Journal of Public Economics

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Journal of Public Economics"

Transcription

1 Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Public Economics journal homepage: Social identity and preferences over redistribution Esteban F. Klor a,b,, Moses Shayo a a Department of Economics, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Israel b Centre for Economic Policy Research, CEPR article info abstract Article history: Received 8 January 2009 Received in revised form 9 December 2009 Accepted 21 December 2009 Available online 6 January 2010 JEL classification: C92 D63 D72 Keywords: Social identity Social preferences Income redistribution Experimental economics We design an experiment to study the effects of social identity on preferences over redistribution. The experiment highlights the trade-off between social identity concerns and maximization of monetary payoffs. Subjects belonging to two distinct natural groups are randomly assigned gross incomes and vote over alternative redistributive tax regimes, where the regime is chosen by majority rule. We find that a significant subset of the subjects systematically deviate from monetary payoff maximization towards the tax rate that benefits their group when the monetary cost of doing so is not too high. These deviations cannot be explained by efficiency concerns, inequality aversion, reciprocity, social learning or conformity. Finally, we show that behavior in the lab helps explain the relationship between reported income and stated preferences over redistribution observed in survey data Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Corresponding author. addresses: eklor@mscc.huji.ac.il (E.F. Klor), mshayo@huji.ac.il (M. Shayo). URL: (E.F. Klor). What determines preferences over economic policies in democracies? Economic self-interest appears to be a rather weak predictor of voting behavior: poor people do not necessarily vote for extensive redistribution of income, and rich people sometimes support welfare programs from which they do not expect to benefit. While many factors have been suggested to explain voting behavior, researchers have long noted that social context seems to have a crucial effect (Lazarsfeld et al., 1948; Miller et al., 1991; Beck et al., 2002). This view is supported by observed differences in voting patterns and reported policy preferences across social groups such as class, race and religious affiliation, controlling for measures of economic self-interest (Evans, 2000; Luttmer, 2001; Glaeser and Ward, 2006). One important factor underlying these relationships may be social identity. However, the precise relationship between social identity and political choices has yet to be properly understood. The main difficulty is due to endogeneity of both economic and social variables. For example, people with certain characteristics may be more likely to earn higher incomes, associate with certain groups and vote in certain ways. This hampers attempts at uncovering the mechanisms behind groupbased voting and distinguishing them from other motives such as economic self-interest, altruism or inequality aversion. This paper employs an experimental approach to study the effect of social identification on voting over redistribution. We define social identification in terms of preferences. We say that an individual identifies with a group if she cares not only about her own selfinterest, but also about the status of that group. 1 This feature is a prominent implication of Social Identity Theory (Tajfel and Turner, 1979, 1986) and is motivated in the social psychology literature by observed behavior in Minimal Group experiments. 2 Caring about one's group is also consistent with behavior in strategic bargaining, prisoner's dilemma and public goods experiments. 3 Our experiment is designed to identify whether a subject's preferences over redistribution are affected by the payoffs of her 1 Hence, this paper abstracts from the effect of prototypical or prescribed behavior associated with a given identity, a second important feature of social identity stressed by Akerlof and Kranton (2000). 2 See Tajfel et al. (1971), Brewer (1979) and Bourhis and Gagnon (2001). In these experiments, individuals are assigned to one of two groups. Each individual then chooses an allocation of payoffs between two other randomly chosen subjects. The only information provided about these subjects is their group affiliation. Despite the very weak treatment, individuals systematically favor their ingroup member. 3 For public goods experiments see, e.g., Brewer and Kramer (1986), Orbell et al. (1988), Eckel and Grossman (2005) and Ruffle and Sosis (2006). For other strategic games see Bernhard et al. (2006), Charness et al. (2007), Chen and Li (2008), Fowler and Kam (2007), and Goette et al. (2006) /$ see front matter 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi: /j.jpubeco

2 270 E.F. Klor, M. Shayo / Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) ingroup members. In the main treatment, subjects are divided into two weak natural groups based on their field of studies. They are randomly assigned gross incomes, and are informed of their own income, the overall mean income and the mean income of each group. Subjects then vote anonymously over a redistributive scheme consisting of a linear tax and a lump sum transfer. Taxes do not introduce distortions; that is, overall payoffs are unaffected by the chosen tax scheme. The tax is chosen by majority rule and applied to the entire population in the two groups combined. This procedure is repeated 40 times, without feedback between rounds, and without any interaction between subjects. The income distributions are designed to allow us to classify deviations from self-interest into two distinct categories: inequality aversion and group identification. Specifically, inequality averse subjects exhibit a bias towards high redistribution regardless of their ingroup's income. In contrast, social identifiers exhibit a bias towards the tax rate that benefits their ingroup. Our main finding is that group identification significantly affects preferences over redistribution. Over a third of the subjects systematically deviate from monetary payoff maximization towards the tax rate that benefits the average member of their group. That is, they tend to vote for high levels of redistribution when their group is relatively poor even if they themselves are relatively rich. Further, and in contrast to the behavior expected under inequality aversion, these subjects also vote for low levels of redistribution when their group is relatively rich even if they themselves are relatively poor. This pattern of behavior is especially striking since all voting decisions are not observed by any of the other subjects, and groups' prototypical behavior is unknown as well. Although social identifiers are willing to forego monetary payoffs to support their group, their decision is affected by their economic self interest. That is, subjects respond systematically to the costs associated with supporting their ingroup. We find that, among the identifiers, the probability of supporting the ingroup tax rate decreases by 8 percentage points with a unit increase in the monetary cost to the subject divided by the average benefits to ingroup members. Remarkably, the probability of supporting one's group is higher when the social identifiers belong to a rich group than to a poor group. Beyond studies of voting over redistribution and studies of social identity, the present paper also relates to the growing literature on social preferences. This literature attempts to develop models that accurately and parsimoniously capture individuals' preferences over other individuals' payoffs. These models include, most prominently, inequality aversion (Fehr and Schmidt, 1999; Bolton and Ockenfels, 2000), competitive preferences (Boskin and Sheshinski, 1978; Bolton, 1991), various forms of altruism and Rawlsian preferences (Charness and Rabin, 2002), warm glow (Andreoni, 1989), and reciprocity (Rabin, 1993; Fehr and Gächter, 2000). 4 This paper attempts to expand our understanding of social preferences by disentangling the effect of group membership from the motives listed above in a political economy framework. The paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the theoretical framework implemented in the experiment. Section 3 describes our experimental design. The main results appear in Section 4. Section 5 relates the behavior observed in the lab to survey evidence on the relation between income and preferences over redistribution. Section 6 concludes. Appendix A contains the proof to the theoretical claim. The instructions of the experiment are available on the online appendix. 2. Theoretical framework The experiment is designed to isolate and examine one specific component of a general model of social identity in a political economy context. The general model studies both the endogenous determination of groups people end up identifying with, and the behavior of each individual given the groups he or she identifies with (Shayo, 2009). The present study focuses on this last component. Therefore, it does not examine equilibrium behavior. In our experiment, subjects are exogenously assigned to groups, leaving the endogenous determination of group identification out of the analysis. We define identification with a group to mean caring about the status of that group. In our setting, an important determinant of group status is monetary payoff. Thus, the status of a social group can be thought of in terms similar to standard definitions of individual status (Boskin and Sheshinski, 1978; Clark and Oswald, 1998). To be more precise, let N be a set of individuals, A i a set of available actions for each individual i N, and π i : i N A i R the individual's monetary payoff. In the present study we take the set of social groups as given. The status of a group j N is represented by a function S j ðaþ = S j ðπ jðaþ; π jðaþþ; ð2:1þ where π j is the mean monetary payoff of individuals that belong to group j (the ingroup) and j is the reference-group of group j, which in our two-group setting is simply the other group (the outgroup). We assume that the status of group j is strictly increasing in π j and is decreasing in π j. 5 Given Eq. (2.1) identification with a group implies caring about the monetary payoffs of the other ingroup members. Although the above definition of identification allows for a more general utility function, in what follows we assume that the utility function of an individual i that identifies with group j is additively separable in monetary payoffs and group status; namely, U i ðaþ = uðπ i ðaþþ + vðs j ðaþþ; ð2:2þ where u and v are both strictly increasing functions and u is weakly concave Implications for voting over redistribution We now embed the social identity framework outlined above into a standard political setting of income redistribution. Consider a population of individuals where each individual i has an exogenous pre-tax income of y i. The population is partitioned into two social groups, P and R. Assume that the mean income in group P, denoted y P, is lower than y R, the mean income in group R. Individual i's monetary payoff is just her after-tax income, which is composed of income net of taxes and a transfer payment financed by the tax revenues. That is, monetary payoffs are given by π i ðτþ = ð1 τþy i + τy; ð2:3þ where τ [0, 1] is the tax rate and y is the mean income. 6 We refer to individuals with income above the mean income as rich and to those with income below the mean income as poor. The tax rate is chosen directly by the individuals. Individuals vote over two proposed tax rates, τ h and τ l, with τ h Nτ l. The winner is decided by majority rule (ties are broken by an equal probability rule). 4 Recently, Fudenberg and Pathak (2009) have also shown that social preferences may explain punishment in public goods experiments better than an instrumental explanation. 5 We allow the status function to be constant in π j. In this case group j's status depends on the ingroup's mean absolute, rather than relative, payoff. 6 The profile of actions affect monetary payoffs only through the chosen tax rate. Hence we write π i directly as a function of τ.

