Institutions and Deep Integration

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Institutions and Deep Integration"

Transcription

1 HEI Working Paper No: 07/2006 Institutions and Deep Integration Alberto Amurgo Pacheco Graduate Institute of International Studies Abstract The paper explains why institutions matter for a deep integration process, as illustrated by the liberalization of Non-Tariff Barriers (NTBs) in Europe. We argue that deep trade liberalization requires supranational institutions of deeper integration that permit enforcement, surveillance, and adjudication. To support the claim, we develop a simple model showing why mutual recognition of norms and testing procedures, coupled with a supranational institution can shape the equilibrium level of NTBs in every member state. Member states host special-interest groups that make political contributions to influence their respective government's choice of NTBs. Politicians maximize a realistic welfare function that favours contributions over consumer's social welfare. The supranational institution drains the incentive to lobby for NTBs. The paper discusses the structure of protection that emerges in the equilibrium, stressing how the lobbies' contributions vary with the effectiveness of the supranational institution in reducing NTBs in the final policy outcome. We then use the model to explain the liberalization of NTBs in the EU. The Authors. All rights reserved. No part of this paper may be reproduced without the permission of the authors.

2 Institutions and Deep Integration Alberto AMURGO PACHECO March, 2006 Abstract The paper explains why institutions matter for a deep integration process, as illustrated by the liberalization of Non-Tariff Barriers (NTBs) in Europe. We argue that deep trade liberalization requires supranational institutions of deeper integration that permit enforcement, surveillance, and adjudication. To support the claim, we develop a simple model showing why mutual recognition of norms and testing procedures, coupled with a supranational institution can shape the equilibrium level of NTBs in every member state. Member states host special-interest groups that make political contributions to influence their respective government s choice of NTBs. Politicians maximize a realistic welfare function that favours contributions over consumer s social welfare. The supranational institution drains the incentive to lobby for NTBs. The paper discusses the structure of protection that emerges in the equilibrium, stressing how the lobbies contributions vary with the effectiveness of the supranational institution in reducing NTBs in the final policy outcome. We then use the model to explain the liberalization of NTBs in the EU. JEL Classification: F13, F15 Keywords: economic integration, endogenous protection. Graduate Institute of International Studies; Avenue de la Paix, 11; 1202 Geneva; Switzerland, amurgop1@hei.unige.ch. I am grateful to Richard Baldwin, and Jaya Krishnakumar for useful discussions and helpful comments.

3 1 Introduction There is deep versus shallow integration in the world, the European Union (EU) is a deep one. The EU is the biggest peaceful effort ever made to bring the peoples of the continent together. It is an exceptional endeavour without parallel elsewhere. Since the collapse of the European Defense Community in 1954, most of the effort has focused on economic integration. One of the most unusual aspects of European economic integration is deep trade liberalization; or the removal of technical barriers to trade arising from heterogeneous national norms (technical regulations and standards), and testing procedures. 1 The European process of NTB liberalization has no equivalent anywhere else in the world. 2 Unlike any other trade arrangement, the ECJ has legislative authority, which supersedes national legislation. In the European experience the issue of supranationality has played a key role to foster deep trade liberalization. None questions the role of the European institutions to liberalize internal trade. Liberalization of tariffs and quotas is relatively simple. The GATT and its successor, the WTO, have been extraordinary successful in the multilateral context, and the EU, and NAFTA in the regional one. In all these cases negotiation has produced the desired outcome. Deep trade liberalization is tricky. NTBs restrain trade by raising foreign firms costs relative to the domestic ones. As Baldwin (2000) suggests, liberalization requires lowering the wedge. There are two dimensions to it; content-of-norms, and testing procedures. Liberalization of the first involves making product norms more cosmopolitan and thus narrowing the cost advantage of domestic firms. Liberalization of the second involves lowering the excess costs that foreign firms face in demonstrating compliance of their goods to accepted norms. There are two ways forward along both dimensions, harmonization (convergence to a single norm or test), and mutual recognition (acceptance of foreign norms and tests). Harmonization can be accomplished through negotiation (a discussion aimed at agreeing a single norm), or through the hegemonic route, (everyone adopts the norms of a 1 Technical regulations are mandatory whereas standards are voluntary. Norms are the specific requirements that products have to meet to be sold in a particular market; testing is required to assess whether products conform with the norms. 2 Australia, and New Zealand have made some progress towards NTB liberalization but it is still very incipient. 1

4 hegemonic state). There are few recent examples of deep trade liberalization. 3 The European experience is the most significant one. The EU has been dealing with NTBs since the Treaty of Rome. In 1957 the Community advocated for harmonization of technical standards but it did not happen; in fact it went backwards. Then from 1969 to 1983 the Community worked on a Programme that far from eliminating NTBs witnessed an increase in technical barriers in the internal market. And then the ECJ enforced mutual recognition and NTB liberalization followed very quickly. European institutions have been important, and most researchers claim that mutual recognition is also an important aspect of NTB liberalization. 4 But, how does the combination of a supranational institution of deeper integration, and mutual recognition lead to liberalization? We present a model that provides a plausible explanation for the question. The model is motivated by the EU experience but it is more general than that; we use it to investigate the role of institutions in liberalization. We develop a model in which the combination of mutual recognition, and the court as an imperfect enforcement and surveillance mechanism, change the equilibrium in a way that there is no lobbying in the first place. There is a quick change, and NTBs disappear because nobody wants them anymore. We organized the paper as follows: section 2 develops a simple formal model of supranational institutions in deep trade liberalization. We show how a supranational institution, and mutual recognition of norms and testing procedures can eliminate NTBs. We discuss some welfare implications, and the fact that there are winers and losers, but the winers win more. section 3 we first use the model to inform a discussion over stage zero. And then we use the model to explain the liberalization of NTBs in the EU. We conclude in section 4 summarizing the main findings and providing some avenues for future research. This is as far as the discussion can go without a formal model. We are turning now to a political economy model that crystallizes the logic behind institutions of deep integration, and NTB liberalization. 3 The process of formation of nations are old examples. 4 See Egan (2001) for a detailed account. In 2

5 2 Institutions and Deep Integration: A Formal Model In order to make the analysis of NTB liberalization tractable, we consider the following simple model. Consider a union of small and symmetric states, and a supranational court of justice. Without loss of generality we will refer to them as the European Union (EU), and the European Court of Justice (ECJ). Member states are free to adopt norms, and testing procedures that may generate NTBs in their territory. Individuals, industries, and member states, however, can complain about them before the ECJ. The court applies the principle of mutual recognition of norms, and testing procedures when it finds that the regulation presents an unnecessary distortion of trade. Supranational law supersedes state s law. We are going to take the perspective that NTBs are politically optimal. This perspective has been the subject of formal work by Grossman and Helpman (1994). It may be useful to present it informally, we assume that governments make their trade policy choices in response to industry lobbying pressures balanced against consumer interests. This is known as the lobbying approach to endogenous protection, and it assumes that all elected governments respond to lobbying activities in the same way. We model the lobbying activities as a menu auction problem. 5 Namely, a situation where the lobby announces a menu of contributions for various possible NTBs open to an auctioneer and then pay the bids according to the action selected. On the supply side, we consider a factor-specific framework. 6 This eliminates general equilibrium supply-side effects because wages are pinned down by productivity in the numeraire industry and each industry-specific factor is paid the Ricardian rent. A typical individual derives income from wages wl, and from the industry-specific factor that he may own. In particular, owners of the specific input used by industry i see their income tied to the domestic price of i. All income is expended. Each member state is inhabited by individuals with identical preferences but different indutry-specific factor endowments. The consumption space is bounded, good 0 acts as a numeraire and there are n non-numeraire goods. 5 See Bernheim and Whinston (1986), and Grossman and Helpman (1994) for a more more detailed treatment. 6 Ricardo-Viner setup. 3

