ASSESSMENT OF CORRUPTION IN THE HEALTH CARE SECTOR IN SERBIA

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "ASSESSMENT OF CORRUPTION IN THE HEALTH CARE SECTOR IN SERBIA"

Transcription

1 ASSESSMENT OF CORRUPTION IN THE HEALTH CARE SECTOR IN SERBIA Background Document, March 2015

2 Southeast Europe Leadership for Development and Integrity (SELDI) is an anti-corruption and good governance coalition of likeminded CSOs in Southeast Europe, involving partners from nine participating countries (Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia Kosovo, Macedonia, Montenegro, Serbia and Turkey). In the present document the Network`s partner CLDS engaged the expert who analysed the problem of the Corruption in the Health Care Sector in general with an overview of the current situation in Serbia. The text was written by Dr. Danica Popović, Professor of Economics, Faculty of Economics, University of Belgrade on demand of CLDS, Serbia - partner of the South-East Europe Leadership for Development and Integrity (SELDI). This document has been produced with the financial assistance of the European Union. The contents of this document are the sole responsibility of the SELDI initiative and can in no way be taken to reflect the views of the European Union. 2

3 Contents 1. Introduction Demand for Corruption in Health Care Supply of Corruption in Health Care Mechanisms of Corruption in Health Care Factors of Corruption in Health Care Consequences of Corruption in Health Care Elements of an Anti-Corruption Strategy in Health Care Some Estimates of the Health Care Sector Corruption in Serbia

4 1. Introduction Many people are ready to more strongly condemn corruption in health care from the moral standpoint than corruption in some other parts of the public administration. A corrupt customs officer or tax inspector can often be met with more understanding by the general public than a corrupt general practitioner or surgeon. Two reasons can be cited as explanations for such moral attitude toward corruption in health care. First, corruption in health care is, completely erroneously, associated exclusively with the doctor-patient relationship, and then this relationship is, also erroneously, reduced to extortion by doctors, which gives rise to non-collusive corruption a patient pays a bribe to a doctor to prompt him to fulfil his duty, i.e., his professional obligation. 1 Second, it is implicitly assumed that a patient is in a vulnerable position, since the price elasticity of demand for health services is low, and doctors can use this, even in non-collusive corruption, to extort large amounts of bribes. The list of the reasons for such harsh moral condemnation by the general public could perhaps be enlarged by another one, which touches upon personal interests of almost all individuals. It is related to the fact that everybody, regardless of their profession, job, social and/or material status, can imagine themselves on the side of demand for medical services, i.e., health services and, consequently, as potential victims of corruption in the health sector as well. 2 Corruption in health care is, however, a far more complex, that is stratified phenomenon. First and foremost, corruption in the case of health services delivery, i.e., corruption which occurs within the doctor-patient relationship constitutes just one form of corruption in the health sector. Other forms of corruption in the health sector are related to large-scale public procurement transactions that are inevitable in this sector, at least to the extent to which the public, i.e., government sector provides health services. Corruption in public procurement in health care can take place in investment, be it the constructing and equipping new health care facilities, or just procurement of new capital equipment. Furthermore, this form of corruption can occur in procurement of medical supplies, starting with those very valuable and specific, such as medicines, all the way to other kinds of medical or diverse non-medical supplies, such as meals for hospitals. Finally, corruption can also occur in outsourcing of certain services, such as laboratory tests, to commercial organizations. Pursuant to all the above, it is obvious that the case of corruption in which corrupt exchange takes place between a doctor and a patient constitutes just one, specific case of corruption 1 Throughout this report, only the professional duty of doctors, i.e., medical staff, will be looked at, the one that arises from the contractual relationship they have entered into. Their moral obligation to provide a relevant service is not the subject of this discussion. 2 Bearing this in mind, that is, bearing in mind the low price elasticity of demand for health services, it is clear that the personal interest of citizens can occupy a crucial position in the creation of a widespread moral condemnation of corruption in health care. 4

5 in health care. In this specific case of corruption, too, its different types are present. As a result of the specific features of health care and its financing, which will be discussed in greater detail a bit later, in the case of the relationship between a patient and a doctor, i.e., other medical staff, despite the fact that the basic general definition of corruption (Chapter III) is fulfilled, the word corruption is not used; instead euphemisms are used in the literature, such as: informal payment, unofficial payment or payments received without any basis in official rules. Irrespective of the specific features to be discussed, avoiding the use of the term corruption can be an indicator that professionals in the field of health care have not yet accepted the fact that the problem of corruption exists, i.e., that they do not want to discuss it openly. Irrespective of the plausibility of the previous position, several authors have offered definitions of corruption in health care which are focused exclusively on the relationship between a patient and a doctor, i.e., medical staff, and they are related to the character of payments, i.e., of the cash flow from a patient to a doctor. Therefore, it is argued that corruption in health care exists if there are informal and/or unofficial payments, that is, payments which are not made official by health policy. A bit more comprehensive is definition that corruption in health care constitutes payments to individuals or institutions in cash or in kind, which are outside the official payment system, referring to the services whose costs should be covered (without direct payments) by the general health insurance system. The above definition of corruption in health care, which is limited to corruption in the relationship between a patient and a doctor, i.e., other medical staff, points to a very important element, i.e., factor of corruption of that type the system of state (compulsory) health insurance. Specifically, in many countries there is a monopoly of this system, i.e., only this system provides funding for the functioning of the health care system, which boils down to state health institutions, which are forbidden to operate on the market for health services; instead they are supposed to cover all their costs from the cash flow which comes from the state health insurance fund. Within such a financing framework for the health care system, many countries are faced with the essential problem of limited, i.e., relatively low revenues of the state health insurance fund (determined by the contribution rate and the total size of the base, in most of the cases the gross wage to which they are applied), while all insurees, irrespective of the level of the premium they are paying, are offered complete, best possible health care. 3 In other words, while supply of health services is limited, demand for these services is practically unlimited. This is all the more so because in the case of such, compulsory, universal and across-the-board insurance moral hazard of an increase in demand for services provided by the system of insurance is strong. Simply, an 3 Sometimes complete, best possible (that includes all the services) health care is offered to all citizens of a country, irrespective of whether they are insurees, i.e., irrespective of whether they are paying contributions for compulsory health insurance. 5