3 E.F. Klor, M. Shayo / Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) their income is above the mean income. Furthermore, if the marginal utility of income decreases fast enough, then an individual identifying with the poor group votes for the high tax rate even if her income is very high (Fig. 1, panel (c)). That is, her marginal utility from an increase of the poor group's status is higher than her marginal utility from an increase in her own monetary payoffs. Note that preferences for a more equal distribution of net income or a Rawlsian concern for the poor may also generate support for a high tax rate among relatively rich individuals. However, such preferences cannot account for poor individuals' support for a low tax rate when redistribution does not generate deadweight losses. 3. Experimental design Fig. 1. Implications of identification for voting behavior. a. A monetary payoff maximizer. b. An individual that identifies with a rich group. c. An individual that identifies with a poor group. Thus an action for individual i is a vote from A i, where A i = fτ h ; τ l g for all i. The implications of social identification, depicted in Fig. 1, are as follows. Claim. Assume that individuals do not play weakly dominated strategies. Then: 1. An individual who maximizes her own monetary payoffs votes for the high tax rate if her income is below the mean income (y i by) ; and votes for the low tax rate if her income is above the mean income (y i Ny). 2. An individual who identifies with the rich group votes for the high tax rate if her income is below a threshold level ωby, and for the low tax rate if her income is above ω. 3. An individual who identifies with the poor group votes for the high tax rate if her income is below a threshold level ω Ny. If the utility function is sufficiently concave in the individual's monetary payoffs, there exists a threshold level ω (where ω Nω ) such that individuals with incomes between ω and ω vote for the low tax rate, whereas individuals with incomes above ω support the high tax rate. If u is not concave enough, all the individuals with income above ω support the low tax rate. Proof. See Appendix A. The basic intuition behind this claim is simple. Assuming that individuals do not play weakly dominated strategies, sheer economic interests should lead rich individuals to support a low tax rate and poor individuals to support a high tax rate (panel (a) in Fig. 1). This is, indeed, the standard approach of positive models of income redistribution. 7 Strategies become more subtle once we allow for group identification. According to the second part of the claim, an individual identifying with the relatively rich group is expected to vote for the low tax rate even if her income is below the mean, as long as the difference between her income and the mean income is not too high (panel (b) in Fig. 1). Similarly, the third part states that individuals identifying with the poor group may vote for the high tax rate even if 7 In the simplest version of this model individuals' income is exogenously determined (Hamada, 1973). Later analyses emphasize that individuals' income is a function of their ability and the chosen redistribution scheme (Romer, 1975; Roberts, 1977; Meltzer and Richard, 1981). The main message remains unchanged as individuals with higher ability prefer lower tax rates. The experiment is designed to examine whether, and to what extent, subjects are influenced by their group membership when choosing a redistribution scheme. In particular, to what extent are individuals willing to vote against their own economic interest in order to enhance their ingroup's standing, even when they do not have any information about the typical (or prescribed) behavior in their group, and when their action is never observed by other individuals. 8 The experiment was conducted at a computer lab at The Hebrew University of Jerusalem. The 180 subjects in this experiment were recruited from the pool of undergraduate students that belong to either the Faculty of Social Sciences or the Faculty of Humanities and had no previous experience in experiments related to redistribution. Each subject was seated at a cubicle in front of a computer screen and was given written instructions. An administrator read the instructions aloud before the experiment started to make sure the rules of the experiment were public information. Subjects were also asked several hypothetical questions at the end of the instructions to verify their comprehension of the procedure (the instructions and questions are available in an online appendix). A session lasted about an hour. Payoffs were denominated in Francs, which were converted to New Israeli Shekels (NIS) at the rate of 40 Francs per one NIS at the end of the session. Average earnings were equal to NIS 67 (slightly over $15 USD at the time) and were distributed privately and in cash. 9 Eighteen subjects participated in each session. We ran seven sessions using a group treatment and three sessions as a control treatment. Wefirst describe the group treatment. For each session we recruited nine subjects whose major field of study was from the Faculty of Social Sciences and nine subjects whose major was from the Faculty of Humanities. 10 Subjects were accordingly divided into two equal groups and were informed about the existence of groups, the size of the groups, and their group affiliation. Naturally, subjects maintained their group affiliation throughout the entire session See Akerlof and Kranton (2000) and Shayo (2009) for reviews on conformity to group norms; and Andreoni and Bernheim (2009) on social image motivation. 9 The hourly minimum wage in Israel at the time was slightly below NIS 20. Thus, subjects on average earned more than 3 times the minimum wage. 10 Students at The Hebrew University can choose to have a double major. For the group treatment we did not recruit any student who had one field of studies from the social sciences and the second field of studies from the humanities. 11 Subjects were not informed of the exact affiliation of other subjects. In fact, every effort was made to minimize the extent to which participants in a given session knew each other. We did not allow participants to sign up together for a specific session and, from the pool of over three thousands students who had signed up to participate in experiments, we allowed no more than two participants from the same year and major. Throughout the experiment we ensured anonymity and effectively isolated each subject in a cubicle to minimize any undesired interpersonal influence. The allocation of subjects to cubicles was independent of subjects' field of study. Communication between subjects was not allowed throughout the session. Subjects' anonymity was guaranteed so that neither the other subjects nor the researchers knew the ingroup of any particular subject or her action in a given round.

