voting Behavior Weighting Parties and Coalitions: How Coalition Signals Influence Voting Behavior Thomas Gschwend Lukas F Stoetzer University of Mannheim University of Mannheim gschwend@uni-mannheim.de lstoetze@mail.uni-mannheim.de

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Direction of trade and wage inequality This article was downloaded by: [California State University Fullerton], [Sherif Khalifa] On: 15 May 2014, At: 17:25 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number:

More information

Should I stay or should I go? An experimental study on voter responses to pre-electoral coalitions

Should I stay or should I go? An experimental study on voter responses to pre-electoral coalitions 556 European Journal of Political Research 47: 556 577, 2008 doi: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2008.00787.x Should I stay or should I go? An experimental study on voter responses to pre-electoral coalitions THOMAS

More information

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Chad Kendall Department of Economics University of British Columbia Marie Rekkas* Department of Economics Simon Fraser University mrekkas@sfu.ca 778-782-6793

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications January 30, 2004 Emerson M. S. Niou Department of Political Science Duke University niou@duke.edu 1. Introduction Ever since the establishment

More information

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Polit Behav (2013) 35:175 197 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9189-2 ORIGINAL PAPER On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Marc Meredith Yuval Salant Published online: 6 January 2012 Ó Springer

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

Voter strategies with restricted choice menus *

Voter strategies with restricted choice menus * Voter strategies with restricted choice menus * Kenneth Benoit Daniela Giannetti Michael Laver Trinity College, Dublin University of Bologna New York University kbenoit@tcd.ie giannett@spbo.unibo.it ml127@nyu.edu

More information

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty 1 Electoral Competition under Certainty We begin with models of electoral competition. This chapter explores electoral competition when voting behavior is deterministic; the following chapter considers

More information

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries?

Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? Introduction Why Don t Electoral Rules Have the Same Effects in All Countries? In the early 1990s, Japan and Russia each adopted a very similar version of a mixed-member electoral system. In the form used

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Median voter theorem - continuous choice

Median voter theorem - continuous choice Median voter theorem - continuous choice In most economic applications voters are asked to make a non-discrete choice - e.g. choosing taxes. In these applications the condition of single-peakedness is

More information

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000 Campaign Rhetoric: a model of reputation Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania March 9, 2000 Abstract We develop a model of infinitely

More information

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party Policy Images Pablo Fernandez-Vazquez * Supplementary Online Materials [ Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies ] These supplementary materials

More information

Understanding People s Choice When They Have Two Votes

Understanding People s Choice When They Have Two Votes Understanding People s Choice When They Have Two Votes Ludovic Rheault, University of Toronto André Blais, University of Montreal John Aldrich, Duke University Thomas Gschwend, University of Mannheim Abstract

More information

CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations

CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations CSI Brexit 2: Ending Free Movement as a Priority in the Brexit Negotiations 18 th October, 2017 Summary Immigration is consistently ranked as one of the most important issues facing the country, and a

More information

Candidate Citizen Models

Candidate Citizen Models Candidate Citizen Models General setup Number of candidates is endogenous Candidates are unable to make binding campaign promises whoever wins office implements her ideal policy Citizens preferences are

More information

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences University of Colorado, Boulder CU Scholar Undergraduate Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2011 Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's

More information

Repeat Voting: Two-Vote May Lead More People To Vote

Repeat Voting: Two-Vote May Lead More People To Vote Repeat Voting: Two-Vote May Lead More People To Vote Sergiu Hart October 17, 2017 Abstract A repeat voting procedure is proposed, whereby voting is carried out in two identical rounds. Every voter can

More information

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy

Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy Chapter three Electoral Systems and Evaluations of Democracy André Blais and Peter Loewen Introduction Elections are a substitute for less fair or more violent forms of decision making. Democracy is based

More information

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard RESEARCH PAPER> May 2012 Wisconsin Economic Scorecard Analysis: Determinants of Individual Opinion about the State Economy Joseph Cera Researcher Survey Center Manager The Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

More information

A New Electoral System for a New Century. Eric Stevens

A New Electoral System for a New Century. Eric Stevens A New Electoral System for a New Century Eric There are many difficulties we face as a nation concerning public policy, but of these difficulties the most pressing is the need for the reform of the electoral

More information

Voter preferences and party loyalty under cumulative voting: Political behaviour after electoral reform in Bremen and Hamburg

Voter preferences and party loyalty under cumulative voting: Political behaviour after electoral reform in Bremen and Hamburg Voter preferences and party loyalty under cumulative voting: Political behaviour after electoral reform in Bremen and Hamburg Shaun Bowler, Gail McElroy, Stefan Müller Published in Electoral Studies 51