6 Every industry produces one type of good. The numeraire good is produced from labour alone. The non-numeraire goods are produced from labour and an industry-specific factor. In order to eliminate cross-price effects on the demand side, we assume that preferences are separable industry-byindustry. Preferences are strictly convex, and quasi-linear with respect to the numeraire good. We normalize the world and domestic price of the numeraire good to 1. Individuals derive utility from the consumption of goods. Given these assumptions we can represent the individual s preferences by the following quasi-linear utility function: U = c 0 + n u i [c i ] (1) where c 0 is the consumption of the numeraire good; c i is the consumption of the good produced by industry i; i = 1, 2,..., n and n is the number of non-numeraire industries. The sub-utility functions of the non-numeraire industries u i [c i ] are increasing, differentiable, and strictly concave. We denote by p w i the exogenous world price 7 of the good produced by industry i, while p i represents its domestic price. NTBs are the only trade barrier in this world. NTBs drive a wedge τ i between domestic and foreign price of the good produced by industry i. Thus, we denote domestic prices by p i = (p w i + τ i ). Liberalization consists in reducing the wedge. Utility-maximizing individuals consume x 0 = E i=1 p id i (p i ), and x i = d i (p i ); where E is the budget constraint (E stands for expenditure). The individual s optimal choice is embodied in the Walrasian demand function (note that d i ( ) the inverse of u i [c i]). Given the assumption of quasilinear preferences the demand is independent of income. The individual s optimal utility value is captured by the following indirect utility function: V = E + i=1 n S i [p i ] (2) where S i [p i ] is the industry-specific consumer surplus function. i=1 In some exogenous set of industries, industry-specific factor owners are organized politically. 8 Organized industries push for NTBs in order to un- 7 Thanks to the small nation assumption we do not have to worry about it. The small country assumption is convenient so the volume of purchases and sales of each member state does not affect its border prices. 8 See Olson (1971). 4

7 dermine foreign competitors and thus create rents for themselves. As a result, each member state hosts special-interest groups that make political contributions to influence the incumbent government s choice of NTBs. The remaining industries and consumers are not organized, and therefore do not offer any political contribution to the government. We assume that in each member state, all firms in an industry act as one when it comes to political contributions. Contributions are directly and intuitively related to the main reason for lobbying: raising the price of goods that the industry sells by increasing the costs faced by foreign competitors. We can use reasoning from contract theory to argue that it is natural to expect each lobby s contribution to be truthful in the sense that each lobby s contribution varies with NTBs in the same way that the lobby s objective function varies with NTBs. The contribution schedules are as follows: C i [p i ] = π i [p i ] + α i N (S i [p i ] + L) B i (3) where π i [p i ] is the total the Ricardian surplus earned by firms in industry i; N is the number of individuals in a member state; α is the fraction of the population that owns the industry-specific factor for industry i; and L is the individual s labour endowment. Contributions may be reduced by a constant B i. Without loss of generality we are going to assume that α is zero. 9 The present framework is, essentially, applied contract theory. In contract theory, we use two expressions to characterize the optimal contract: the incentive constraint (the agent s first-order condition taking the contract as given), and the participation constraint (the requirement that the expected reward is generous enough to induce the agent to accept the contract in the first place). The lobby presents the government with incentive contracts called contribution schedules that induce the government to do what the organized industry wants the government to do. The government is the agent and the lobby is the principal. Note that the form of the contribution schedule is exactly equal to the lobby s welfare minus B i. This means that the lobby s contributions are di- 9 As Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2006) argue, we are confronted to an awkward situation where the lobby also adjusts its contributions to his interest as consumer. This is what they call the ice-cream clause. 5

8 rectly related to its rents, π i [p i ], but a lobby is not required to contribute all its Ricardian rents to the government; the lobby can reduce its contributions by B i to retain some of the fruits of lobbying without violating the truthfulness constraint. All they have to do is to make sure that the government goes along with it. 10 The lobby does not necessarily give any money, when the point to make is that contribution won t have any effect it can set B i in a way that does not have to pay anything to the government. 11 The national government values the total amount of political contributions and social welfare. Specifically, the government favours campaign contributions over the individual s well being because the former provides a higher probability of becoming re-elected. The government of the typical member state maximizes a realistic welfare function 12 where organized producers receive a higher relative weight than consumers, and non-organized producers. The government s objective function consists of a weighted sum of the standard utilitarian social welfare W, and lobbying contributions C i [p i ], that is: Ω = aw + j Λ C i [p i ] (4) where Λ is the set of industries that are politically organized, and as such are able to make political contributions; 13 a is how much the government weights the consumer surplus, and the producer surplus in unorganized industries; it can be interpreted as the relative weight that the government assigns to the general interest. The parameter a is greater or equal to 0. An equilibrium in the model is a set of contribution schedules, one for each industry, such that each one maximizes the joint welfare of the lobby given the anticipated political optimization by the government; and a domestic price vector that maximizes the government s objective function taking the contribution schedules as given. We have developed a quasi-general equilibrium model that relates the level of NTBs in each state to its domestic political process. We are now 10 Note that it is very different from assuming that lobbyists bribe the governments. 11 It is right in the equilibrium. I give you an incentive to do something in the margin, and then I take away to the point where you are just indifferent between saying yes or no to the whole package. Basic contract theory. 12 See Baldwin (1987) on realistic welfare functions. 13 There is no restriction on the size of the parameter a. 6

9 turning to discuss the equilibrium level of NTBs that will arise both in the absence and in the presence of the ECJ. 2.1 The equilibrium level of NTBs We are interested in finding the equilibrium level of pre-liberalization barriers. Namely, the level of NTBs in the absence of the ECJ, and before the principle of mutual recognition plays any role in the story. The government s decision problem is to find the domestic vector of prices that maximizes its objective function taking the contribution schedules as given. Thus, the government s problem is to choose τ i in order to maximize: Ω = a NS i [p i ] + π i [p i ] + (1 + a) π i [p i ] B i (5) i Λ i Λ Given that 5 is continuously differentiable, we can characterize an optimal τ by means of the first-order conditions: Ω = a ( NS i[p i ] + π i [p i ] ) + π i [p i ] = 0 (6) For tractability we assume linear demand and supply functions of the type Q s [p i ] = b s p i, and Q d [p i ] = a d b d p i. We have that the change in consumer surplus NS i [p i] is (minus) the level of consumption, and the change in producer surplus π i [p i] is the level of production. Therefore the parameter a is multiplying the negative term M[p i ], the level of imports. We can rewrite 6 as follows: a(m[p i ]) = π i(p i ) (7) The left hand side term in 7 can be thought of as the Marginal Economic Cost (MEC) for the government of allowing NTBs. The right hand side can be interpreted as the Marginal Political Benefit (MPB) for the government of adopting the NTB. Note that the MPB is identical to the domestic supply curve Q s [p i ]. Substituting the functional forms in 7 and solving for τi we find the level of NTBs that the government chooses in equilibrium: τ i = aa d [a (b d + b s ) + b s ] pw i (8) 7

10 where τ is the equilibrium wedge (mark-up) on the domestic price of good i; 14 the impact on prices resulting from the government s domestic choice of equilibrium NTBs in industry i. Given the symmetry of the model, we expect all governments to choose the same.! MEC MPB! * NTB Figure 1: The level of NTBs τ in the absence of the ECJ. Figure 1 shows the MEC and MPB curves. The MPB curve is upward sloped. The MEC curve could start from zero under some regulatory conditions. Since the marginal economic loss from rising the NTB from zero is zero it makes sense to plot it in such a way. The MEC rises as long as the slopes of the domestic supply and demand curve do not change too much. Given the assumption of linear supply and demand curves the MEC curve is a positively sloped linear curve. The determination of the level of contributions, in particular, the determination of the B i s is straight forward. 15 In the model, the assumption of truthfulness dictates the form of the contract, so 6 is the incentive constraint. To find the participation constraint, we assume that the government has the right to refuse the contribution schedules. The assumption implies that the lobby must ensure that the level of the government s payoff is at least as high when it accepts the contributions as when it does not. If the government refuses the contribution schedule from the lobby in industry i, aa d [a(b d +b s)+b s]. 14 The calculation of the domestic price is straight forward; p i = 15 A similar procedure for determining the B s is laid out in detail in Grossman and Helpman (1994). 8