4 272 E.F. Klor, M. Shayo / Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) Each session consists of 40 rounds. At the beginning of each round a chance move determines each group's gross income distribution and then each subject's income for the current round. The possible distributions denoted x 1, x 2, z 1, z 2 are presented in Table 1. In half the rounds one group draws x 1 and the other group draws x 2, and in the other half they draw z 1 and z 2. The design is such that each group draws each of the four distributions ten times. The exact timing of the assignment is randomly determined. After a distribution is assigned to a group, the nine gross incomes are randomly assigned to the nine group members. Subjects are not informed of the exact distributions of gross income or of the way they are chosen. They only know that after their group's total gross income has been chosen, their individual gross income is randomly chosen, and varies between 10 and 150 Francs. At the beginning of each round each subject is informed of her own gross income, the mean gross income of each group and the overall mean gross income. After receiving this information subjects choose between two redistribution schemes. These schemes consist of a proportional tax rate on the income of every subject, with the resulting revenue distributed equally between all subjects. The two proposed tax rates are 20% and 40%. The implemented tax is decided by majority rule, with ties broken by an equal probability rule. After the elections all subjects are notified of the end of the round and of the beginning of a new round. We do not provide the subjects with any feedback whatsoever regarding the outcome of the current or of previous rounds. Subjects learn of the elections' outcomes and their resulting payoffs for each of the rounds only at the end of the experiment. Subjects were informed of this feature of the experimental design at the beginning of the session. After completing all the rounds and before learning the results of each round, each subject completes a questionnaire that includes basic demographics as well as questions on attitudes to redistribution taken from the General Social Survey (GSS) and the World Values Survey (WVS). The questionnaire also includes several questions to gauge the subject's identification with her ingroup. The questionnaire appears in Table 3. After each subject completes the questionnaire she is informed of her gross income, the chosen tax rate and her net income for every single round. The control treatment follows exactly the same recruiting and protocol except for the following differences. Subjects are randomly assigned to two groups of nine subjects each, but are not informed of the existence of groups. Thus, they do not know they were assigned to a group and only receive information on the overall average gross income at the beginning of each round. We omit from their questionnaire questions related to social identity. Table 1 Gross income distributions. x 1 x 2 z 1 z Group Mean Overall Mean Note: Treatments with a conflict between own and group monetary payoff appear in boldface. In the control treatment, subjects are only informed of their own gross income, the support of the overall distribution, and the overall mean gross income. In the group treatment, subjects are additionally informed of the groups' gross mean incomes Discussion The chosen design allows us to closely examine the effect of group membership on voting patterns. The main treatment divides the subjects into (very weak) natural groups instead of creating artificial ones to ensure that groups have some meaning outside of the laboratory. This does not imply that social identity effects are not to be expected under artificial groups. However, using artificial groups may arguably create a situation where all socially meaningful bases for decision making have been removed. This may render inferences regarding the effects of group membership in real elections rather tenuous. By using natural groups we seek to avoid such a situation. 12 Beyond comparing behavior in the group treatment to that in the absence of groups, we compare each subject's behavior when facing different environments. In every round of the group treatment, eight subjects face a conflict between monetary payoffs maximization and maximizing ingroup status: There are four poor subjects whose ingroup is rich, and four rich subjects whose ingroup is poor. We exploit these situations of conflict (shown in boldface in Table 1) to examine the existence of social identity effects. The construction of the first two distributions (x 1 and x 2 ) is guided by three major considerations. First, we want to examine the behavior of a subject with a given income level in situations when the relative mean income of her ingroup changes. This allows us to keep her own monetary incentives constant while changing only the incentives regarding group status. 13 Therefore, except for the highest and lowest income levels, all possible income levels appear in both distributions. Second, we want to distinguish deviations from monetary payoff maximization induced by social-identity from deviations induced by preferences for income equality (Loewenstein et al., 1989; Fehr and Schmidt, 1999; Bolton and Ockenfels, 2000). Although a preference for equality may drive a rich subject in a poor group to vote for a high tax rate, this type of preference cannot account for poor subjects in a rich group supporting a low tax rate. Finally, we want to observe the subjects' decisions under a sufficiently rich support of incomes to examine the trade-off between monetary payoff maximization and social-identity concerns. That is, even if subjects with incomes below the mean do vote for a low tax rate when they identify with the rich group, we want to quantify the amount of money that an individual is willing to forego in order to promote her ingroup's status. The income distributions z 1 and z 2 maintain the main attributes of the distributions x 1 and x 2, varying only the difference between the mean incomes of the two groups. As it turned out, there was no meaningful difference in behavior under the x and z distributions. Hence the next section reports results combining both distributions. A final comment relates to the information supplied to subjects. Recall that subjects do not receive any feedback until the end of the experiment. Hence, the subjects decide simultaneously on a set of forty votes. This suppresses repeated games effects (Costa-Gomes and Crawford, 2006), and is crucial for identifying behavior consistent with caring about ingroup status. For example, information on the outcomes of previous rounds may induce subjects to vote according to their narrow pecuniary interests if others did that in the past, due to conformity to the group. Finally, the design does not allow for collusive behavior or reciprocity effects. Therefore, the design provides 40 observations on each subject that allow us to focus on how a given individual responds to exogenous variations in her own and her ingroup's income Our analysis does not assume that the two groups are similar. Hence there is little gain from randomly assigning subjects to groups. 13 Note that by keeping the overall mean income constant we abstract from efficiency considerations. See Charness and Rabin (2002) for a study showing the effects of these considerations. 14 It should be noted that we find little evidence for the existence of order effects. Specifically, initial conditions (subject's income, and/or subject's ingroup income, in the first round) are not significantly associated with the subjects' subsequent behavior.

5 E.F. Klor, M. Shayo / Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) Fig. 2. Cumulative distribution of group votes out of conflict situations. Notes: There are 126 subjects in the group treatment and 54 subjects in the control treatment. The number of situations of conflict per subject varies from 10 to 26; its median is 18. Fig. 3. Propensity to vote for the high tax rate (all subjects in group treatment). Notes: For each subject we compute the proportion of votes for a high tax rate separately for each income and the subject's ingroup's relative income. The figures depict the mean across subjects at each income level. Capped ranges indicate 95% confidence intervals. Data are from the group treatment only. 4. Results This section presents the main experimental results. We first provide a glimpse of the subjects' behavior when facing a trade-off between social-identity concerns and their own monetary payoff. We then exploit the rich set of choices made by each subject to classify subjects into three categories: monetary payoff maximizers (MPM), social identifiers (SI), and inequality averse (IA). At the end of this section we closely examine the behavior of SIs vis-à-vis MPMs, and quantify the impact of monetary costs on the likelihood of supporting one's ingroup. Recall that a subject faces a situation of conflict whenever the relative income of the subject is opposed to the relative income of her ingroup. For each subject we compute the proportion of votes in support of her ingroup out of her total votes in situations of conflict. Of course, subjects in the control treatment are unaware of the existence of groups (and thus of the existence of a conflict). Nevertheless, we compute for these subjects the proportion of votes in support of their ingroup as a benchmark to which we can compare the behavior of subjects in the group treatment. Fig. 2 depicts the cumulative distribution of this proportion separately for the group and the control treatments. The figure highlights several important patterns in the data. Consider first the behavior in the control treatment. Almost 50% of subjects in this treatment never deviate from monetary payoff maximization in these situations. As for the remainder of the subjects, the vast majority of them deviate from monetary payoff maximization less than 20% of the time, and practically all subjects in this treatment deviate less than 50% of the time. Consider now the behavior in the group treatment. Again, a sizable amount of subjects never vote in support of their ingroup at the expense of their own monetary payoffs. This is not for lack of opportunities since, on average, each of these subjects faced slightly over 18 situations of conflict. The proportion of such subjects is, however, substantially lower than in the control treatment. 15 Another interesting pattern that emerges from the figure is the heterogeneity of the subjects' behavior in the group treatment. Once we focus on subjects that supported their group at least 15% of the 15 A Kolmogorov-Smirnov test confirms that the distributions are different across groups, with the control treatment containing smaller percentages of group votes than the group treatment (p-value=0.006). time (61 subjects), the distribution is close to uniform, with subjects spanning the entire range. This is reflected in the close to linear shape of the cumulative distribution function for the group treatment. Thirty one subjects supported their ingroup at least 50% of the time, and eleven subjects supported their ingroup at least 80% of the time. Fig. 3 takes a closer look at the group treatment, differentiating the subjects according to the relative income of their ingroup. The figure shows the mean proportion of votes for the high tax rate (with the associated 95% confidence intervals) by the subjects' gross income. 16 Fig. 3 suggests that group identification significantly affects subjects' voting behavior. Consider first the behavior of poor subjects (gross income less than 67 Francs). Taken together, poor subjects have a significantly lower propensity to support a high tax rate when their group is rich, compared to when it is poor. The difference is not only statistically significant for every income level but also of a sizeable magnitude, ranging from 19 to 27 percentage points. 17 That is, poor subjects show a striking willingness to sacrifice their own monetary payoffs to increase their ingroup's average payoffs. This behavior is inconsistent with inequality aversion. The behavior of subjects when their income is above the mean also indicates a possible concern for ingroup payoffs. That is, rich subjects in a rich group vote overwhelmingly for the low tax. When they belong to a poor group, however, the likelihood that rich subjects vote for the high tax increases significantly. 18 Looking at mean behavior is important, but it can mask substantial differences in individual responses to the economic environment. As 16 To construct this figure we compute, for each subject and each income level, the proportion of votes for a high tax across all the different rounds. We then compute the mean (and confidence interval) across subjects at that income level. This eliminates any effects due to possible correlations across repeated observations within a given subject. To avoid unnecessary clutter, Fig. 3 does not display subjects in the control treatment. Behavior in this treatment does not differ by group income. 17 Equality of means across group-incomes is rejected at the 1% level for all income levels from 20 to 110, except for 100 Francs where it is rejected at 2%. Mann-Whitney tests reject equality of behavior at 1% level for all income levels. 18 Note that rich individuals supporting a high tax rate when their ingroup is relatively poor may also be consistent with group specific inequality aversion. However, group specific inequality aversion cannot account for poor individuals supporting a low tax rate when their group is rich.