6 insuree does not bear any additional (marginal, i.e., incremental) costs, and therefore he has an incentive to request an additional medical service, i.e., an additional service of the health care system. Precisely the mentioned disproportion, which exists in many countries, generates the difference between demand and supply of health services, i.e., a gap between demand and supply that would be based on legal revenues (from compulsory health insurance) of providers of health services. In other words, if supply of health services was increased to match demand, i.e., in order to strike a balance, part of the costs of provision of health services would remain uncovered, for which reason no medical service provider has an incentive to increase the supply of these services. This has clarified the framework in which corruption in the health sector, i.e., corruption in the patient-doctor relationship, actually takes place. This clarification helps to better understand the difference among three specific types of corruption in the health sector in which a patient appears on the demand side. It could be said that the first type of that corruption is the one which ensures the coverage of costs of the provision of health services. This type of corruption occurs in the situation which has just been described, in which, due to limited funds for covering the costs, generated by the state system of compulsory health insurance, doctors, i.e., all providers of health services, have an incentive to cut back supply, i.e., to set the level of supply so as to balance the marginal revenue (from the state health insurance fund) and marginal costs, that is, costs of providing an additional service. 4 Precisely such rational behaviour of doctors and other medical staff opens up a gap between demand and supply of health services, i.e., a situation in which certain part of demand is not met. That creates incentives to patients to generate incentives, through informal payments, i.e., bribes, to doctors and other medical staff to increase the volume of supply and to establish, in this manner, equilibrium on the market for health services. 5 More specifically, payments are not necessarily in cash, they can also be in kind medical supplies which the provider of medical services lacks. Such supplies are used for a specified purpose, exclusively for the provision of medical services to the one who has secured them. It is very important to note that this form of corruption aimed at covering costs includes all the costs of providing health care, including the opportunity costs of labour of the medical staff, primarily doctors. Specifically, the salaries of doctors in the state sector of health services which are below their opportunity costs also constitute, although that is very often 4 The cut in the level of supply applies to both the level in the narrow sense of the word, and to the composition of health services, since such services are not homogeneous. 5 Pursuant to the mentioned result, this type of corruption in health care is sometime called sensible corruption. Irrespective of whether this term is suitable, it is certain that this type of corruption can result in a Pareto improvement, i.e., in a simultaneous increase in the welfare of both the doctor and the patient. 6

7 overlooked, uncovered costs of resources. 6 Therefore, all those payments which end up with doctors and serve to cover the opportunity costs of their labour, belong to this type of corruption. The next category of corruption in health care is a kind of extortion by doctors, namely those who are in a monopolistic position. The mechanism is similar to the price setting process in a monopoly. Considering the heterogeneity of health services, as well as the heterogeneity of supply of those services, specialists in certain tasks appear on the market, who provide a very high quality of that specialist service. In other words, there is no competition in the case of, for example, top cardio surgeon in a clinic, i.e., hospital. The key question is whether, and in which manner, that cardio surgeon will charge for his services. If there is a system that will enable him to balance his marginal income and marginal costs within permitted, i.e., legal cash flows, corruption will not occur there will be no need for it. However, if the health care financing system does not make such balancing possible, there is an incentive for corruption, both on the supply side (the doctor-specialist who is asking for a bribe), and on the demand side, since the marginal benefit of the patient is higher than, or equal in the marginal case, the amount of the bribe that should be paid. Of course, it is rather difficult to assess in operational terms where one type of corruption in health care stops and another one begins. What are the real opportunity costs of the labour of a top cardio surgeon? Is it possible that the rent which he is possibly appropriating is not rent in the true sense of the word, but returns on the investment in his own specific human capital, i.e., professional advancement? Unambiguous answers should be given to these questions before a certain type of corruption in health care (in the doctor-patient relationship) is declared to be extortion. The third type of corruption in health care is the one which implies unofficial payments for those services, medical or supporting (non-medical), which are not, at least not explicitly, covered by compulsory state health insurance, but their delivery is not regulated by separate regulations, i.e., it cannot be financed by legal payments. The problem is in the fact that official regulation of payments is too rigid to cover such possibilities. The patient then becomes a corruptor in order to ensure these services for himself. In the case of additional medical services there is considerable asymmetry of information, i.e., the patient does not know whether these services (for example, additional tests) are really necessary from the standpoint of treatment, or they constitute a form of extortion. In the case of non-medical services (better hospital accommodation, such as a single room or a room with airconditioning, better meals, etc.) there is no asymmetry of information, patients know what they are paying for, they would be willing to pay for that in any event, and they resort to 6 Opportunity costs of doctors include the possibility of their earnings outside the state sector of health care provision (private medical practice), or outside the health sector in the narrow sense, such as commercial transactions of selling medicines and/or medical equipment, for example. 7