11 its optimal choice of NTB is zero. 16 Consequently, the lobby must ensure that B i is such that the government s payoff is equal to its reservation payoff, namely a times social welfare under free trade. 17 An organized industry will always choose to offer the contract to its agent, the government. 2.2 The equilibrium level of NTBs with the ECJ. We are now going to determine the level of NTBs that arises in the presence of the ECJ, and the principle of mutual recognition in the model. The combination of mutual recognition and the ECJ makes protection less attainable to all firms, and changes the domestic problem in a way that favours liberalization. We can think of mutual recognition as an agreement to disagree. It boils down to accepting that different regulations are simply different means of achieving the same regulatory goals. 18 The consequence for firms is freedom to use any of the available regulations, including those of their own national state. Put simply, mutual recognition allows all firms to avoid unpleasant foreign regulations that have the purpose of making their exports less competitive; products meeting the norms of any member state enjoy single-market access. By the same token, firms realize that pushing for similar unpleasant regulations at home does not protect them from foreign competition any longer. As a result, firms stop lobbying for regulatory protectionism, namely NTBs. become less interested in regulatory protection. The result for governments is that lobbies The ECJ allows those hurt by NTBs to challenge them on court. We can use economic reasoning to infer that the challenged NTBs are going to be the ones creating the highest rents for the organized domestic firms, namely those that create the greatest losses for foreign competitors. The ECJ acts as an imperfect enforcement mechanism of mutual recognition. When the ECJ backs the claim mutual recognition is the baseline principle. Mutual recognition, and in particular its imperfect enforcement produced by the Court, drains the lobbies incentive to lobby. In the context of the model, we expect the lobby s truthful contribution schedule to capture the possibility to reach mutual recognition. The new 16 Given the small nation fiction. 17 We can easily compute B i = a d(b d +3 b s)a b d 2 +b s See Baldwin (2000). 9

12 contribution schedules of the lobbies look as follows: { Ci θ θ i B i If the constraint binds; = π i [p i ] B i Otherwise. (9) where Ci θ is the level of contribution schedules. Note that at the margin the lobby s contribution is π i (p i) up to the point where the constraint binds, thereafter the marginal contribution drops to zero and stays there. We can interpret the level of θ as the maximum amount of the lobby s producer surplus that is not likely to be challenged in court. The government (acting as an auctioneer) observes the menu of political contributions that the lobby makes available, and aims to do as good as it can. The government s attainable rents are capped because mutual recognition has taken away much of the incentive to lobby, and the lobbies adjust their contribution schedules accordingly. The salient feature of the model is the subtle intervention or lack of it of the ECJ. The ECJ does not determine directly the size of θ, those hurt by NTBs do. In other words, surveillance is done by those hurt by NTBs. The ECJ adjudicates in case of complain, and by taking a narrow view as to what constitutes a NTB the ECJ can effectively enforce a tight θ. We can think of it as a threshold. 19 The ECJ introduces a constraint on the amount of favour that lobbyists can extract from their national governments. The presence of the court modifies the government s decision problem, and the optimal choice of NTB. The government, as the agent, can only choose among the contribution schedules proposed by the lobbies, and the lobbies contribution schedules reflect the bound imposed by mutual recognition. The government now faces a constraint on the MPB (the amount of truthful contributions schedules). We can write the constraint as follows: π i [p i ] θ (10) The problem of the government now consists in choosing τ i to maximize its objective function 5 given constraint on the lobby s rents. So far so good, however, the ECJ and the possibility of mutual recognition introduces some elements of complexity in the model. Note that the constraint is continuous in the level space, but piecewise continuous in the 19 In reality we could think of it as a diminimis rule; norms having a marginal impact on trade are allowed. 10

13 marginal space. 20 This translates into the government s objective function having a kink at the point where the constraint becomes binding. As shown in figure 2, the first derivative of the producer surplus is positive until it drops to zero when the constraint binds. The objective function is piecewise continuous, but not differentiable. In other words, we have to maximize a non-smooth function.! MEC MPB! " NTB Figure 2: The level of NTBs τ θ in the presence of the ECJ. There is a branch of mathematics that deals with non-smooth optimization. 21 We could apply it to solve this problem but it would require adding some structure on the problem and some restrictive assumptions. We can characterize a solution for the model in an accessible way, however, by realizing that given the way the problem is defined, the optima must be the corner solution. The solution method that we propose does not fit the cookbook approach for constrained optimization; nevertheless it allows to characterize the optimal level of NTBs τ θ chosen by the government. We propose to divide the problem in two parts. The first part consists in maximizing 5 up to the point where the constraint becomes binding (included). The second part consists in maximizing 5 after the constraint becomes binding. 22 We then compare the local optima from each of the parts, and choose the highest. We show that there is no point belonging to 20 When the constraint becomes binding the marginal π i [p i] drops to zero. 21 See Clarke (1983) for an introduction to the optimization of non-smooth functions. 22 What the government wants to do is to get the marginal differences as close as possible, in fact zero if they can. The first-order conditions say that we should equate the MEC 11

14 the other part that yields a higher level of welfare for the government. In the first part, until the constraint becomes binding, Kuhn-Tucker (necessary) conditions characterize the local optimum. 23 We set up the lagrangean for the government s maximization problem: L = a NS i [p i ] + π i [p i ] + (1 + a) π i [p i ] B i + λ (θ π i [p i ]) (11) i Λ i Λ By inspection of the Kuhn-Tucker (necessary) conditions: L τ θ = a ( NS i[p i ] + π i[p i ] ) + (1 λ)π i[p i ] = 0 L λ = (θ π i[p i ]) 0 (12) With complementary slackness. 24 Given the linear specification of the model we can find an expression for the producer surplus that allows us to solve the problem. 25 The MEC of the government is the same as in the absence of the court. The MPB is discontinuous and the discontinuity lies where π i [p i ] = θ. It is straight forward to find a solution for part one 2θ τ = b s p w i. As for the second part, we have to show that there is no other point where the government can do better. By inspection of the discontinuous first order conditions it is straight forward. We can verify this because after the constraint becomes binding, the change in the producer surplus π i [p i] drops to zero. So we know that the function must necessarily take a lower value. We are able to characterize the solution because it is a corner situation. The outcome is where the constraint is. The NTB will be dictated where profit is equal to θ, and the solution is the θ where the jump started if it is binding. If it is not binding it is the same old one. And this is exactly and the MPB, but if cannot equate them because of the non-differentiability, should be as close as possibe. 23 Concerning the FOCs. The solution is obtained from the FOC on lambda. The first order condition is a necessary condition for a smooth function, and that s why we do not use it. 24 The complementary slackness condition sates that λ L = 0; with L = 0 where the λ λ constraint binds.» 25 The expression for the producer surplus is π i[p i] = bsp2 i. λ = 1 + a 1 + b d 2 bs q a d b 2θ s bs 12