6 274 E.F. Klor, M. Shayo / Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) we have seen in Fig. 2, subjects display considerable heterogeneity in whether or not they support their group. Some of this heterogeneity may be a consequence of subjects' different preferences. Some of it, however, may be due to the different monetary costs of voting for one's ingroup. We explore these two possibilities in turn Classifying subjects into preference-types As suggested by the behavior in the control treatment, the deviations from monetary payoff maximization depicted in Fig. 2 may not necessarily reflect a preference for higher ingroup payoffs. These deviations may well stem from other factors such as plain errors or inequality aversion. We now propose an algorithm to classify each subject into one of three categories: monetary payoff maximizer, inequality averse or social identifier. Consider the following econometric model, applied separately to each subject: E½ðvote lowþ it jy it ; y jt Š = β 1 ðrichþ it + β 2 ðrich groupþ it + β 3 ðrich 4 rich groupþ it ð4:1þ where (vote low) it equals one if subject i voted for the low tax rate in round t and zero otherwise; (rich) it equals one if i's income in round t was above the mean income (y it Ny t ) and zero otherwise; and (rich group) it equals one if the mean income of i's group in round t was above the mean income (y jt Ny t ). Consider now the behavior of a subject that always chooses to maximize her monetary payoff. Assuming that subjects do not play weakly dominated strategies, an MPM votes for a low tax in round t if and only if y it Ny t, independently of her ingroup's relative income. Thus, for an MPM, E[(vote low) it y it, y jt ]=rich it. It follows that a subject can be classified as a monetary payoff maximizer whenever the conditions β 1 =1 and β 2 =β 3 =0 are jointly satisfied. Consider next a subject that has a preference for income equality. An inequality averse subject never supports the low tax rate when y i by,but may vote for the high tax rate when y i Ny.Thatis,foranIA,E[(vote low) it y it, y jt ]=β 1 rich it, where 1 β 1 N0 represents the probability that the subject votes for a high tax rate when y it Ny t. This gives us the parameter restrictions β 1 b1andβ 2 =β 3 =0. Note that, similar to an MPM, the decisions of an IA are independent of her group's relative income. Finally, a subject that identifies with group j always votes for the low tax rate whenever y i N y and y j N y (thus β 1 + β 2 + β 3 =1). Similarly, this subject never votes for the low tax rate when y i by and y j by. As established in the Claim above, an SI sometimes supports a low tax even when y i b y provided that y j Ny. The necessary conditions for a subject to be an SI in terms of model (4.1) are thus, β 1 b1, β 2 N0 and β 1 +β 2 +β 3 =1, where 1 β 1 N0 is the probability of voting for the high tax when the subject is rich and her group is poor; and β 2 is the probability of voting for the low tax when the subject is poor and her group is rich. This suggests that we can classify a subject as an MPM, an IA or an SI by estimating model (4.1) separately for each individual and then applying the following procedure: 1. We start with the null hypothesis that the subject is an MPM; that is, a subject is classified as an MPM whenever the joint hypothesis H 0 : β 1 =1 and β 2 =β 3 =0 cannot be rejected at the 95% confidence level. 2. If H 0 is rejected, we test the joint hypothesis H 1 : β 1 b1 and β 2 =β 3 =0. If this hypothesis is not rejected at the 95% confidence level we classify the subject as an IA. 3. If H 0 and H 1 are rejected, we test hypothesis H 2 : β 1 b1, β 2 N0 and β 3 =1 β 1 β 2. If this hypothesis is not rejected at the 95% confidence level we conclude that the subject is an SI. 4. If H 0, H 1 and H 2 are rejected we conclude that the subject cannot be classified in any of these three categories. We apply this procedure using OLS with robust standard errors. 19 The resulting classification of the subjects between the three categories is as follows (percentage of total appears in parenthesis). 20 Classification of subjects Group treatment Control treatment Monetary Payoff Maximizer (MPM) 70(55.6%) 43(79.6%) Inequality Averse (IA) 8(6.3%) 6(11.1%) Social Identifier (SI) 42(33.3%) 1(1.9%) None 6(4.8%) 4(7.4%) Total The resulting classification of subjects into three preference-types is striking for several reasons. In the control treatment, where subjects are asked to choose a tax policy knowing nothing about the characteristics of its beneficiaries, the overwhelming majority behave as MPMs. This is consistent with previous experimental results on voting over redistribution (Rutström and Williams, 2000; Esarey et al., 2007). Although several subjects do show a consistent concern for the welfare of the relatively poor, their proportion is rather low compared to related studies (Tyran and Sausgruber, 2006). Finally, one subject is classified as an SI even though she is unaware of the existence of groups. The picture is dramatically different in the group treatment. We observe a significant decrease in the proportion of MPMs. Remarkably, this proportion is very similar to that found in Andreoni and Miller (2002), who classified 47.2% of the subjects as selfish in a dictator game experiment. Subjects that are not MPM are often classified as efficiency maximizers or inequality averse (Charness and Rabin, 2002; Tyran and Sausgruber, 2006). In contrast to previous studies, our design allows subjects to deviate from both selfishness and inequality aversion, without introducing efficiency considerations. As a result the classification reveals a very low percentage of IAs and a significantly larger proportion of subjects that support their ingroup, even when this causes greater inequality. As expected, subjects' behavior varies significantly according to preference-type. Fig. 4 reproduces the analysis of Fig. 3 but differentiates the subjects according to their type. 21 The figure corroborates that the procedure used to classify subjects into different types, while somewhat arbitrary, delivers a sensible classification. For MPMs it makes virtually no difference whether their group is rich or poor: they almost always vote for the high tax rate when their income is below the mean, and for the low tax rate otherwise. 22 For SIs, on the contrary, the ingroup's income has a large effect. Whereas poor SIs in a poor group support the high tax rate over 90% of the time on average, poor SIs in a rich group support the high tax less than 30% of the time. 23 Similarly, rich SIs in a rich group vote overwhelmingly for the low tax, whereas rich SIs in a poor group are 19 We repeated the estimation of Eq. (4.1) using Feasible Generalized Least Squares (FGLS) to adjust for heteroskedasticity of the standard errors. The estimation based on FGLS produced the exact same classification of the subjects as the one based on robust standard errors. The results of these estimations and the subsequent classification of the subjects can be obtained from the authors upon request. 20 The sequence of the tests above is the most conservative in terms of the number of subjects classified as SIs. If we start out with H 2 as the null hypothesis, we obtain that 47 subjects (rather than 42) in the group treatment are classified as SIs. The difference is caused by 5 subjects for whom we cannot reject either H 0 or H 2 at the 95% confidence level. 21 Behavior of MPMs in the control treatment is basically the same as that of MPMs in the group treatment. 22 The average proportion of votes for the high tax among poor MPMs is above 97% when in the poor group and slightly below 95% when in the rich group. Mann- Whitney tests cannot reject equal behavior of MPMs in the rich group and in the poor group for any income at a significance level of 10 percent. 23 The proportion of poor SIs in a rich group voting for a low tax rate is highly statistically different from the proportion observed for poor SIs in a poor group for any income level. The confidence intervals do not overlap and equality of behavior is also rejected by Mann-Whitney tests with p-value b0.001 for any income level.