8 corruption because a rigid system of legal, i.e., official payments does not allow them to do so. Although this taxonomy of corruption in health care, which occurs in the relationships between patients and doctors, i.e., medical staff, is very clear and consistent in analytical terms, in operational terms it is very difficult to precisely categorize individual cases of corruption under all these criteria. For example, it is very difficult to establish whether a particular case involves extortion in terms of rent seeking or coverage of opportunity costs of doctors labour. Of course, as in all other cases, corruption in health care can be categorized into corruption through which regulations are implemented (extortion, i.e., non-collusive corruption) and rule-breaking corruption (collusive corruption). In the case of the patient, non-collusive corruption means that he bribes the doctor or other medical staff in order to receive his entitlement, i.e., the services envisaged by compulsory or some other health insurance whose beneficiary he is. The problem arises because in a large number of cases medical and other services to which an insuree is entitled are not precisely specified. For example, although an insuree is entitled to a specialist examination, the time limit in which that specialist examination is to be performed has not been specified. Therefore, it is sometimes difficult to determine whether there is extortion or not, or collusive corruption, which means that the patient, i.e., insuree will receive a medical or some other service to which he is not entitled. Corruption in the case of public procurement in health care is mostly collusive corruption, hence, the kind of corruption which breaks, i.e., circumvents the basic rules of public procurement, essentially in the same manner in which corruption occurs in other cases of public procurement. The core motive is avoiding competition in the broadest sense of the word, i.e., appropriation of rents generated by avoiding corruption. The key prerequisite for that is the existence of collusion between someone from among those appearing on the supply side in the case of public procurement and health officials who appear on the demand side. On top of that, other forms of abuse also occur in public procurement: it does not have to be corruption in the narrow sense of the word, but also cartel collusion of competitors through which competition is evaded in public procurement. Such collusion, in which officials on the side of demand for services that are purchase through public procurement are not involved in any way, gives rise to economic inefficiency and income redistribution in favour of those who are involved in collusion, although there is no corruption the same effects that are generated in the case of collusive corruption. 8

9 2. Demand for Corruption in Health Care When demand for corruption in health care by patients is discussed, it is necessary to note the characteristics of demand for health services. Specifically, demand for corruption in health care by patients is derived demand it derives from demand for health services. Moreover, demand for medical services is per se derived demand patients, i.e., individuals do not require health care, but health. Specificities of health as a good determine the specificities of demand for health care. Essentially, there are two methods of paying for health services. One is health insurance, compulsory or voluntary, and the insuree acquires the right, by regularly paying the premium, to have full costs of delivery of health services paid by an insurance organization. 7 Naturally, as with any other insurance scheme, the premium is paid regardless of whether services of health insurance are delivered. The second is direct payment for health services, upon the delivery of a particular service. In the case of direct payments, low price elasticity of demand for health services can be noticed. Specifically, since there is essentially no substitute for health services, there are no substitution effects, but only the income effect. The mentioned low price elasticity of demand for health services, in principle, constitutes fertile soil for extortion by doctors or other medical staff. It is noteworthy, from the standpoint of demand for corruption by patients, to also examine the case of gifts. Specifically, in many countries, a gift to the doctor at the end of the treatment is part of the cultural tradition. Of course, if it is a gift, no corruption is involved. In order to identify any gift (be it monetary or non-monetary, a gift in cash is still a gift) as gift, the requirement is that there is no explicit exchange. In the case of the health sector, that can boil down to an answer to the question whether the transfer was made before or after the delivery of medical services. In principle, if the transfer was made after the provision of health services, it can be said that it is a gift. This criterion for differentiating corruption in health care from a gift faces two major operational problems. First, it is possible to imagine (although it is not very likely) a corruption transaction in which a corrupt service is delivered first (e.g. the provision of health services ahead of one s turn), and only then a bribe for such service is paid, all the more so because it has the form of a gift. Second, in many cases, treatment, the provision of health services is continuous, i.e., delivered in stages, so a gift at the end of one stage can constitute corruption related to the next stage of treatment. In addition to the patient, a very large number of various economic agents can appear on the side of demand for corruption in health care in public procurement. On the one hand, they include economic agents specialized in production of and/or trade in medical equipment, medicines, as well as specific non-medical equipment (hospital beds, for example). On the 7 This payment method is sometimes combined with the so-called co-payment, that is, with an outlay through which a patient co-finances full costs with an insurance organization. 9