15 what we want because what we get is that τ θ is dictated by the institutional constraint and if the constraint gets tighter, the θ gets lower. We denote by τ θ i the equilibrium level of NTBs in industry i; namely: τ θ = 2θ b s p w i (13) What we can see from 13 is that by choosing θ the ECJ can bring the domestic price anywhere between the free trade level and the pre-liberalization level (both included). We can verify that choosing θ F T the ECJ would achieve p ECJ i = p F i T. The result allows us to characterize a range for θ that yields any value between the free trade outcome, and the equilibrium with the court. The range θ F T < θ < θ is: b s a 2 d 2 (b s + b d ) 2 < θ < b s (aa d ) 2 2 [a (b s + b d ) + b s ] 2 (14) In the presence of the ECJ the solution is the incentive constraint. Namely, when the lobby does its best given the constraint that it faces. There is no incentive constraint as before due to the non-smoothness problem. The incentive constraint is non-smooth. So that is the incentive constraint, their behaviour is compatible with what is good for them given the contract that they observe. The participation constraint in the presence of the ECJ is B i. We can verify that once the firms are done paying off the government, there is something left over for them; that s fairly obvious in this case. B i is the difference between the government welfare with the ECJ and under free trade Welfare considerations In the model there is a difference between the government s objective function and the social welfare function. The problem arises when we deal with institutions in economic models, and can be solved assuming a veil of ignorance type of evaluation; we are outside of the political system and evaluate whether the ECJ is a good idea. 27 We can also think of it as the right and q 26 We can compute B i = θ 1 b d bs a d 2 θ, which is positive for any b s a d(b d +3 b s) b 2 d +b 2 s value of θ > 1/2 a d 2 (2 b s+2 b d +a d a b s a d b d a) 2 b s ( b d 2 +b s2 ) Another way to think about this is like a constitution writing exercise; we write a constitution under the veil of ignorance. The government, the consumers, etc. ignore 13

16 left sides of the government s brain; the government worries about social welfare in stage one, but in stage two it cannot resist the lobbiests. 28 The social welfare is simply the sum of the consumer and producer surplus. Given the linear specification of the model the expression for social welfare in industry i is: SW i = a d p i + p2 i 2 (b s b d ). We use the model to show how the social welfare changes with mutual recognition and the court. We denote by W F T the social welfare under free trade. Given the absence of transport costs in the model the domestic price of the good produced by industry i and its world price are identical. We have that p w i = p i = a d (b s+b d ) ; and the corresponding level of social welfare is: W F T = 1/2 a d 3 a (aa d b s + 2 b s + 2 b d b d aa d ) (b s + b d ) 2 (15) We denote by W the social welfare in the absence of the ECJ; the level of pre-liberalization social welfare. The domestic price of the good produced aa in industry i is p i = d [a(b s+b d )+b s] ; and the associated level of social welfare is: W = 1/4 aa d 2 ( 4 b d 2 + b s 2 ) b s + b d (16) We denote by W θ the social welfare when the ECJ constrains the level of attainable protection. The corresponding price is determined by θ, namely 2θ those hurt by NTBs. The expression for domestic prices is p i = b s, and the associated level of welfare is: W θ = θ + a d 2 θ b s b dθ b s (17) Note that W θ is positive for any value of θ > 2 a 2 d b s. ( b s+b d ) 2 We verify that as long as the domestic price with the court and mutual recognition is below the pre-liberalization level, social welfare is higher with the court than without: (W θ > W ) (p θ i < p i ) (18) the way it is going to be, we decide a system to lead best, and then we find out whether we do good or not given the system we have. 28 See Bhagwati and Feenstra (1982) for a left versus right brain discussion in the context of tariff-setting. 14

17 Given the linearity of the model individuals are better off in the equilibrium in the presence of the ECJ. They face a lower price, and the consumer surplus is higher. Organized industries are worse off with the Court than without since the price is lower and their combined producer surplus is also lower than the pre-liberalization level. The court has no impact for nonorganized industries, if anything they win as consumers. Those who win with the court win more than those who lose because the combined social welfare is higher. Nobody would object to the ECJ. 3 Discussion In this section, we first step outside the model and use the model to inform a discussion on stage zero. Then we use the model to explain a particular episode of European integration: the liberalization of NTBs in the EU. 3.1 Some informal considerations We refer to stage zero as the period of time when the deep measure is agreed; it is the setting up phase. Although it is not formally addressed in the model we can use the model to inform a discussion about it. Specifically, we can use the results of the model to discuss whether or not the deep measure (a supranational institution) would be acceptable. When the deep measure is approved the wins exam is done under a veil of ignorance; nobody knows who is going to be the lobby in the future. If countries were to adopt a deep measure with immediate effects, we would expect a whole set of industries to lobby against it. But in the European case what happened is that the deep measure was adopted in 1957 and it does not really have an impact until thirty 30 years later. It was difficult to know at that point who would win or lose. Moreover, since the society as a whole is better off with the court, it is reasonable not to expect major objections to the court. There may also be some aspects of discounting as well. Namely, potential lobbyists discount heavily uncertain losses that are far in the future, as a result the lobbies do not have any quasi-rents to defend. They do not get organized during stage zero. In reality the ones who actually have to agree are the governments that negotiate the Treaty, and the people that have to approve it by referendum. 15

18 Big institutional changes as a deep measure of integration very often involve referendums where the citizens have to more or less approve it. It is the way it works in democracy. In the model both the people and the governments are happy with the Court, they are not shooting themselves in the foot, or acting irrationally. As a result we can argue that it is natural for the deep measure to be approved. Organized industries lose from liberalization in their industries, but they win from liberalization in the remaining industries. In an utilitarian framework where one dollar counts one dollar, they do lose, there are winers and losers but the winers win more, so as long as there is symmetry in the model there is no reason for them not to agree to the ECJ. Everyone is involved in referendums involving big institutional changes, rather than just the lobbiests. 3.2 European institutions and internal trade liberalization As pointed out in the introduction, the model is motivated by the European experience with NTB liberalization. This section discusses the European experience in the light of the economic and political economy logic that is crystallized in our simple model. The EU has been trying to deal effectively with NTBs since the Treaty of Rome. In 1957 the EEC advocated for harmonization of technical standards but it did not happen, although internal tariffs and quotas disappeared very quickly. Little progress was made to eliminate NTBs but since 1968 essentially all intra-community trade has been free from tariffs and quotas; subsequent liberalization has focused on NTBs. Then from 1969 to 1983 the EEC worked on a General Programme that specifically targeted NTBs. 29 The Programme is known as the Old Approach and it defined an ambitious agenda to eliminate all NTBs by 1971, and to prevent new ones from being adopted. The Old Approach focused on NTB liberalization through negotiated harmonization. Far from eliminating NTBs, it witnessed a surge of NTBs in the internal market. It was a remarkable failure by any measure. 30 In the 1970s, the ECJ ruled that most NTBs conflicted with the Treaty 29 The General Programme for the removal of technical obstacles to trade was adopted on May 28,1969, it was composed of four Council resolutions and a framework decision. 30 See Majone (1994). 16

19 ! MEC = MEC MPB MPB! "! * NTB Figure 3: The equilibrium level of NTBs in the presence and in the absence of the ECJ. of Rome and were therefore illegal. The rulings provided the key elements for mutual recognition and are the basis of the New Approach. After the Dassonville 31 and Cassis 32 sentences national governments were still free to adopt different norms and testing procedures, but mutual recognition assured that no significant protection of the domestic market was to be derived from them. Most NTBs could then be challenged in court under EU law. 33 The ECJ took a very narrow view as to what constituted an NTB; the ones creating the highest rents (the greatest losses for foreign competitors) were the first ones to be challenged. As we can observe in figure 3, the model provides a plausible explanation for the process of European deep trade liberalization. The level of NTBs in the presence of mutual recognition and the ECJ is unambiguously lower than in the absence of the court; it is so because the ECJ can dictate a level of θ such that τ θ < τ. The ECJ s sentences fostered NTB liberalization in the EU because they enforced the principle of mutual recognition. Mutual recognition guaranteed that the goods legally produced in any member state enjoyed EU-market access. As a result, the ECJ changed the value of lobbying for regulatory protection, and the domestic political process inside each member state. 31 In 1974 the ECJ ruled that all trading rules enacted by member sates which are capable of hindering directly or indirectly, actually or potentially, intra-community trade are to be considered as measures having an equivalent effect to quantitative restrictions. 32 In 1979 the ECJ explicitly allowed for some trade-inhibiting national norms, although it set the permissibility very high for rules applying to import-only. 33 Under EU law it is possible for citizens and firms to bring cases before the ECJ even against its own government. 17