7 E.F. Klor, M. Shayo / Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) Table 2 Support for ingroup among social identifiers (random effects probit estimates). Variable (1) (2) (3) (Cost/Benefit) of Voting for Ingroup 0.301*** 0.751*** 0.592*** [0.021] [0.062] [0.091] (Cost/Benefit) *** 0.055*** [0.012] [0.016] Poor Ingroup 0.400*** [0.132] (Poor Ingroup)*(Cost/Benefit) 0.399*** [0.129] (Poor Ingroup)*(Cost/Benefit) *** [0.024] Constant 1.348*** 1.558*** 1.833*** [0.111] [0.116] [0.149] Log Likelihood Fig. 4. Propensity to vote for the high tax rate by preference type. Notes: For each subject we compute the proportion of votes for a high tax rate separately for each income and the subject's ingroup's relative income. The figures depict the mean across subjects at each income level. Capped ranges indicate 95% confidence intervals. Data are from the group treatment only. equally likely to vote for the low tax as for the high tax. 24 Notably, MPMs are not the only ones to show little concern for equality of payoffs. Rich SIs behave similarly when their group is rich Do social identifiers respond to monetary costs? In a situation of conflict the cost of supporting the tax that benefits the ingroup increases with the difference between the subject's income and the mean income. Although SIs sacrifice money for their group, Fig. 4 suggests that these subjects do take into account the associated cost. That is, an increase in the cost of supporting the ingroup seems to cause a decrease in the proportion of subjects that choose to do so. To analyze the trade-off between own monetary payoffs and group status among SIs we need to quantify the cost of voting for one's group. The subject's cost of supporting the tax that benefits her ingroup is zero if she is not in a situation of conflict. Consider now a situation of conflict. When the tax that benefits the subject's ingroup is adopted, her monetary loss is 0.2 y i y ; that is, the difference between the two tax rates times the difference between the subject's income and the mean income. When the subject is pivotal, by voting for the tax that benefits her ingroup she increases the probability that this tax is adopted by 50%. Thus, if p is the probability that the individual is pivotal, then the expected cost of siding with one's ingroup is: cost = p 40:540:2jy i yj; if in conflict 0; otherwise: ð4:2þ At the same time, the expected benefit to the average member of group j from the subject's siding with that group is: benefit = p40:540:2jy j yj ð4:3þ regardless of whether or not i is in a situation of conflict. The analysis below examines how the ratio of expected cost to expected benefit affects the behavior of SIs. A convenient feature of this cost/benefit measure is that the term measuring the probability of being pivotal cancels out. The cost/benefit measure ranges from 0 to 6.03 for subjects in the rich group and from 0 to 5.54 in the poor group. 24 The behavior of rich SIs in a poor group is highly statistically different from the behavior of rich SIs in a rich group for any given income level (Mann-Whitney, p-value b0.001). Notes: The dependent variable is the probability of voting in support of the ingroup. The sample consists only of subjects classified as Social Identifiers and has 1680 observations. Standard errors in parentheses. *** indicates statistically significant at 1% level. Table 2 presents the results of the estimation of a random effects probit model for SIs. 25 The dependent variable is whether or not subject i voted for the tax that benefits the average member of her ingroup. The main explanatory variable is the cost/benefit ratio of supporting that tax. The first column shows that overall, the effect of costs on the probability that SIs vote for their ingroup is negative, large and highly statistically significant. The implied probability of supporting the ingroup tax rate for the average subject decreases by 8 percentage points for an increase of one unit in the cost to benefit ratio of doing so. Column 2 adds to the model the square of the cost to benefit ratio to assess possible nonlinearities. The results suggest that indeed the subjects' propensity to support their ingroup is better represented by a decreasing convex function. Column 3 examines whether the subjects' behavior differs systematically when their ingroup is poor or rich. To that effect we introduce a dummy variable equal to one when the ingroup is poor, fully interacted with the cost variables. Interestingly, the subjects' behavior is qualitatively different in a rich or a poor ingroup. This difference is illustrated in Fig. 5. The figure presents the predicted probabilities (for SIs) of supporting the ingroup's tax rate as functions of the cost/benefit ratio, for rich and poor ingroups separately, based on the estimates in Column (3). Accordingly, the probability that SIs support their ingroup is significantly higher when that group is rich than when it is poor at any given cost/benefit ratio, even though supporting a rich group increases income inequality. We conjecture that this behavior could be a consequence of subjects attaching a higher status to rich groups, which tends to increase identification (Shayo, 2009). Finally, we observe that the probability of supporting the ingroup decreases almost linearly for rich groups but is a convex function of cost for poor groups. 5. Relating behavior in the lab to survey evidence This section examines whether the classification of subjects into preference types can enhance our understanding of the low correlation between preferences over redistributive policies and income observed in numerous surveys (Blinder and Krueger, 2004; Fong, 2001). Specifically, is it the case that the observed low correlation is due to the lumping together of individuals who care primarily about their own economic interests (MPMs) with individuals who care about other issues, for example the wellbeing of their 25 A linear probability model with fixed effects yields very similar results.

8 276 E.F. Klor, M. Shayo / Journal of Public Economics 94 (2010) Table 3 Subjects' characteristics by preference type. Fig. 5. Predicted probability of supporting the ingroup. Note: Predicted probabilities from the random effects probit model in Table 2, estimated for Social Identifiers. groups? We address this issue using answers to the questionnaire administered at the end of each session. Table 3 depicts mean responses to the questionnaire by subjects in both treatments and separately for SIs and MPMs in the group treatment. Consistent with other studies, we observe the well known economist effect whereby subjects studying economics and/or business administration are significantly more likely to exhibit selfish behavior (Marwell and Ames, 1981; Frank et al., 1993). We do not find a significant direct relationship between the subjects' revealed preferences and their reported income. On the other hand, social identifiers convey greater concern over income inequality and express a somewhat higher willingness to help the poor (though not statistically significant at conventional levels). The answers to the questions measuring social identification show that, as expected, SIs report a heightened awareness of their group membership and feel more emotionally involved with their group than MPMs. Interestingly, social identification as revealed by costly actions is, if anything, most closely correlated with answers to item 2: When someone criticizes [own faculty] it feels like a personal insult followed by item 4: I am proud to be a student in [own faculty] (Spearman's ρ=0.08 for both). It is not meaningfully associated with answers to item 5: I am similar to other students of [own faculty] (ρ= 0.009). This is consistent with Ellemers et al. (1999), who show that (costless) ingroup favoritism in allocation decisions is captured by questions on commitment to the group and not by mere self-categorization statements such as I am similar to other members of my group. This might be important for empirical work, where identification is often measured by questions of the self-categorization type. 26 Table 4 presents the correlation between self-reported income and self-reported preferences for redistribution for subjects in the group treatment. Income is measured on a 5 point scale from Rich, through Middle-Class to Poor as done in the World Values Survey (WVS). Since our subjects are university students, we concentrate on reported parental income when subjects were in high school, rather than on current income. 27 We use two questions that measure 26 Indeed, in recent work on charitable giving to Hurricane Katrina victims, Fong and Luttmer (2009) find an important difference between the effect of subjective racial identification (measured by the question How close do you feel to your ethnic or racial group? ) and that of merely belonging to a racial group. Fong and Luttmer (2009) show that the objective race of the respondent is not significantly related to giving to a particular racial group, but that subjective racial identification is associated with significantly higher giving to victims from one's racial group. 27 Given that most students work (if at all) in temporary jobs, this appears to be a better measure of the subjects' economic conditions. Results are qualitatively similar when using current income, but the correlations tend to be weaker. Group treatment Control SI MPM All treatment Percent Male Percent in Humanities Percent studying Economics and/or 0.19*** 0.471*** Business Parent income when in high school (1 = poor, 5 = rich) (0.751) (0.883) (0.813) (0.811) Income today (1 = poor, 5 = rich) (0.947) (0.826) (0.859) (0.726) Inequality 1 = Incomes in Israel should be 3.881* 4.543* more equal 10 = We need larger income (2.452) (2.250) (2.347) (2.023) differences as incentives for individual effort Helping the poor 1 = The government should do everything possible to improve (2.326) (2.131) (2.160) (2.034) the standard of living of all the poor in Israel 10 = improving the standard of living of the poor is not the government's responsibility: people should take care of themselves Social Identification (1 = strongly disagree, 7 = strongly agree) 1. Being a student of [own faculty] is an important part of my identity (1.761) (1.818) (1.791) 2. When someone criticizes [own faculty] it feels like a personal insult 3.167* (1.807) 2.629* (1.704) (1.771) 3. When I talk about students of [own faculty] I usually say we rather than they 4. I am proud to be a student in [own faculty] 5. I am similar to other students of [own faculty] 6. I would rather be a student of [other faculty] (2.170) (1.887) (1.984) (1.590) (1.467) (1.486) (1.774) (1.453) (1.565) (1.251) (1.366) (1.361) Number of Subjects Notes: Mean responses to questionnaire administered at the end of the experiment. Standard deviations are in parentheses. Inequality item adapted from the World Value Survey (WVS); Helping the poor item adapted from the General Social Survey; Social identification items 1 3 adapted from Roccas (2003); item 4 adapted from WVS, and items 5 6 adapted from Ellemers et al. (1999). * indicates difference between SI and MPM populations is statistically significant at 10% level by Mann-Whitney test. *** indicates difference between SI and MPM populations is statistically significant at 1% level by Mann-Whitney test. preferences for redistribution. The first, adapted from the WVS, asks whether inequality in Israel should be reduced or increased. The second, adapted from the General Social Survey (GSS), asks whether the government should improve the standard of living of the poor in Israel. We then compare the results obtained from our sample of university students to those obtained from representative samples of the Israeli and American populations, using the WVS and the GSS. Consider first the attitudes towards inequality, starting with Column 3. Overall, the correlation between the subjects' income and their stated preferences over inequality in our entire sample is That is, higher income is associated with more acceptance of inequality. This value is remarkably similar to the correlation of 0.12 observed in the 2001 Israeli WVS, which consists of a representative sample of 1,161 respondents. A similar correlation is also observed in the American WVS. Consider now the same correlation when differentiating subjects by their revealed preference types. Remarkably, among MPMs the correlation is quite high, consistent with the suggestions of standard models of political economy: richer people tend to oppose redistribution more strongly. However, for those