More information

UNDERSTANDING TAIWAN INDEPENDENCE AND ITS POLICY IMPLICATIONS

UNDERSTANDING TAIWAN INDEPENDENCE AND ITS POLICY IMPLICATIONS UNDERSTANDING TAIWAN INDEPENDENCE AND ITS POLICY IMPLICATIONS Emerson M. S. Niou Abstract Taiwan s democratization has placed Taiwan independence as one of the most important issues for its domestic politics

More information

Accepted Manuscript. Title: Voting for government coalitions in Ireland under Single Transferable Vote. Authors: Michael Marsh

Accepted Manuscript. Title: Voting for government coalitions in Ireland under Single Transferable Vote. Authors: Michael Marsh Accepted Manuscript Title: Voting for government coalitions in Ireland under Single Transferable Vote Authors: Michael Marsh PII: S0261-3794(10)00016-8 DOI: 10.1016/j.electstud.2010.03.004 Reference: JELS

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Jesse Richman Old Dominion University jrichman@odu.edu David C. Earnest Old Dominion University, and

More information

A Benchmarking Forecast of the 2013 Bundestag Election. Mark Kayser and Arndt Leininger. Hertie School of Governance, Berlin.

A Benchmarking Forecast of the 2013 Bundestag Election. Mark Kayser and Arndt Leininger. Hertie School of Governance, Berlin. A Benchmarking Forecast of the 2013 Bundestag Election Mark Kayser and Arndt Leininger Hertie School of Governance, Berlin 31 July 2013 Election forecasts are too serious a business to be left to pollsters

More information

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Olga Gorelkina Max Planck Institute, Bonn Ioanna Grypari Max Planck Institute, Bonn Preliminary & Incomplete February 11, 2015 Abstract This paper

More information

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Case Study: Get out the Vote Case Study: Get out the Vote Do Phone Calls to Encourage Voting Work? Why Randomize? This case study is based on Comparing Experimental and Matching Methods Using a Large-Scale Field Experiment on Voter

More information

Mathematics and Social Choice Theory. Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives. 4.1 Social choice procedures

Mathematics and Social Choice Theory. Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives. 4.1 Social choice procedures Mathematics and Social Choice Theory Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives 4.1 Social choice procedures 4.2 Analysis of voting methods 4.3 Arrow s Impossibility Theorem 4.4 Cumulative voting

More information

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices Kim S. So, Peter F. Orazem, and Daniel M. Otto a May 1998 American Agricultural Economics Association

More information

Electing the President. Chapter 12 Mathematical Modeling

Electing the President. Chapter 12 Mathematical Modeling Electing the President Chapter 12 Mathematical Modeling Phases of the Election 1. State Primaries seeking nomination how to position the candidate to gather momentum in a set of contests 2. Conventions

More information

Germany: Merkel does not stand out but holds

Germany: Merkel does not stand out but holds Germany: Merkel does not stand out but holds Carolina Plescia and David Johann 5 June 2014 Introduction Germany went to the polls on Sunday, May 25 to elect 96 members of the European Parliament, by far

More information

Majority cycles in national elections

Majority cycles in national elections Majority cycles in national elections Bodo Knoll, Joan Serra 1 University of Bochum Abstract This paper provides information on cycle probabilities for 147 national elections and tests if a high level

More information

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE. Full terms and conditions of use:

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE. Full terms and conditions of use: This article was downloaded by: [UT University of Texas Arlington] On: 3 April 2010 Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 907143247] Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England

More information

CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS

CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS Working Paper Number 93 September 2001 Tactical Voting and Tactical Non-Voting By Stephen Fisher The Centre for Research into Elections and Social

More information

Approval Voting in Germany: Description of a Field Experiment

Approval Voting in Germany: Description of a Field Experiment Approval Voting in Germany: Description of a Field Experiment Carlos Alós Ferrer and Ðura-Georg Granić This version: January 2009 Abstract We report on a field experiment on approval voting conducted during

More information

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics Kenneth Benoit Trinity College Dublin Michael Laver New York University July 8, 2005 Abstract Every legislature may be defined by a finite integer partition

More information

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders Gregory S. Warrington Department of Mathematics & Statistics, University of Vermont, 16 Colchester Ave., Burlington, VT 05401, USA November 4,

More information

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and education use, including for instruction at the authors institution

More information

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Soc Choice Welf (018) 50:81 303 https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1084- ORIGINAL PAPER Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Margherita Negri