20 In the context of our highly stylized model; mutual recognition drains the incentive to lobby for NTBs. The maximum benefit that a lobby can obtain depends on whether mutual recognition is reached. The lobby takes the foreign norm as given, and the ECJ implies that the maximum benefit that can be obtained is capped since any complain before the ECJ is likely to lead to mutual recognition. The sentences were an effective transfer of sovereignty from the member states to the European institutions. It meant that mutual recognition was the baseline principle and the ECJ was going to drive the liberalization agenda. We could wonder how the ECJ got so far out in front of EU politician. The ECJ s sentences amplified by the Commission s embrace of mutual recognition could have fostered regulatory competition, or even a race to the bottom. But the rapid embrace of the New Approach by the EU member states, first, and the Single European Act (SEA) later, were the means of regaining control over the liberalization process. Of course, there were many other factors intervening. But the role of theory is to crystallize the logic of an economic process in a simplified way. What is relevant in the story is that the ECJ brought mutual recognition, and mutual recognition did away with NTBs because it changed the domestic political process in each member state. The supranational authority of the ECJ is key to the liberalization of NTBs. The model shows that European governments did not act irrationally when they agreed on the deep measure that created the ECJ in Concluding remarks We argue that deep trade liberalization requires supranational institutions that permit enforcement, surveillance, and adjudication. The paper presents a simple model of how mutual recognition of norms and testing procedures, and a supranational institution helps a group of protectionist states overcome a coordination failure, and thus foster deep trade liberalization that can benefit them all. The basic logic is very simple. Member states agree to a deep measure that changes the incentives of national special interest groups to lobby for NTBs in a way that leads quickly to a new equilibrium with lower barriers; interestingly, all the parties involved in protection-making the society as a 18

21 whole, the government, and even organized firms are acting rationally. The model takes the perspective that NTBs are the result of the domestic political process in each member state. Governments make their choice of NTBs in response to industry lobbying activities balanced against consumer interests. Mutual recognition is detrimental to the benefits of lobbying, and the supranational institution produces an imperfect enforcement of mutual recognition. Since NTBs are endogenous to the lobbying activities and lobbying is affected by mutual recognition, a supranational institution that enforces mutual recognition changes the incentives to lobby for protection. In fact, when mutual recognition is reached the benefits of lobbying for NTBs evaporate and the lobbies cease their activities. The model explains how barriers which are politically optimal before the court are not politically optimal afterwards; as a result some of the barriers disappear. We show that the model provides a reasonable accounting of the liberalization of NTBs in the EU; it is not empirical evidence but it is an example in which the model helps to organize the thinking about what happened in reality. What happened is that the EU failed to liberalize NTBs until the ECJ enforced mutual recognition. From there onwards mutual recognition would have been the baseline principle but politicians were quick to react and the Council officially launched the Single European Act on The SEA increased the governments control over the liberalization process given that the ECJ had established mutual recognition as the baseline principle. In democracy the ones that have to approve to a deep measure of integration are the governments that negotiate the Treaty, and the citizens. Since the entire society is involved in big institutional changes it makes sense to think of a referendum rather than just the lobbyists. We have presented a model where both the citizens and the governments are happy with the Court, they are not acting irrationally by approving the ECJ. Of course the lobbies that enjoyed high barriers before the Court do lose with it. In an utilitarian framework where one dollar counts one dollar, they do lose, there are winers and losers but the winers win more, so as long as there is symmetry there is no reason for not to approve the deep measure. We have not formalized strategic behaviours; namely why countries do not find significant opposition from the lobbies that would potentially lose with the ECJ-type of agreements. We have assumed that lobbyists act under 19

22 a veil of ignorance. At the time when the deep measure is taken nobody knows who are going to be the lobbies in the future. An example from the European experience may help to clarify the point. In 1957, when the Treaty of Rome was signed none knew who would have an incentive to lobby against it fifty years later. Given that the signature of the deep measure and liberalization happen at very distant points in time there may be also some issues of discounting potential future losses. When the treaty was signed the potential lobbies did not have any quasi-rents to defend. The European experience with NTBs raises some important questions regarding the role of institutions in liberalization. Specifically, does deep trade liberalization in the multilateral context also require supranational institutions? or could mutual recognition work under a lighter enforcement mechanism than the ECJ? In future research it would also be interesting to step outside the EU and investigate both the relevance of the story to the multilateral initiatives to liberalize NTBs, and the scope for coordination between regional and multilateral NTB liberalization policies. Specifically, early coordination could be useful to prevent potential conflicts among highly-idiosyncratic institutions of deeper integration. References Baldwin, R. E. (1987): Politically Realistic Objective Functions and Trade Policy: PROFs and Tariffs, Economic Letters, 24, (2000): Regulatory Protectionism, Developing Nations and a Two- Tier World Trading System, Brookings Trade Forum, 2000, pp Baldwin, R. E., and F. Robert-Nicoud (2006): Protection for Sale Made Easy, CEPR Discussion Papers 5452, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers. Bernheim, B. D., and M. D. Whinston (1986): Menu Auctions, Resource Allocation, and Economic Influence, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(1), Bhagwati, J. N., and R. C. Feenstra (1982): Import Competition Policy and Responsechap. Tariff-Seeking and the Efficient Tariff, pp NBER and University of Chicago Press. 20

23 Clarke, F. H. (1983): Optimization and Nonsmooth Analysis, vol. 5 of Classics in aplied mathematics. John Wiley and Sons. Egan, M. P. (2001): Constructing a European market: standards, regulations, and governance. Oxford Univeryity Press. Grossman, G. M., and E. Helpman (1994): Protection for Sale, American Economic Review, 84(4), Majone, G. (1994): Comparing Strategies of Regulatory Rapprochement, Regulatory Cooperation for an Interdependent World. Olson, M. (1971): Press, Cambridge. The Logic of Collective Action. Harvard University 21

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

The Political Economy of Trade Policy The Political Economy of Trade Policy 1) Survey of early literature The Political Economy of Trade Policy Rodrik, D. (1995). Political Economy of Trade Policy, in Grossman, G. and K. Rogoff (eds.), Handbook

More information

3 Electoral Competition

3 Electoral Competition 3 Electoral Competition We now turn to a discussion of two-party electoral competition in representative democracy. The underlying policy question addressed in this chapter, as well as the remaining chapters

More information

INFANT INDUSTRY AND POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE PROTECTION

INFANT INDUSTRY AND POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE PROTECTION Pacific Economic Review, 11: 3 (2006) pp. 363 378 doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0106.2006.00320.x INFANT INDUSTRY AND POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE PROTECTION BIN XU* China Europe International Business School, Shanghai

More information

Median voter theorem - continuous choice

Median voter theorem - continuous choice Median voter theorem - continuous choice In most economic applications voters are asked to make a non-discrete choice - e.g. choosing taxes. In these applications the condition of single-peakedness is

More information

Corruption and Political Competition

Corruption and Political Competition Corruption and Political Competition Richard Damania Adelaide University Erkan Yalçin Yeditepe University October 24, 2005 Abstract There is a growing evidence that political corruption is often closely

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness CeNTRe for APPlieD MACRo - AND PeTRoleuM economics (CAMP) CAMP Working Paper Series No 2/2013 ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness Daron Acemoglu, James

More information

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION Laura Marsiliani University of Durham laura.marsiliani@durham.ac.uk Thomas I. Renström University of Durham and CEPR t.i.renstrom@durham.ac.uk We analyze

More information

The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises. Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL.