Are Dictators Averse to Inequality? *

Are Dictators Averse to Inequality? * Are Dictators Averse to Inequality? * Oleg Korenokª, Edward L. Millnerª, and Laura Razzoliniª June 2011 Abstract: We present the results of an experiment designed to identify more clearly the motivation

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 06-24 Pure Redistribution and the Provision of Public Goods Rupert Sausgruber Jean-Robert Tyran Studiestræde 6, DK-1455 Copenhagen K.,

More information

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies Dominik Duell and Justin Valasek Abstract While scholars and pundits alike have expressed concern regarding the increasingly tribal

More information

Ernst Fehr; Michael Näf und Klaus M. Schmidt: The Role of Equality and Equity in Social Preferences

Ernst Fehr; Michael Näf und Klaus M. Schmidt: The Role of Equality and Equity in Social Preferences Ernst Fehr; Michael Näf und Klaus M. Schmidt: The Role of Equality and Equity in Social Preferences Munich Discussion Paper No. 2005-19 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche

More information

Norms of Distributive Justice in Rural Malawi

Norms of Distributive Justice in Rural Malawi Norms of Distributive Justice in Rural Malawi Annika Mueller Harvard University amueller@fas.harvard.edu 2012 World Bank Conference on Equity Two-Part Study Research Questions Part 1 Which norms of distributive

More information

WHEN IS INEQUALITY FAIR? AN EXPERIMENT ON THE EFFECT OF PROCEDURAL JUSTICE AND AGENCY 1. Merve Akbaş Dan Ariely Sevgi Yüksel. July 24, 2014.

WHEN IS INEQUALITY FAIR? AN EXPERIMENT ON THE EFFECT OF PROCEDURAL JUSTICE AND AGENCY 1. Merve Akbaş Dan Ariely Sevgi Yüksel. July 24, 2014. WHEN IS INEQUALITY FAIR? AN EXPERIMENT ON THE EFFECT OF PROCEDURAL JUSTICE AND AGENCY 1 Merve Akbaş Dan Ariely Sevgi Yüksel July 24, 2014 Abstract We investigate how the perceived fairness of income distributions

More information

Party Hacks and True Believers: The Effect of Party Affiliation on Political Preferences

Party Hacks and True Believers: The Effect of Party Affiliation on Political Preferences Party Hacks and True Believers: The Effect of Party Affiliation on Political Preferences Eric D. Gould and Esteban F. Klor February 2017 ABSTRACT: This paper examines the effect of party affiliation on

More information

The welfare effects of public opinion polls

The welfare effects of public opinion polls Int J Game Theory (2007) 35:379 394 DOI 10.1007/s00182-006-0050-5 ORIGINAL PAPER The welfare effects of public opinion polls Esteban F. Klor Eyal Winter Revised: 15 May 2006 / Published online: 1 November

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK Alfonso Miranda a Yu Zhu b,* a Department of Quantitative Social Science, Institute of Education, University of London, UK. Email: A.Miranda@ioe.ac.uk.

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No THE ROLE OF EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY IN SOCIAL PREFERENCES. Ernst Fehr, Michael Naef and Klaus M.

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No THE ROLE OF EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY IN SOCIAL PREFERENCES. Ernst Fehr, Michael Naef and Klaus M. DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES No. 5368 THE ROLE OF EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY IN SOCIAL PREFERENCES Ernst Fehr, Michael Naef and Klaus M. Schmidt INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION ABCD www.cepr.org Available online at: www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/dp5368.asp

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Soc Choice Welf (018) 50:81 303 https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1084- ORIGINAL PAPER Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Margherita Negri

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Intergroup Inequality and the Breakdown of Prosociality

Intergroup Inequality and the Breakdown of Prosociality Intergroup Inequality and the Breakdown of Prosociality Rustam Romaniuc, Dimitri Dubois, Gregory J. DeAngelo, Bryan C. McCannon Abstract Each year about 60 million people flee their home country and seek

More information

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET Lurleen M. Walters International Agricultural Trade & Policy Center Food and Resource Economics Department P.O. Box 040, University

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7019 English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap Alfonso Miranda Yu Zhu November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

This article develops a model for analyzing social identity and applies it to the political economy

This article develops a model for analyzing social identity and applies it to the political economy American Political Science Review Vol. 103, No. 2 May 2009 A Model of Social Identity with an Application to Political Economy: Nation, Class, and Redistribution MOSES SHAYO The Hebrew University of Jerusalem

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY Over twenty years ago, Butler and Heckman (1977) raised the possibility

More information

Political Self-Serving Bias and Redistribution. Version 1.5

Political Self-Serving Bias and Redistribution. Version 1.5 Political Self-Serving Bias and Redistribution. Version 1.5 Bruno Deffains, Romain Espinosa, Christian Thöni February 12, 2015 Abstract In this article, we explore the impact of self-serving biases on

More information

Political Identity and Trust

Political Identity and Trust Political Identity and Trust Pablo Hernandez New York University AD Dylan Minor Northwestern University This version: October 2014 Abstract We explore how political identity affects trust. Using an incentivized

More information

Voting with hands and feet: the requirements for optimal group formation

Voting with hands and feet: the requirements for optimal group formation Exp Econ (2015) 18:522 541 DOI 10.1007/s10683-014-9418-8 ORIGINAL PAPER Voting with hands and feet: the requirements for optimal group formation Andrea Robbett Received: 13 September 2013 / Revised: 18

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

We argue that large elections may exhibit a moral bias (i.e., conditional on the distribution of

We argue that large elections may exhibit a moral bias (i.e., conditional on the distribution of American Political Science Review Vol. 03, No. 2 May 2009 doi:0.07/s0003055409090224 Moral Bias in Large Elections: Theory and Experimental Evidence TIMOTHY FEDDERSEN Northwestern University SEAN GAILMARD

More information

Immigration and Multiculturalism: Views from a Multicultural Prairie City

Immigration and Multiculturalism: Views from a Multicultural Prairie City Immigration and Multiculturalism: Views from a Multicultural Prairie City Paul Gingrich Department of Sociology and Social Studies University of Regina Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Canadian

More information

Small Employers, Large Employers and the Skill Premium

Small Employers, Large Employers and the Skill Premium Small Employers, Large Employers and the Skill Premium January 2016 Damir Stijepic Johannes Gutenberg University, Mainz Abstract I document the comovement of the skill premium with the differential employer

More information

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997) The identity of politicians is endogenized Typical approach: any citizen may enter electoral competition at a cost. There is no pre-commitment on the platforms, and winner implements his or her ideal policy.