10 other hand, they include all other economic agents that produce or sell everything else, not belonging to anything associated in any sort of specialization, but is the subject of public procurement. The group of such economic agents comprises everybody from contractors in the construction industry to manufacturers of food and hygiene items. Their motive is very simple appropriation, i.e., maximization of rents they are appropriating. That is achieved through subverting, i.e., eliminating competition in public procurement. 3. Supply of Corruption in Health Care In relation to the patient, supply of corruption in health care comes from the doctor and other medical staff. Already in defining corruption in health care, i.e., in discussing its different forms, it was mentioned that one of the main mechanisms is the one in which corruption, in the absence of legal possibilities for payment, serves to cover costs of health services, since these costs are not covered by the payments from the state fund of compulsory health insurance. Still, a question may be raised of why doctors accept to work in such circumstances where their official salary is lower than their opportunity costs, which practically forces them to, maybe, through corruption cover the difference between the official salary and opportunity costs. Moreover, in such circumstances, all those doctors who do not want to be involved in corruption are receiving salaries that are lower than their opportunity costs. This certainly has to do with the specific features of medical profession that reduce the mobility of this kind of labour force. If the mobility of medical doctors within the ambit of their profession, the possibilities for such mobility are often relatively limited, since the dominant state health care sector in many countries sets the terms on the labor market for doctors. In such circumstances, the private sector is relatively small and limited to some specific segments of health care, so it is no real professional alternative for a vast majority of doctors. 8 As already mentioned, although a distinction can be drawn in analytical terms between corruption which is aimed at covering opportunity costs and corruption which constitutes extortion in the sense of abuse of the monopolistic position, in reality it is very difficult to differentiate between these two kinds in operational terms. The information derived from this differentiation is that on the motive of the corrupted: is the motive to cover opportunity costs or to appropriate rents. However, even if it has been definitely determined that the motive was rent appropriation, there is a question whether these rents are returns on investment in one s own human capital as a result of which some top medical doctorsspecialists are in a monopolistic position. In operational terms, this differentiation would make sense if the mechanisms for combating one or the other type of corruption in health care were different. It will turn out, however (the last section of this chapter), that the 8 The domination of the state health care system means that all the elite health institutions are state-owned, that is, that moving to the private sector for a doctor means losing prestige in the medical profession. 10

11 mechanisms are almost identical, for which reason making this distinction is not particularly useful even in operational terms. A specific supply of corruption in health care, i.e., abuse of office by doctors, is reflected in the use of the posts held in a public institution providing health services for pursuing patients to come to their own private offices. In other words, if a service is rendered in the public sector, since the costs of its provision are covered, at least nominally by revenues from the compulsory health insurance fund, it is provided in the private sector and paid by direct payments of the patient. On the supply side of corruption in health care in public procurement all those health officials can appear who are taking operational decisions on the drafting of public procurement notices, the conduct of procedures and on the best bidder, that is, the one who will be awarded a contract on a particular deal. Those officials, no matter how high up they are, are just agents, who are much better informed than the principal, and therefore they can abuse their position with a view to gaining material benefits. They can do that at any stage of public procurement and all that in collusion with the corruptor, that is, the economic agent who is willing, for the purpose of acquiring rents, to enter into collusion i.e., a corrupt deal with officials in health institutions. The main motive of those officials, of course, is a bribe which is appropriated as part of the kickback operation. In that respect, supply of corruption from health officials in the case of public procurement is not much different from public procurement in any other field. 4. Mechanisms of Corruption in Health Care In principle, corrupt deals in health care are identical to corrupt deals in other sectors. In health care, too, corruption is a contract which two parties should enter into and they should make sure that the other party will meet his contractual obligations, aware of the fact that, due to the invalidity of such contract, they cannot turn to the judiciary if the obligations are not fulfilled. In other words, corrupt partners in health care are, in principle, faced with considerable transaction costs. Yet, a question is raised of the level of these transaction costs relative to some other sectors, i.e., which kind of transaction costs is the most significant in the case of corruption in health care. It is necessary to differentiate here between corruption in which the patient appears as the corruptor and corruption in the case of public procurement in health care. In the case of corruption which occurs in the patient-doctor relationship, transaction costs are relatively low. First, there is no major problem in finding an appropriate corrupt partner. The patient and the doctor get in touch through regular channels, i.e., a relationship between them is established in a completely regular manner, and this relationship is the relationship of 11

12 mutual trust, which is, for understandable and absolutely legitimate reasons, closed to the public. In other words, if a corrupt deal is to be struck, a regular doctor-patient relationship makes a perfect screen. The patient enters the doctor s office alone and stays alone with the doctor a completely normal situation in health care and there is absolutely no reason why something like that would arouse suspicion. Within such a safe framework, it is relatively easy to find an appropriate partner and start negotiating a corrupt contract. Both interested parties have an incentive to truthfully present their demands. The only danger to the doctor who is negotiating a corrupt deal is that the patient is a stoolpigeon, i.e., that he deliberately initiates a conversation about corruption so that the doctor can express his intentions, perhaps receive money and thus provide evidence for prosecution, i.e., a possible conviction. Still, doctors who are prone to corruption are relatively good in observing the general climate in society, i.e., in estimating the probability of a provocation of this kind. The next stage of corruption is the one at which contractual obligations should be met. The patient - corruptor is supposed to pay the agreed amount of the bribe, while the corrupt doctor is supposed to deliver the agreed service. It is customary to pay in advance for the services of this kind in full, before their delivery. Such arrangement prevents any opportunistic behaviour on the part of the patient. In principle, such an arrangement opens up the possibilities for opportunistic behaviour by the corrupt doctor, but there are no strong incentives for that. Specifically, the corrupt doctor who has already received a bribe has an incentive to deliver the agreed service for at least two reasons. First, the probability is very high, if it is a case of extortion, that he has to provide that service in any event, regardless of whether he has received an additional payment or not. A failure to provide services can arouse suspicion that there is corruption, maybe not immediately, but it would signal that something irregular is going on. Second, it is not in the interest of the corrupt doctor to gain a reputation of a doctor who is taking bribes, and then fail to provide agreed services. Such reputation will discourage patients, potential corruptors, thus reducing the amount of expected future cash flows. It is a question whether the patient has strong incentives to report extortion by the doctor. In all likelihood, those incentives are weak. In such a case, the patient is not very likely to improve his chances to receive an adequate medical service, while gaining practically nothing in return. Consequently, incentives to the patient to report the corrupt practice of the doctor are fairly weak. After the provision of the agreed medical services, such incentives practically disappear completely. Pursuant to all the above, transaction costs of corruption in the case of corrupt deals between patients, on the one hand, and doctors, i.e., other medical staff, on the other, are not high, i.e., they are lower than transaction costs of corruption in some other fields. It should be added here that the transaction costs of organizing corrupt teams are also low. Most of the corrupt transactions that include patients are, from the standpoint of organization, simple transactions which include only one person or very few people on the supply side of a corrupt service. 12