The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises. Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL. The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL. In this paper we wish to explain certain "stylized facts" of the Cuban

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Open Trade, Closed Borders Immigration Policy in the Era of Globalization

Open Trade, Closed Borders Immigration Policy in the Era of Globalization Open Trade, Closed Borders Immigration Policy in the Era of Globalization Margaret E. Peters University of Wisconsin Madison November 9, 2011 Prepared for the 2011 Annual Conference of the International

More information

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus Udo Kreickemeier University of Nottingham Michael S. Michael University of Cyprus December 2007 Abstract Within a small open economy fair wage model with unemployment

More information

"Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson

Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information, by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson April 15, 2015 "Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson Econometrica, Vol. 51, No. 6 (Nov., 1983), pp. 1799-1819. Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1912117

More information

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3 Introduction to Political Economy 14.770 Problem Set 3 Due date: October 27, 2017. Question 1: Consider an alternative model of lobbying (compared to the Grossman and Helpman model with enforceable contracts),

More information

Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards

Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards Paul Oslington 2005 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/963/ MPRA Paper No. 963, posted 29.

More information

An example of public goods

An example of public goods An example of public goods Yossi Spiegel Consider an economy with two identical agents, A and B, who consume one public good G, and one private good y. The preferences of the two agents are given by the

More information

Production Patterns of Multinational Enterprises: The Knowledge-Capital Model Revisited. Abstract

Production Patterns of Multinational Enterprises: The Knowledge-Capital Model Revisited. Abstract Production Patterns of Multinational Enterprises: The Knowledge-Capital Model Revisited Kazuhiko OYAMADA * July 31, 2015 Abstract To prepare an answer to the question of how a developing country can attract

More information

Dynamic Political Choice in Macroeconomics.

Dynamic Political Choice in Macroeconomics. Dynamic Political Choice in Macroeconomics. John Hassler, Kjetil Storesletten, and Fabrizio Zilibotti August 2002 Abstract We analyze positive theories of redistribution, social insurance and public good

More information

International Business 7e

International Business 7e International Business 7e by Charles W.L. Hill (adapted for LIUC09 by R.Helg) McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 The Political Economy of

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY IN AN INTERDEPENDENT WORLD. Kyle Bagwell Robert W. Staiger

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY IN AN INTERDEPENDENT WORLD. Kyle Bagwell Robert W. Staiger NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY IN AN INTERDEPENDENT WORLD Kyle Bagwell Robert W. Staiger Working Paper 10249 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10249 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GOVERNMENT GAINS FROM SELF-RESTRAINT: A BARGAINING THEORY OF INEFFICIENT REDISTRIBUTION. Allan Drazen Nuno Limâo

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GOVERNMENT GAINS FROM SELF-RESTRAINT: A BARGAINING THEORY OF INEFFICIENT REDISTRIBUTION. Allan Drazen Nuno Limâo NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GOVERNMENT GAINS FROM SELF-RESTRAINT: A BARGAINING THEORY OF INEFFICIENT REDISTRIBUTION Allan Drazen Nuno Limâo Working Paper 10375 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10375 NATIONAL

More information

The Immigration Policy Puzzle

The Immigration Policy Puzzle MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Immigration Policy Puzzle Paolo Giordani and Michele Ruta UISS Guido Carli University, World Trade Organization 2009 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/23584/

More information

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative Electoral Incentives Alessandro Lizzeri and Nicola Persico March 10, 2000 American Economic Review, forthcoming ABSTRACT Politicians who care about the spoils

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY John A. List Daniel M. Sturm Working Paper 10609 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10609 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Immigration and Conflict in Democracies

Immigration and Conflict in Democracies Immigration and Conflict in Democracies Santiago Sánchez-Pagés Ángel Solano García June 2008 Abstract Relationships between citizens and immigrants may not be as good as expected in some western democracies.

More information

Lobbying and Bribery

Lobbying and Bribery Lobbying and Bribery Vivekananda Mukherjee* Amrita Kamalini Bhattacharyya Department of Economics, Jadavpur University, Kolkata 700032, India June, 2016 *Corresponding author. E-mail: mukherjeevivek@hotmail.com

More information

Self-enforcing Trade Agreements and Lobbying

Self-enforcing Trade Agreements and Lobbying Self-enforcing Trade Agreements and Lobbying Kristy Buzard 110 Eggers Hall, Economics Department, Syracuse University, Syracuse, NY 13244. 315-443-4079. Abstract In an environment where international trade

More information

Trade theory and regional integration

Trade theory and regional integration Trade theory and regional integration Dr. Mia Mikic mia.mikic@un.org Myanmar Capacity Building Programme Training Workshop on Regional Cooperation and Integration 9-11 May 2016, Yangon Outline of this

More information

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication Tilburg University Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: 1995 Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Mountford, A. W. (1995). Can a brain drain be good

More information

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu STRATEGIC INTERACTION, TRADE POLICY, AND NATIONAL WELFARE Bharati Basu Department of Economics, Central Michigan University, Mt. Pleasant, Michigan, USA Keywords: Calibration, export subsidy, export tax,

More information

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Sephorah Mangin 1 and Yves Zenou 2 September 15, 2016 Abstract: Workers from a source country consider whether or not to illegally migrate to a host country. This

More information

1 Aggregating Preferences

1 Aggregating Preferences ECON 301: General Equilibrium III (Welfare) 1 Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301 General Equilibrium III: Welfare We are done with the vital concepts of general equilibrium Its power principally

More information

George Mason University

George Mason University George Mason University SCHOOL of LAW Two Dimensions of Regulatory Competition Francesco Parisi Norbert Schulz Jonathan Klick 03-01 LAW AND ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES This paper can be downloaded without

More information

IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 517

IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 517 INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES IDE Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussions and critical comments IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 517 Is FTA/EPA Effective for a Developing

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ANALYTICS OF THE WAGE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ANALYTICS OF THE WAGE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ANALYTICS OF THE WAGE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 14796 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14796 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi Voter Participation with Collusive Parties David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi 1 Overview Woman who ran over husband for not voting pleads guilty USA Today April 21, 2015 classical political conflict model:

More information

A General Overview of the Political Economy of Trade

A General Overview of the Political Economy of Trade A General Overview of the Political Economy of Trade By Ana Islam * May 17, 2002 Islam 1 Written for: Seminar in Aussenwirtschaft Sommersemester 2002 Abstract Economists have long promoted free trade but

More information

Introduction to WTO Law

Introduction to WTO Law Introduction to WTO Law Prof. Dr. Friedl WEISS Institute for European, International and Comparative Law University of Vienna Winter Term 2009 WTO Law - Prof. WEISS 1 Why trade? Autarky: a country has

More information

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism By Richard Baldwin, Journal of Economic perspectives, Winter 2016 The GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) was established in unusual

More information

Trans-boundary Pollution and International. Migration

Trans-boundary Pollution and International. Migration Trans-boundary Pollution and International igration KENJI KONDOH School of Economics, Chukyo University, 11-2 Yagotohonmachi Showaku, Nagoya, JPN 466-8666 FX: +81-52-835-7496, e-mail: kkondo@mecl.chukyo-u.ac.jp

More information

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL:

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Import Competition and Response Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor Volume

More information

Endogenous Politics and the Design of Trade Agreements

Endogenous Politics and the Design of Trade Agreements Endogenous Politics and the Design of Trade Agreements Kristy Buzard* May 10, 2014 Abstract Political pressure is undoubtedly an important influence in the setting of trade policy and the formulation of