More information

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

The Political Economy of Trade Policy The Political Economy of Trade Policy 1) Survey of early literature The Political Economy of Trade Policy Rodrik, D. (1995). Political Economy of Trade Policy, in Grossman, G. and K. Rogoff (eds.), Handbook

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

EDUCATION AND PRO-FAMILY ALTRUISTIC DISCRIMINATION AGAINST FOREIGNERS: FIVE-COUNTRY COMPARISONS

EDUCATION AND PRO-FAMILY ALTRUISTIC DISCRIMINATION AGAINST FOREIGNERS: FIVE-COUNTRY COMPARISONS Discussion Paper No. 1002 EDUCATION AND PRO-FAMILY ALTRUISTIC DISCRIMINATION AGAINST FOREIGNERS: FIVE-COUNTRY COMPARISONS Shusaku Sasaki Naoko Okuyama Masao Ogaki Fumio Ohtake May 2017 The Institute of

More information

Veto Power in Committees: An Experimental Study* John H. Kagel Department of Economics Ohio State University

Veto Power in Committees: An Experimental Study* John H. Kagel Department of Economics Ohio State University Power in Committees: An Experimental Study* John H. Kagel Department of Economics Ohio State University Hankyoung Sung Department of Economics Ohio State University Eyal Winter Department of Economics

More information

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Polit Behav (2013) 35:175 197 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9189-2 ORIGINAL PAPER On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Marc Meredith Yuval Salant Published online: 6 January 2012 Ó Springer

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Practice Questions for Exam #2 Fall 2007 Page 1 Practice Questions for Exam #2 1. Suppose that we have collected a stratified random sample of 1,000 Hispanic adults and 1,000 non-hispanic adults. These respondents are asked whether

More information

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Protection for Free? The Political Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions Rodney Ludema, Georgetown University Anna Maria Mayda, Georgetown University and CEPR Prachi Mishra, International Monetary Fund Tariff

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

What is the Nature and Social Norm within the Context of In-Group Favouritism?

What is the Nature and Social Norm within the Context of In-Group Favouritism? What is the Nature and Social Norm within the Context of In-Group Favouritism? Donna Harris, Benedikt Herrmann, and Andreas Kontoleon 1 December 2010 CWPE 1062 What is the Nature of Social Norm within

More information

On the Measurement and Validation of Political Ideology

On the Measurement and Validation of Political Ideology On the Measurement and Validation of Political Ideology Maite Laméris RESEARCH MASTER THESIS University of Groningen August 2015 Abstract We examine the behavioural validity of survey-measured left-right

More information

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000 Campaign Rhetoric: a model of reputation Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania March 9, 2000 Abstract We develop a model of infinitely

More information

Why are relatively poor people not more supportive of redistribution? Evidence from a Survey Experiment across 10 countries

Why are relatively poor people not more supportive of redistribution? Evidence from a Survey Experiment across 10 countries Why are relatively poor people not more supportive of redistribution? Evidence from a Survey Experiment across 10 countries Christopher Hoy 1 Franziska Mager 2 First Draft (November 2018) Abstract. Using

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

On the External Validity of Corruption Lab Experiments. The Economics of Corruption, October 2012

On the External Validity of Corruption Lab Experiments. The Economics of Corruption, October 2012 On the External Validity of Corruption Lab Experiments The Economics of Corruption, October 2012 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of the author; they do not necessarily reflect the views of

More information

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi Voter Participation with Collusive Parties David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi 1 Overview Woman who ran over husband for not voting pleads guilty USA Today April 21, 2015 classical political conflict model:

More information

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

Wisconsin Economic Scorecard RESEARCH PAPER> May 2012 Wisconsin Economic Scorecard Analysis: Determinants of Individual Opinion about the State Economy Joseph Cera Researcher Survey Center Manager The Wisconsin Economic Scorecard

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy

A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy Jean-Robert Tyran and Rupert Sausgruber November, 2002 Abstract We use a model of self-centered inequality aversion suggested by Fehr and

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

The determinants of voting in multilateral bargaining games

The determinants of voting in multilateral bargaining games J Econ Sci Assoc (2017) 3:26 43 DOI 10.1007/s40881-017-0038-x ORIGINAL PAPER The determinants of voting in multilateral bargaining games Guillaume R. Fréchette 1 Emanuel Vespa 2 Received: 24 February 2017

More information

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties Wenbin Chen, Matthew Keen San Francisco State University December 20, 2014 Abstract This article estimates

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983-2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri July 2014 Abstract This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India

More information

Employer Attitudes, the Marginal Employer and the Ethnic Wage Gap *

Employer Attitudes, the Marginal Employer and the Ethnic Wage Gap * [Preliminary first version] Employer Attitudes, the Marginal Employer and the Ethnic Wage Gap * by Magnus Carlsson Linnaeus University & Dan-Olof Rooth Linnaeus University, IZA and CReAM Abstract: This

More information

Social Insurance and Income Redistribution in a Laboratory Experiment

Social Insurance and Income Redistribution in a Laboratory Experiment Social Insurance and Income Redistribution in a Laboratory Experiment Justin Esarey, Tim Salmon, and Charles Barrilleaux March 5, 2010 Abstract Why do some voters support income redistribution while others

More information

Does opportunism pay off?

Does opportunism pay off? Does opportunism pay off? Linda G. Veiga, Francisco José Veiga Universidade do Minho and NIPE, Portugal Received 22 June 2006; received in revised form 1 December 2006; accepted 20 December 2006 Available

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis Author Saha, Shrabani, Gounder, Rukmani, Su, Jen-Je Published 2009 Journal Title Economics Letters

More information

The Governance Game. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND PAPER. Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia

The Governance Game. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND PAPER. Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia BACKGROUND PAPER GOVERNANCE and THE LAW The Governance Game Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia David Bulman, Luis F. Lopez-Calva, Ezequiel Molina, Abla Safir, and Siddharth Sharma The World Bank

More information

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete International Cooperation, Parties and Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete Jan Klingelhöfer RWTH Aachen University February 15, 2015 Abstract I combine a model of international cooperation with

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Andrzej Baranski & John H. Kagel

Andrzej Baranski & John H. Kagel Communication in legislative bargaining Andrzej Baranski & John H. Kagel Journal of the Economic Science Association A Companion Journal to Experimental Economics ISSN 2199-6776 Volume 1 Number 1 J Econ

More information

Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?*

Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?* Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?* Nauro F. Campos University of Newcastle, University of Michigan Davidson Institute, and CEPR E-mail: n.f.campos@ncl.ac.uk Francesco

More information

Corruption and Cooperation

Corruption and Cooperation University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper Series ISSN 1664-741 (print) ISSN 1664-75X (online) Working Paper No. 26 Corruption and Cooperation Justin Buffat and Julien Senn August 217 Corruption

More information

Do Liberals Play Nice? The Effects of Party and Political Ideology in Public Goods and Trust Games

Do Liberals Play Nice? The Effects of Party and Political Ideology in Public Goods and Trust Games Do Liberals Play Nice? The Effects of Party and Political Ideology in Public Goods and Trust Games By Lisa Anderson Department of Economics College of William and Mary Jennifer Mellor Department of Economics

More information

Resource Allocations and Disapproval Voting in Unequal Groups

Resource Allocations and Disapproval Voting in Unequal Groups Article Resource Allocations and Disapproval Voting in Unequal Groups Journal of Conflict Resolution 57(4) 627-652 ª The Author(s) 2012 Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalspermissions.nav DOI:

More information

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION Laura Marsiliani University of Durham laura.marsiliani@durham.ac.uk Thomas I. Renström University of Durham and CEPR t.i.renstrom@durham.ac.uk We analyze

More information

Has the War between the Rent Seekers Escalated?