13 It is interesting to consider the question of transaction costs in the case of corruption in public procurement in health care. As regards the finding of corrupt partners on the supply side of corruption, transaction costs can be substantial. Specifically, officials charged with the implementation of public procurement are usually carefully watched by the general public, i.e., their principal. An attempt to establish contact, i.e., negotiate a corrupt deal, can result not only in a negative reply, but also in the elimination of the corruptor from any subsequent public procurement tenders in which he tries to take part. For that reason, the first step is made with great caution, maybe through a middleman who would only gather the basic information, in order to take a decision on a general strategy on how to go about the public procurement. Furthermore, the problem of fulfilment of contractual obligations, provided that a corrupt contract has been concluded, generates substantial transaction costs. Both parties are in a position to behave opportunistically. This is all the more so because the payment for and the provision of a corrupt service are separated in terms of time. This problem cannot be solved even by breaking the total amount of the bribe into several instalments. If the amount (share) of the advance payment is high, the corruptor is vulnerable, and the corrupted has an incentive for opportunistic behaviour. If the amount (share) of the advance payment is low, the situation is reversed: the corrupted is vulnerable, while the corruptor has an incentive for opportunistic behaviour. Furthermore, the corrupted can be under corrupt pressure from several interested corruptors. Such competition among corruptors causes a rise in the amount of the bribe, but the possibility is clearly left to the corrupted to take bribes from several corruptors, and provide a corrupt service to only one of them. The probability of such opportunistic behaviour depends on the ability of the corruptor to punish the corrupted who received the bribe, and failed to provide the contracted corrupt service. Obviously, transaction costs of corruption in health care in public procurement are higher than in the case of the provision of medical services, i.e., health services. Luckily enough for the participants in corrupt deals in public procurement, the reputation gained in that relatively closed circle of businessmen and officials is a prerequisite for the performance of corrupt exchange in which both sides gain, so both of them have incentives to build such a reputation by refraining from opportunistic behaviour. 9 Although the levels of transaction costs in two basic types of corruption in health care are different, a general assessment can be made that the level of these costs is somewhat lower 9 This applies in particular to producers of specialized equipment, which essentially have no other option. Those who have no incentive to build a reputation, i.e., those who can relatively easy move to another market, can afford to behave opportunistically, such as producers of and traders in non-medical products, that is, nonspecialized equipment. 13

14 than in the case of corruption in other sectors. Still, it is necessary to point to the main mechanisms through which it occurs, i.e., its typical cases, in order to understand the character of transaction costs that have been discussed. One of the basic cases of corruption in the provision of health services is corruption associated with admission to hospital (for hospital treatment) in the circumstances where waiting periods for such admission are very long. The assumption is that there is a medical necessity (medical grounds) for hospitalization, i.e., that there are no irregularities in that respect. The scarcity of supply, i.e., the lack of hospital capacities creates a bottleneck, so the rationing of spending is carried out in two ways. Officially, a system based on the first come first served principle is applied, and unofficially this queue is jumped by means of corruption. Furthermore, the next objective which can be accomplished through corruption is the securing of a longer stay of a patient in hospital relative to the period required on the basis of medical reasons. The main motive of the corruptor in this case can be of relevance if the status of the hospitalized is different from that of non-hospitalized with respect to drug purchase. In those cases in which drugs are free only for hospitalized patients (costs are covered by health insurance), there is a motive to stay in hospital longer than necessary on medical grounds, in order to reduce expenses for drugs. Corruption in health care is very often associated with surgeries, in particular surgeries carried out by the best specialized surgeons. The first case of that type of corruption is payment to be listed for surgery by that particular surgeon in the first place. If the patient fails to pay a bribe, he will be operated on by another surgeon with lower qualifications, i.e., less capable, so the probability of restoration to health will thus be lower, or the required surgery will not take place at all. The second case is to pay for jumping the queue formed for surgeries by a top surgeon. Without corruption one s turn comes after a long waiting period, while with corruption they can be jumped. A special problem with this type of corruption lies in the fact that a corrupt contract is concluded by a lead surgeon, who also appropriates the entire amount of the bribe. The problem arises because of the fact that this medical service is not provided only by the lead surgeon. In spite of the fact that he is the leading star of the surgery, he would not have been able to provide that medical service without other members of the team: other assistant surgeons, an anaesthesiologist, nurses and medical technicians, etc. None of them will receive as much as a fraction of the corrupt income, although they provide, i.e., take part in providing of the corrupt service. Very often, that creates bad interpersonal relations and causes a breakup of teams that could have functioned very well in different circumstances. A special type of abuse of office in public health institutions is the abuse of the public health care system for attracting patients to private clinics where a doctor employed in the public health care sector is working. This is performed in the following manner: a specialist in a public hospital suggests to a patient to move all the treatment to the private sector, i.e., to 14