More information

Common Agency and Coordination: General Theory and Application to Government Policy Making

Common Agency and Coordination: General Theory and Application to Government Policy Making Common Agency and Coordination: General Theory and Application to Government Policy Making The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your

More information

A Comparison of Optimal Tariffs and Welfare under No. Lobbying, Domestic Lobbying, and Domestic-foreign. Lobbying

A Comparison of Optimal Tariffs and Welfare under No. Lobbying, Domestic Lobbying, and Domestic-foreign. Lobbying A Comparison of Optimal Tariffs and Welfare under No Lobbying, Domestic Lobbying, and Domestic-foreign Lobbying Xianhai Huang School of Economics, Zhejiang University Hangzhou, P.R. China Jing Lu School

More information

Trade and Public Policies: NTMs in the WTO

Trade and Public Policies: NTMs in the WTO Trade and Public Policies: NTMs in the WTO Xinyi Li Trade Policies Review Division, WTO Secretariat 12 th ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop December 2016 1 Disclaimer The views and opinions expressed in

More information

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency 14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency Daron Acemoglu MIT October 2 and 4, 2018. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9 October 2 and 4, 2018. 1 /

More information

Common Agency Lobbying over Coalitions and Policy

Common Agency Lobbying over Coalitions and Policy Common Agency Lobbying over Coalitions and Policy David P. Baron and Alexander V. Hirsch July 12, 2009 Abstract This paper presents a theory of common agency lobbying in which policy-interested lobbies

More information

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009 The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009 1. The question Do immigrants alter the employment opportunities of native workers? After World War I,

More information

Labour market integration and its effect on child labour

Labour market integration and its effect on child labour Labour market integration and its effect on child labour Manfred Gärtner May 2011 Discussion Paper no. 2011-23 Department of Economics University of St. Gallen Editor: Publisher: Electronic Publication:

More information

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation Hung- Ju Chen* ABSTRACT This paper examines the effects of stronger intellectual property rights (IPR) protection

More information

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA 1 VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA SANTA CRUZ wittman@ucsc.edu ABSTRACT We consider an election

More information

Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community

Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community 24.11.2016 RELATED Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community Training Course Challenges and Opportunities of the ASEAN Economic Community

More information

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006) Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006) Group Hicks: Dena, Marjorie, Sabina, Shehryar To the press alone, checkered as it is

More information

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 11: Economic Policy under Representative Democracy

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 11: Economic Policy under Representative Democracy 14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 11: Economic Policy under Representative Democracy Daron Acemoglu MIT October 16, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lecture 11 October 16, 2017.

More information

INTERNATIONAL LABOR STANDARDS AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CHILD-LABOR REGULATION

INTERNATIONAL LABOR STANDARDS AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CHILD-LABOR REGULATION INTERNATIONAL LABOR STANDARDS AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CHILD-LABOR REGULATION Matthias Doepke Northwestern University Fabrizio Zilibotti University of Zurich Abstract Child labor is a persistent phenomenon

More information

Illegal Immigration and Preferential Trade Liberalization. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay *

Illegal Immigration and Preferential Trade Liberalization. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay * Illegal Immigration and Preferential Trade Liberalization Subhayu Bandyopadhyay * Department of Economics, West Virginia University Morgantown, WV-26506-6025, USA. April, 2001. Abstract This paper presents

More information

4.1 Efficient Electoral Competition

4.1 Efficient Electoral Competition 4 Agency To what extent can political representatives exploit their political power to appropriate resources for themselves at the voters expense? Can the voters discipline politicians just through the

More information

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor Journal of Economic Integration 2(2), June 2008; -45 Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor Shigemi Yabuuchi Nagoya City University Abstract This paper discusses the problem of unemployment

More information

International Business Economics

International Business Economics International Business Economics Instructions: 3 points demand: Determine whether the statement is true or false and motivate your answer; 9 points demand: short essay. 1. Globalisation: Describe the globalisation

More information

Global Fairness and Aid

Global Fairness and Aid Global Fairness and Aid ETSG September 2015 Pertti Aalto University School of Business 20.10.2015 Contents Framework Application with a simple Ricardian model Conclusions Global Fairness 1 Equality has

More information

The Choice of Environmental Regulatory Enforcement by Lobby Groups

The Choice of Environmental Regulatory Enforcement by Lobby Groups The Choice of Environmental Regulatory Enforcement by Lobby Groups Lotte Ovaere*, Stef Proost* and Sandra Rousseau** * Center for Economic Studies, KU Leuven ** CEDON, KU Leuven CITE AS : Ovaere, L., Proost,

More information

Can We Reduce Unskilled Labor Shortage by Expanding the Unskilled Immigrant Quota? Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Can We Reduce Unskilled Labor Shortage by Expanding the Unskilled Immigrant Quota? Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University Can We Reduce Unskilled Labor Shortage by Expanding the Unskilled Immigrant Quota? Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University Abstract We investigate whether we can employ an increased number

More information

Jagdish Bhagwati University Professor, Columbia University & Andrew Meyer Senior Fellow Council on Foreign Relations

Jagdish Bhagwati University Professor, Columbia University & Andrew Meyer Senior Fellow Council on Foreign Relations Final The Byrd Amendment Is WTO-Illegal: But We must Kill the Byrd with the Right Stone Jagdish Bhagwati University Professor, Columbia University & Andrew Meyer Senior Fellow Council on Foreign Relations

More information

Joint Report on the EU-Canada Scoping Exercise March 5, 2009

Joint Report on the EU-Canada Scoping Exercise March 5, 2009 Joint Report on the EU-Canada Scoping Exercise March 5, 2009 CHAPTER ONE OVERVIEW OF ACTIVITIES At their 17 th October 2008 Summit, EU and Canadian Leaders agreed to work together to "define the scope

More information

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank Decentralization in Political Agency Theory Decentralization

More information

Should We Tax or Cap Political Contributions? A Lobbying Model With Policy Favors and Access

Should We Tax or Cap Political Contributions? A Lobbying Model With Policy Favors and Access Should We Tax or Cap Political Contributions? A Lobbying Model With Policy Favors and Access Christopher Cotton Published in the Journal of Public Economics, 93(7/8): 831-842, 2009 Abstract This paper

More information

Taxation, Migration, and Pollution

Taxation, Migration, and Pollution International Tax and Public Finance, 6, 39 59 1999) c 1999 Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Taxation, Migration, and Pollution AGNAR SANDMO Norwegian School of Economics

More information

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Chapter 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Preview Production possibilities Changing the mix of inputs Relationships among factor prices and goods prices, and resources and output Trade in

More information

Thinkwell s Homeschool Microeconomics Course Lesson Plan: 31 weeks

Thinkwell s Homeschool Microeconomics Course Lesson Plan: 31 weeks Thinkwell s Homeschool Microeconomics Course Lesson Plan: 31 weeks Welcome to Thinkwell s Homeschool Microeconomics! We re thrilled that you ve decided to make us part of your homeschool curriculum. This

More information

REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME

REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME Ivana Mandysová REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME Univerzita Pardubice, Fakulta ekonomicko-správní, Ústav veřejné správy a práva Abstract: The purpose of this article is to analyse the possibility for SME

More information

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy Chapter 9 The Political Economy of Trade Policy Preview The cases for free trade The cases against free trade Political models of trade policy International negotiations of trade policy and the World Trade

More information

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Chapter 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Chapter Organization 1. Assumption 2. Domestic Market (1) Factor prices and goods prices (2) Factor levels and output levels 3. Trade in the Heckscher-Ohlin