More information

Power in German Politics: An Analysis of the German Electoral System

Power in German Politics: An Analysis of the German Electoral System Power in German Politics: An Analysis of the German Electoral System Josef Schmalfuss University of Cambridge September 6, 2010 Abstract The decision of the Federal Constitutional Court of Germany that

More information

Online publication date: 02 December 2010 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Online publication date: 02 December 2010 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE This article was downloaded by: [University of Connecticut] On: 10 December 2010 Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 922824824] Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and

More information

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance 2015 Gothenburg 2015-04-16 Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance Maria Oskarson, Henrik Oscarsson & Edvin Boije Report 2015:01 Swedish National Election Studies Program

More information

On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making

On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making I. SOCIAL CHOICE 1 On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making Duncan Black Source: Journal of Political Economy, 56(1) (1948): 23 34. When a decision is reached by voting or is arrived at by a group all

More information

MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory

MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory 3.1 Social choice procedures Plurality voting Borda count Elimination procedures Sequential pairwise

More information

Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations. Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016

Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations. Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016 Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016 Page 1 About CFUW CFUW is a non-partisan, voluntary,

More information

On the nature of voters coalition preferences

On the nature of voters coalition preferences JOURNAL OF ELECTIONS, PUBLIC OPINION AND PARTIES, 2017 VOL. 27, NO. 3, 254 273 http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/17457289.2016.1270286 On the nature of voters coalition preferences Carolina Plescia and Julian

More information

A Dead Heat and the Electoral College

A Dead Heat and the Electoral College A Dead Heat and the Electoral College Robert S. Erikson Department of Political Science Columbia University rse14@columbia.edu Karl Sigman Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research sigman@ieor.columbia.edu

More information

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference? Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference? Elena Llaudet Department of Government Harvard University April 11, 2015 Abstract Little is known about how electoral

More information

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc.

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc. Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc. Andrei Bremzen, Georgy Egorov, Dmitry Shakin This Draft: April 2, 2007 Abstract In most countries with proportional representation

More information

HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham February 1, 2018

HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham February 1, 2018 HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham smg1@ualberta.ca February 1, 2018 1 1 INTRODUCTION Dual Member Proportional (DMP) is a compelling alternative to the Single Member

More information

- IPSA World Congress 2016, Poznan - RC Playing the Multilevel Game: Federalism and the Articulation of Power

- IPSA World Congress 2016, Poznan - RC Playing the Multilevel Game: Federalism and the Articulation of Power - IPSA World Congress 2016, Poznan - RC28.16 - Playing the Multilevel Game: Federalism and the Articulation of Power Simon WILLOCQ PhD Candidate F.R.S.-F.N.R.S. Fellow Researcher Cevipol / Université libre

More information

An Assessment of Ranked-Choice Voting in the San Francisco 2005 Election. Final Report. July 2006

An Assessment of Ranked-Choice Voting in the San Francisco 2005 Election. Final Report. July 2006 Public Research Institute San Francisco State University 1600 Holloway Ave. San Francisco, CA 94132 Ph.415.338.2978, Fx.415.338.6099 http://pri.sfsu.edu An Assessment of Ranked-Choice Voting in the San

More information

Approval Voting and Scoring Rules with Common Values

Approval Voting and Scoring Rules with Common Values Approval Voting and Scoring Rules with Common Values David S. Ahn University of California, Berkeley Santiago Oliveros University of Essex June 2016 Abstract We compare approval voting with other scoring

More information

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE This article was downloaded by:[neicon Consortium] [NEICON Consortium] On: 13 July 2007 Access Details: [subscription number 762905488] Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales

More information

Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland

Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland Prof. Gallagher Arguments for and against electoral system change in Ireland Why would we decide to change, or not to change, the current PR-STV electoral system? In this short paper we ll outline some

More information

Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Comparative Perspective: A Test of Existing Hypotheses

Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Comparative Perspective: A Test of Existing Hypotheses Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Comparative Perspective: A Test of Existing Hypotheses Sona Nadenichek Golder Florida State University 2005 Electoral Studies, Vol. 24. Abstract Despite the vast coalition literature,

More information

Ticket-splitting and strategic voting under mixed electoral rules : evidence from Germany Gschwend, Thomas

Ticket-splitting and strategic voting under mixed electoral rules : evidence from Germany Gschwend, Thomas www.ssoar.info Ticket-splitting and strategic voting under mixed electoral rules : evidence from Germany Gschwend, Thomas Veröffentlichungsversion / Published Version Zeitschriftenartikel / journal article

More information

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study Barry C. Burden and Janet M. Box-Steffensmeier The Ohio State University Department of Political Science 2140 Derby Hall Columbus,

More information

Effects of Voting Behavior and Voter Turnout

Effects of Voting Behavior and Voter Turnout John Carroll University Carroll Collected Senior Honors Projects Theses, Essays, and Senior Honors Projects Spring 2014 Effects of Voting Behavior and Voter Turnout Michael Paskert John Carroll University,

More information

Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind?

Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind? Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind? Emekcan Yucel Job Market Paper This Version: October 30, 2016 Latest Version: Click Here Abstract In this paper, I propose non-instrumental benefits

More information

Duverger s Hypothesis, the Run-Off Rule, and Electoral Competition

Duverger s Hypothesis, the Run-Off Rule, and Electoral Competition Advance Access publication May 5, 005 Political Analysis (005) 13:09 3 doi:10.1093/pan/mpi013 Duverger s Hypothesis, the Run-Off Rule, and Electoral Competition Steven Callander Kellogg School of Management,

More information

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Applied Economics Letters, 2012, 19, 1893 1897 Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Jan Saarela a, * and Dan-Olof Rooth b a A bo Akademi University, PO

More information

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis Public Choice (2005) 123: 197 216 DOI: 10.1007/s11127-005-0262-4 C Springer 2005 The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis JOHN CADIGAN Department of Public Administration, American University,

More information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Practice Questions for Exam #2 Fall 2007 Page 1 Practice Questions for Exam #2 1. Suppose that we have collected a stratified random sample of 1,000 Hispanic adults and 1,000 non-hispanic adults. These respondents are asked whether

More information

Electoral Reform Proposal

Electoral Reform Proposal Electoral Reform Proposal By Daniel Grice, JD, U of Manitoba 2013. Co-Author of Establishing a Legal Framework for E-voting 1, with Dr. Bryan Schwartz of the University of Manitoba and published by Elections

More information

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates Vincent Wiegel and Jan van den Berg 1 Abstract. Philosophy can benefit from experiments performed in a laboratory

More information

Leaders, voters and activists in the elections in Great Britain 2005 and 2010

Leaders, voters and activists in the elections in Great Britain 2005 and 2010 Leaders, voters and activists in the elections in Great Britain 2005 and 2010 N. Schofield, M. Gallego and J. Jeon Washington University Wilfrid Laurier University Oct. 26, 2011 Motivation Electoral outcomes

More information

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract

Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner. Abstract Learning and Visualizing Political Issues from Voting Records Erik Goldman, Evan Cox, Mikhail Kerzhner Abstract For our project, we analyze data from US Congress voting records, a dataset that consists

More information

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting An Updated and Expanded Look By: Cynthia Canary & Kent Redfield June 2015 Using data from the 2014 legislative elections and digging deeper

More information

Evidence from Hungary

Evidence from Hungary Strategic Voting, Mixed and Runoff Elections: Evidence from Hungary Daniel Prinz March 30, 2013 Abstract Iattempttoquantifystrategicvotingusingthemixed(proportional and plurality) dual ballot election

More information

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom June 1, 2016 Abstract Previous researchers have speculated that incumbency effects are

More information

Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation

Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation Martin Oost December 216 Faculty of Behavioural, Management and Social Sciences University of Twente Effect of Electoral Systems on the Quality of Political Representation Abstract: Legislatures as elected

More information

Split-ticket voting in German Federal elections, : an example of sophisticated balloting?

Split-ticket voting in German Federal elections, : an example of sophisticated balloting? Electoral Studies 18 (1999) 473 496 www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Split-ticket voting in German Federal elections, 1953 90: an example of sophisticated balloting? Harald Schoen * Institut für Politikwissenschaft

More information

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives?

Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Bachelorproject 2 The Complexity of Compliance: Why do member states fail to comply with EU directives? Authors: Garth Vissers & Simone Zwiers University of Utrecht, 2009 Introduction The European Union

More information

A New Method of the Single Transferable Vote and its Axiomatic Justification

A New Method of the Single Transferable Vote and its Axiomatic Justification A New Method of the Single Transferable Vote and its Axiomatic Justification Fuad Aleskerov ab Alexander Karpov a a National Research University Higher School of Economics 20 Myasnitskaya str., 101000

More information

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys Polimetrics Mass & Expert Surveys Three things I know about measurement Everything is measurable* Measuring = making a mistake (* true value is intangible and unknowable) Any measurement is better than

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information