15 the private medical office of that specialist, although there are no medical grounds for that. Instead of providing to a patient a health service to which he is entitled as a contributor to the state fund for compulsory health insurance, a doctor denies that service to him and entices him to move to the private sector, in order to be able to charge for his services without restrictions in force in the public sector. Through this mechanism, instead of direct corrupt payment within the public sector, the provision of the service is transferred to the private sector with formal, i.e., permitted payments. In the case of corruption in health care in public procurement, the most direct mechanism of corruption is the choosing of the corruptor as the winner of a tender, although he has not offered the best terms. Despite the fact that someone else, for example, offered a more favourable, lower price of hygienic items for a hospital, the bid of the corruptor is chosen, which is less favourable and a higher price is paid for the purchase of hygienic items for the hospital. That enables the corruptor to appropriate rents, which he shares, in the form of a kickback, with the corrupted health official. This mechanism is simple and allows the generation and distribution of the highest rents. The problem with this mechanism lies in the fact that it is apparent, and therefore easily detectable. Competitors who have lost in public tenders have strong incentives to reveal corruption in public tenders, hence the corruptor and the corrupted have an incentive to modify the above mechanism, to make the corrupt transaction as such less apparent. The main method to achieve this is biased drafting of a public procurement notice, i.e., invitation to bid. That implies corrupt cooperation at the first stage of public procurement. Biased notice drafting can be carried out in a number ways. The first one is to list a number of criteria in the notice itself specifying the criteria used to evaluate bids, without specifying the method for combining these several criteria to arrive at an aggregate evaluation. In addition, the list of criteria in most of the cases is drawn up so as to include criteria known to be the most favourable to the corruptor. The second method is to eliminate at the very onset, through inferior formulation of a notice, those producers that are assumed to be the toughest competitors to the corruptor. For example, if the corruptor, unlike others, can deliver the requested supplies relatively quickly, and the delivery period is not of relevance to that procurement transaction, a procurement notice will set out a requirement for a very short time limit for the delivery of supplies, which only the corruptor can meet. In such a manner, the tendering process as such is not influenced, since competition is excluded beforehand all competitors to the corruptor are eliminated at the very beginning, since they cannot submit a tender. Similar mechanisms are also used for making specifications of the product itself, its properties, quality, etc. All these methods are used to bring a procurement notice closer to the specific and unique tender of the corruptor, thus eliminating other competitors from a public procurement tender in health care. 15

16 Free competition in the public procurement process in health care can be called into question in different ways. Some of them do not constitute corruption in health care, but other types of corruption, i.e., they do not have to be corruption at all. It has already been mentioned that cartel collusion among competitors in public procurement a tender which is received is less favourable than the one received through free competition, but no government official is involved in all these practices, either from the health sector, or any other sector, so there is no corruption involved. The second option is for the state to favour domestic producers of, for example, drugs. This is manifested in effective bans on participation in public procurement tenders by foreign producers through, for example, a failure to register their drugs. In such a manner, competition in a public tender is weakened, so domestic producers can appropriate rents. If such an arrangement is a consequence of corruption, that could not be classified as corruption in health care, since those bribed were not officials from the health sector, but people from the executive and legislative authorities. 5. Factors of Corruption in Health Care One of the main factors of corruption in health care in many countries is the existence of a gap between revenues and total expenditures of the public health sector. Total revenues are raised through the public system of compulsory health insurance, while total expenditures are a consequence of the universal right to free health care, that is, the rights of insurees, even all the citizens quite often. The gap is, on the one hand, a consequence of a shortfall in collected revenue from compulsory health insurance contributions. On the other hand, it is a consequence of a considerable moral hazard, i.e., demand for health services. In such circumstances, the only rational strategy for doctors and other medical staff is to reduce the volume of supply, in order to balance official (marginal) revenue and marginal costs, thus creating a gap between supply and demand for health services. Such state of affairs generates incentives to narrow, i.e., close the gap between supply of and demand for health services through corruption. By way of illustration of the above, cases were registered where family doctors, i.e., general practitioners who have entered in contracts on their jobs, i.e., on health services they provide with the national health care fund cannot cover from that revenue even the incurred costs, let alone their own opportunity costs. Direct payments by patients are obviously the only way to close the gap between total costs and total revenues of general practitioners. If there is no possibility to make such payments in a legal manner, within the official system, it is clear that corruption constitutes the only possibility to close the mentioned gap. 16