More information

Unions and the political economy of immigration

Unions and the political economy of immigration Unions and the political economy of immigration Giorgio Bellettini Department of Economics University of Bologna Carlotta Berti Ceroni Department of Economics University of Bologna PRELIMINARY VERSION

More information

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade Econ 340 Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade News: Jan 15-21 US and China prepare for trade disputes -- WSJ: 1/17 Canvas "A record Chinese annual trade surplus with the U.S., announced

More information

How Dictators Forestall Democratization Using International Trade Policy 1

How Dictators Forestall Democratization Using International Trade Policy 1 How Dictators Forestall Democratization Using International Trade Policy 1 Kishore Gawande McCombs School of Business Ben Zissimos 2 University of Exeter Business School February 25th, 2017 Abstract: We

More information

Optimal Voting Rules for International Organizations, with an. Application to the UN

Optimal Voting Rules for International Organizations, with an. Application to the UN Optimal Voting Rules for International Organizations, with an Application to the UN Johann Caro Burnett November 24, 2016 Abstract This paper examines a self-enforcing mechanism for an international organization

More information

P1: aaa SJNW N stylea.cls (2005/11/30 v1.0 LaTeX Springer document class) January 2, :37

P1: aaa SJNW N stylea.cls (2005/11/30 v1.0 LaTeX Springer document class) January 2, :37 European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 DOI 10.1007/s10657-006-5668-z 1 European integration from the agency theory perspective 2 3 J. Andrés Faíña Antonio García-Lorenzo Jesús López-Rodríguez

More information

Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence

Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence Joanne Roberts 1 Department of Economics University of Toronto Toronto, ON M5S 3G7 Canada jorob@chass.utoronto.ca March 23, 2000 Abstract In this

More information

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 62

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 62 1 / 62 Political Economics Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich Summer term 2010 4 / 62 Table of contents 1 Introduction(MG) 2 Preferences and voting (MG) 3 Voter turnout (MG) 4 Electoral competition (SÜ)

More information

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions Xinxuan Cheng School of Management, Hebei University Baoding 071002, Hebei, China E-mail: cheng_xinxuan@126.com Abstract The rules of origin derived from

More information

When users of congested roads may view tolls as unjust

When users of congested roads may view tolls as unjust When users of congested roads may view tolls as unjust Amihai Glazer 1, Esko Niskanen 2 1 Department of Economics, University of California, Irvine, CA 92697, USA 2 STAResearch, Finland Abstract Though

More information

Essays on Incentives and Regulation

Essays on Incentives and Regulation Libera Università Internazionale degli Studi Sociali Guido Carli Facoltà di Economia Dottorato in Diritto ed Economia - XXII Ciclo Essays on Incentives and Regulation Extended abstract Tutor: Candidato:

More information

Chapter 11 Evaluating the Controversy between Free Trade and Protectionism

Chapter 11 Evaluating the Controversy between Free Trade and Protectionism This is Evaluating the Controversy between Free Trade and Protectionism, chapter 11 from the book Policy and Theory of International Economics (index.html) (v. 1.0). This book is licensed under a Creative

More information

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana Journal of Economics and Political Economy www.kspjournals.org Volume 3 June 2016 Issue 2 International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana By Isaac DADSON aa & Ryuta RAY KATO ab Abstract. This paper

More information

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty 1 Electoral Competition under Certainty We begin with models of electoral competition. This chapter explores electoral competition when voting behavior is deterministic; the following chapter considers

More information

The Restoration of Welfare Economics

The Restoration of Welfare Economics The Restoration of Welfare Economics By ANTHONY B ATKINSON* This paper argues that welfare economics should be restored to a prominent place on the agenda of economists, and should occupy a central role

More information

Governments in the advanced industrialized countries have progressively opened

Governments in the advanced industrialized countries have progressively opened Oatl.6613.03.pgs 3/5/03 8:38 AM Page 75 CHAPTER 3 THE DOMESTIC POLITICS OF TRADE POLICY Governments in the advanced industrialized countries have progressively opened their markets to imports through the

More information

Endogenous Politics and the Design of Trade Institutions*

Endogenous Politics and the Design of Trade Institutions* Endogenous Politics and the Design of Trade Institutions* Kristy Buzard March 3, 2018 Abstract While most of the literature on the design of trade agreements and trading institutions takes the political

More information

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000 ISSN 1045-6333 THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION Alon Klement Discussion Paper No. 273 1/2000 Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 The Center for Law, Economics, and Business

More information

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Economics 8413 International Trade James R. Markusen August 2004 Phone: 492-0748 Office: 216 Office hours: Monday, Wednesday, 1:30-3:00 e-mail: james.markusen@colorado.edu

More information

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership Panu Poutvaara 1 Harvard University, Department of Economics poutvaar@fas.harvard.edu Abstract In representative democracies, the development of party platforms

More information

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Protection for Free? The Political Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Rodney Ludema, Georgetown University Anna Maria Mayda, Georgetown University and CEPR Prachi Mishra, International Monetary Fund Tariff

More information

A MODEL OF INEQUALITY AND INTEREST GROUP POLITICS* Inderjit Kohli Department of Economics Santa Clara University

A MODEL OF INEQUALITY AND INTEREST GROUP POLITICS* Inderjit Kohli Department of Economics Santa Clara University A MODEL OF INEQUALITY AND INTEREST GROUP POLITICS* Inderjit Kohli Department of Economics Santa Clara University Nirvikar Singh Department of Economics University of California, Santa Cruz revised October

More information

COVER SHEET. EU institutional reform: Evidence on globalization and international cooperation. Phone: ; Secretary

COVER SHEET. EU institutional reform: Evidence on globalization and international cooperation. Phone: ; Secretary COVER SHEET EU institutional reform: Evidence on globalization and international cooperation Richard Baldwin (corresponding author) The Graduate Institute Cigale 2 1010 Lausanne Phone: 011 41 79 287 6708;

More information

Forced to Policy Extremes: Political Economy, Property Rights, and Not in My Backyard (NIMBY)

Forced to Policy Extremes: Political Economy, Property Rights, and Not in My Backyard (NIMBY) Forced to Policy Extremes: Political Economy, Property Rights, and Not in My Backyard (NIMBY) John Garen* Department of Economics Gatton College of Business and Economics University of Kentucky Lexington,

More information

Planning versus Free Choice in Scientific Research

Planning versus Free Choice in Scientific Research Planning versus Free Choice in Scientific Research Martin J. Beckmann a a Brown University and T U München Abstract The potential benefits of centrally planning the topics of scientific research and who

More information

Source: Piketty Saez. Share (in %), excluding capital gains. Figure 1: The top decile income share in the U.S., % 45% 40% 35% 30% 25%

Source: Piketty Saez. Share (in %), excluding capital gains. Figure 1: The top decile income share in the U.S., % 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% The Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson (HOS) model Extension of Ricardian model: trade is explained by comparative advantage but those are based on:du modèle ricardien: - differences of endowments in factors of

More information

Inequality and Endogenous Trade Policy Outcomes. Arvind Panagariya. Abstract

Inequality and Endogenous Trade Policy Outcomes. Arvind Panagariya. Abstract Inequality and Endogenous Trade Policy Outcomes Nuno Limão University of Maryland & CEPR Arvind Panagariya Columbia University Abstract An enduring puzzle in international economics is why trade interventions

More information

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent University of Connecticut DigitalCommons@UConn Economics Working Papers Department of Economics 6-1-2004 Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent Thomas J. Miceli

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 11217 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11217 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Public Choice Part IV: Dictatorship

Public Choice Part IV: Dictatorship ublic Choice art IV: Dictatorship Chair of Economic olicy University of Jena Carl-Zeiss-Str. 3 07743 / Jena iterature: Mueller (2003) pp. 406-424 onald Wintrobe (1998) The political economy of dictatorship

More information