Has the War between the Rent Seekers Escalated? Has the War between the Rent Seekers Escalated? Russell S. Sobel School of Business The Citadel 171 Moultrie Street Charleston, SC 29409 Russell.Sobel@citadel.edu Joshua C. Hall Department of Economics

More information

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts: 1966-2000 Abdurrahman Aydemir Family and Labour Studies Division Statistics Canada aydeabd@statcan.ca 613-951-3821 and Mikal Skuterud

More information

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution? Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution? Catalina Franco Abstract This paper estimates wage differentials between Latin American immigrant

More information

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W. A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) by Stratford Douglas* and W. Robert Reed Revised, 26 December 2013 * Stratford Douglas, Department

More information

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Jesse Richman Old Dominion University jrichman@odu.edu David C. Earnest Old Dominion University, and

More information

Telephone Survey. Contents *

Telephone Survey. Contents * Telephone Survey Contents * Tables... 2 Figures... 2 Introduction... 4 Survey Questionnaire... 4 Sampling Methods... 5 Study Population... 5 Sample Size... 6 Survey Procedures... 6 Data Analysis Method...

More information

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA Mahari Bailey, et al., : Plaintiffs : C.A. No. 10-5952 : v. : : City of Philadelphia, et al., : Defendants : PLAINTIFFS EIGHTH

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

COLORADO LOTTERY 2014 IMAGE STUDY

COLORADO LOTTERY 2014 IMAGE STUDY COLORADO LOTTERY 2014 IMAGE STUDY AUGUST 2014 Prepared By: 3220 S. Detroit Street Denver, Colorado 80210 303-296-8000 howellreserach@aol.com CONTENTS SUMMARY... 1 I. INTRODUCTION... 7 Research Objectives...

More information

MORALITY - evolutionary foundations and policy implications

MORALITY - evolutionary foundations and policy implications MORALITY - evolutionary foundations and policy implications Ingela Alger & Jörgen Weibull The State of Economics, The State of the World Conference 8-9 June 2016 at the World Bank 1 Introduction The discipline

More information

THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS

THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS WILLIAM ALAN BARTLEY and MARK A. COHEN+ Lott and Mustard [I9971 provide evidence that enactment of concealed handgun ( right-to-carty ) laws

More information

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration?

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration? Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration? David M. Frankel (Iowa State University) January 23, 24 Abstract Cutler, Glaeser, and Vigdor (JPE 1999) find evidence that the late 19th century

More information

Supplementary Materials for

Supplementary Materials for www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/science.aag2147/dc1 Supplementary Materials for How economic, humanitarian, and religious concerns shape European attitudes toward asylum seekers This PDF file includes

More information

8 5 Sampling Distributions

8 5 Sampling Distributions 8 5 Sampling Distributions Skills we've learned 8.1 Measures of Central Tendency mean, median, mode, variance, standard deviation, expected value, box and whisker plot, interquartile range, outlier 8.2

More information

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections by Stephen E. Haynes and Joe A. Stone September 20, 2004 Working Paper No. 91 Department of Economics, University of Oregon Abstract: Previous models of the

More information

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners? José Luis Groizard Universitat de les Illes Balears Ctra de Valldemossa km. 7,5 07122 Palma de Mallorca Spain

More information

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015.

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015. The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015 Abstract This paper explores the role of unionization on the wages of Hispanic

More information

The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform

The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform By SARAH BOHN, MATTHEW FREEDMAN, AND EMILY OWENS * October 2014 Abstract Changes in the treatment of individuals

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

The chicken or the egg: An experimental study of democracy survival, income, and inequality

The chicken or the egg: An experimental study of democracy survival, income, and inequality The chicken or the egg: An experimental study of democracy survival, income, and inequality Dmitry Ryvkin and Anastasia Semykina February 21, 2015 Preliminary draft: Please do not distribute Abstract Many

More information

ARE DISAGREEMENTS AMONG MALE AND FEMALE ECONOMISTS MARGINAL AT BEST?: A SURVEY OF AEA MEMBERS AND THEIR VIEWS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMIC POLICY

ARE DISAGREEMENTS AMONG MALE AND FEMALE ECONOMISTS MARGINAL AT BEST?: A SURVEY OF AEA MEMBERS AND THEIR VIEWS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMIC POLICY ARE DISAGREEMENTS AMONG MALE AND FEMALE ECONOMISTS MARGINAL AT BEST?: A SURVEY OF AEA MEMBERS AND THEIR VIEWS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMIC POLICY (forthcoming in Contemporary Economic Policy) ANN MARI MAY,

More information

Goods, Games, and Institutions : A Reply

Goods, Games, and Institutions : A Reply International Political Science Review (2002), Vol 23, No. 4, 402 410 Debate: Goods, Games, and Institutions Part 2 Goods, Games, and Institutions : A Reply VINOD K. AGGARWAL AND CÉDRIC DUPONT ABSTRACT.

More information

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002. Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002 Abstract We suggest an equilibrium concept for a strategic model with a large

More information

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT ABHIJIT SENGUPTA AND KUNAL SENGUPTA SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE UNIVERSITY OF SYDNEY SYDNEY, NSW 2006 AUSTRALIA Abstract.

More information

Experimental Evidence on Voting Rationality and Decision Framing

Experimental Evidence on Voting Rationality and Decision Framing Experimental Evidence on Voting Rationality and Decision Framing Li-Chen Hsu a* and Yusen ung b Abstract: Electorate sizes of 0, 40, and 70 subjects are used to test the paradox of voter turnout. Payoff

More information

The Link between Partisan Voting and Polarized Social Identity

The Link between Partisan Voting and Polarized Social Identity The Link between Partisan Voting and Polarized Social Identity Dominik Duell and Justin Mattias Valasek Word count: 949 Tuesday 30 th May, 2017 Abstract While scholars and pundits alike have pointed to

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Jan Theodor Schikora: Bringing good and bad Whistle-blowers to the Lab

Jan Theodor Schikora: Bringing good and bad Whistle-blowers to the Lab Jan Theodor Schikora: Bringing good and bad Whistle-blowers to the Lab Munich Discussion Paper No. 2011-4 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät Ludwig-Maximilians-Universität

More information

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS Poli 300 Handout B N. R. Miller DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-2004 The original SETUPS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN IDENTIAL ELECTIONS 1972-1992

More information

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA TITLE: SOCIAL NETWORKS AND THE LABOUR MARKET OUTCOMES OF RURAL TO URBAN MIGRANTS IN CHINA AUTHORS: CORRADO GIULIETTI, MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS,

More information

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

Supplementary/Online Appendix for: Supplementary/Online Appendix for: Relative Policy Support and Coincidental Representation Perspectives on Politics Peter K. Enns peterenns@cornell.edu Contents Appendix 1 Correlated Measurement Error

More information

A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy

A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy Jean-Robert Tyran and Rupert Sausgruber December 2002 Discussion Paper no. 2002-30 Department of Economics University of St. Gallen Editor:

More information

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France No. 57 February 218 The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France Clément Malgouyres External Trade and Structural Policies Research Division This Rue

More information