17 The mentioned gap between demand for and supply of health services is a consequence of populist public policies and proclamations of universal and to the patients free health care, i.e., supreme quality health care services for all those requiring them. Such policy is in part based on left-wing ideologies and the proclamation of free health care, and in part on political populism, absence of incentives to put the system of financing health care, i.e., system of health insurance on a sound and sustainable basis. Precisely that kind of policy is, due to the existence of the already explained mechanism, the most important factor of corruption in health care, the kind related to the provision of medical services to a patient. Such system of free health care usually has features that contribute to the strengthening of corruption. The first such feature is that the system does not allow practically any direct payments by patients to doctors, i.e., health institutions. The second is that health services to which an insuree is entitled are not precisely defined, nor diversified, be it by volume or by quality. There is only one type of compulsory insurance, and the premium whose payment is mandatory is commensurate with the current earnings of insurees. 10 Hence, the usual formulation that everyone is entitled to the best possible health care does not say anything about whether a patient in a hospital is going to be accommodated in a single room or not. These two features of the public health care system boost corruption. If there is demand for something, and that something cannot be paid for legally, it will almost unfailingly be paid illegally. Likewise, if something has not been precisely defined as an obligation for whose fulfilment no direct payment is required (as it has already been covered from insurance), there is a high probability that the payment for it will be collected, formally (if possible) or informally. It has already been mentioned that the demand for health services is price inelastic. That completely understandable inelasticity also constitutes a factor of corruption in health care, i.e., a factor which increases the amount of the bribe. In such circumstances, the probability for successful extortion is going up. Finally, one of significant factors, not necessarily of corruption in health care, but certainly of the conflict of interest and abuse of office in that respect, is the undefined status of double employment of doctors and other medical staff. The key question is whether and on which terms doctors, as well as other medical staff employed in public health institutions, can be engaged in private medical practice. This gives rise to another question: should, and on which terms, institutional capacities of public health institutions be at the disposal of doctors for private medical practice? If there are no clear and unambiguous answers to these questions, that will open up empty space for interpretation of the conflict of interest and 10 This arrangement, a single contribution rate which creates proportionality between taxation and income, can be defended by arguments of the so-called vertical equity. This criterion is fairly widely accepted criterion for assessing the equity of taxation, which indirectly shows the degree to which such system of compulsory health insurance shares common characteristics with the tax system. 17

18 result in the understanding of a job in the public sector is perceived as a possibility to tunnel patients into private medical practice, thus creating conditions to charge the patients for the rendered medical services. Regarding corruption in health care in public procurement, its key factor is the manner in which public procurement procedures are structured. The less transparent the public procurement process and the weaker the obligation to compete for public procurement contracts, the higher the probability of incidence of corruption. For example, if the threshold is high for public procurement procedures implemented without competition (tender), or if the rules applied in tendering are formulated in a way which makes them easily circumvented, all that contributes to a rise in corruption in health care in public procurement. A higher degree of market regulation for products purchased in public procurement transactions, also enhances competition in an indirect manner. If the number of competitors submitting bids in public procurement procedures has been reduced through government regulation, regardless of its motives, the probability of incidence of corruption is increased. 6. Consequences of Corruption in Health Care It is clear that the activity of providing health care in many countries is organized in such manner which constrains the market for those services, i.e., highly regulates it. Many market transactions are explicitly forbidden, even punishable. In that sense, corruption in health care, particularly the part of it which occurs in the provision of medical and supporting services to the patient subverts that regulation, i.e., enables the functioning of the market. Therefore, this type of corruption can result in a Pareto improvement the welfare of the patient, i.e., the one who has received a medical service is improved, as is the welfare of the corrupted, who would not have delivered that service had it not been for corruption. In other words, corruption opens up space for both sides to appropriate (consumer, i.e., producer) surplus, which would not be the case in the absence of the corrupt transaction, i.e., exchange. 11 In addition, corruption practically resolves the problem of moral hazard on the side of demand for health services, since no one has an incentive to request the thing he is not ready to pay for. Such benevolent attitude toward this form of corruption in health care, i.e., its effects on social welfare, should be balanced with facts related to the costs of corruption. These are primarily transaction costs of corruption. Although it turned out that, in the case of provision of medical and supporting services to a patient, these costs are not high, at least not as high 11 Corruption aimed at jumping the queue certainly constitutes corruption of that type. The corruptor pays such amount of a bribe which is, under the worse-case scenario for him, equal to consumer surplus that he appropriates by jumping the queue, while the corrupted appropriates additional income without a rise in costs, accordingly, he appropriates economic surplus. 18

Executive summary. Transparency International

Executive summary. Transparency International Executive summary Transparency International Every year, the world spends more than US $3 trillion on health services, most of which is financed by taxpayers. These large flows of funds are an attractive

More information

CORRUPTION ASSESSMENT REPORT 2016

CORRUPTION ASSESSMENT REPORT 2016 CORRUPTION ASSESSMENT REPORT 2016 CORRUPTION ASSESSMENT REPORT 2016 This publication was published within the framework of the project Civil Society for Good Governance and Anti-Corruption in Southeast

More information

The SELDI Corruption Monitoring System: Overview of Methodology and Select Indicators in Nine SEE Countries 2014

The SELDI Corruption Monitoring System: Overview of Methodology and Select Indicators in Nine SEE Countries 2014 The SELDI Corruption Monitoring System: Overview of Methodology and Select Indicators in Nine SEE Countries 2014 Dr. Alexander Stoyanov, Center for the Study of Democracy, SELDI Secretariat, Bulgaria Istanbul,

More information

What is corruption? Corruption is the abuse of power for private gain (TI).

What is corruption? Corruption is the abuse of power for private gain (TI). Outline presentation What is corruption? Corruption in the water sector Costs and impacts of corruption Corruption and human rights Drivers and incentives of corruption What is corruption? Corruption is

More information

Director of Customer Care & Performance. 26 April The Board is asked to consider and approve the attached draft

Director of Customer Care & Performance. 26 April The Board is asked to consider and approve the attached draft To: From: Subject: Status: Date of Meeting: BSO Board Director of Customer Care & Performance Anti Bribery Policy For Approval 26 April 2012 The Board is asked to consider and approve the attached draft

More information

HYDRATIGHT GROUP ANTI-BRIBERY AND ANTI- CORRUPTION POLICY 11 MAY 2016

HYDRATIGHT GROUP ANTI-BRIBERY AND ANTI- CORRUPTION POLICY 11 MAY 2016 HYDRATIGHT GROUP ANTI-BRIBERY AND ANTI- CORRUPTION POLICY 11 MAY 2016 CONTENTS SECTION 1. Our commitment to ethical performance... 1 2. Who is covered by the policy?... 2 3. What is bribery?... 2 4. Gifts

More information

Anti-bribery Policy. Approving Body: Council. Date of Approval: 26 November Policy owner: Director of Finance and Corporate Services

Anti-bribery Policy. Approving Body: Council. Date of Approval: 26 November Policy owner: Director of Finance and Corporate Services Anti-bribery Policy Approving Body: Council Date of Approval: 26 November 2018 Policy owner: Director of Finance and Corporate Services Policy contact: Stephen Forster, stf17@aber.ac.uk Policy status:

More information

NORTHERN IRELAND SOCIAL CARE COUNCIL

NORTHERN IRELAND SOCIAL CARE COUNCIL NORTHERN IRELAND SOCIAL CARE COUNCIL BRIBERY POLICY FINAL SEPTMBER 2012 1. INTRODUCTION The Bribery Act 2010 (the Act) introduces a new, clearer regime for tackling bribery that applies to all commercial

More information

Warrego Energy Limited Level 6, 10 Bridge Street, Sydney NSW 2000 T: E: warregoenergy.com ABN

Warrego Energy Limited Level 6, 10 Bridge Street, Sydney NSW 2000 T: E: warregoenergy.com ABN Warrego Energy Limited ACN 125 394 667 WARREGO ENERGY LIMITED ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY POLICY Contents SECTION 1. Warrego s commitment to ethical performance 1 2. Who is covered by the policy? 2 3. What

More information

Anti-Corruption Policy

Anti-Corruption Policy Anti-Corruption Policy Version: 1 Page 1 of 10 INTRODUCTION 1 Our Commitment Accolade Wines conducts all of its business in an honest and ethical manner. We take a zero-tolerance approach to bribery and

More information

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy Datum: 05-03- 2015 Rev:1 Pagina: 1 van 9 Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy H.Essers takes a zero-tolerance approach to bribery and corruption and we are committed to conduct our business in an honest

More information

NORTHERN IRELAND PRACTICE AND EDUCATION COUNCIL FOR NURSING AND MIDWIFERY

NORTHERN IRELAND PRACTICE AND EDUCATION COUNCIL FOR NURSING AND MIDWIFERY NIPEC/12/12 NORTHERN IRELAND PRACTICE AND EDUCATION COUNCIL FOR NURSING AND MIDWIFERY Anti-Bribery Policy May 2012 Review date: April 2015 Centre House 79 Chichester Street BELFAST BT1 4JE Tel: (028) 9023

More information

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006) Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006) Group Hicks: Dena, Marjorie, Sabina, Shehryar To the press alone, checkered as it is

More information

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy 1. Introduction PRG demands the highest standards of integrity and ethical conduct in its business dealings. PRG will not tolerate any bribery or corrupt practices related

More information

FIA INSTITUTE ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY

FIA INSTITUTE ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY ! FIA INSTITUTE ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY 1. POLICY STATEMENT 1.1 As indicated in Article 8 of the Internal Regulations of the FIA Institute, we take a zero tolerance approach to bribery and corruption

More information

GAC Anti-Corruption & Bribery Policy. January 2018

GAC Anti-Corruption & Bribery Policy. January 2018 GAC Anti-Corruption & Bribery Policy January 2018 1.1 This Anti-Corruption and Bribery policy complements the GAC Code of Ethics. The GAC Code of Ethics emphasises that the values promoted in the Code

More information

GAC Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy. November 2015

GAC Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy. November 2015 November 2015 1. POLICY STATEMENT 1.1 This Anti-Corruption and Bribery policy complements the GAC Code of Ethics. The GAC Code of Ethics emphasises that the values promoted in the Code must underlie all

More information

ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY

ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY Cubiks Group Limited Ranger House Walnut Tree Close Guildford GU1 4UL United Kingdom Registered Office as above, registered number 4999756 Bribery And Corruption Policy.Doc

More information

NOBLE MOBILITY CHARTER OF CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY

NOBLE MOBILITY CHARTER OF CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY NOBLECARE NOBLE MOBILITY CHARTER OF CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY WHO WE ARE NOBLE MOBILITY is a leading provider of moving and relocation services in the corporate market. The company s core values;

More information

ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY

ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY 1. POLICY STATEMENT 1.1 The Foundation takes a zero tolerance approach to bribery and corruption and will uphold all applicable laws relevant to countering bribery and

More information

Policy Summary. Overview Why is the policy required? Awareness and legal compliance with Bribery Act is required to minimise risk to UHI and its staff

Policy Summary. Overview Why is the policy required? Awareness and legal compliance with Bribery Act is required to minimise risk to UHI and its staff Policy Summary Overview Why is the policy required? Purpose What will it achieve? Scope Who does it apply too? Consultation/notification Highlight plans/dates Implementation and monitoring (including costs)

More information

Anti-Bribery Policy. Anti-Bribery Policy

Anti-Bribery Policy. Anti-Bribery Policy 1. Introduction 1.1 It is ASET s policy to conduct all of our business in an honest and ethical manner. We take a zero-tolerance approach to bribery and corruption and are committed to acting professionally,

More information

AIDENVIRONMENT ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY

AIDENVIRONMENT ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY AIDENVIRONMENT ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY CONTENTS CLAUSE 1. Policy statement... 3 2. Who is covered by the policy?... 4 3. What is bribery?... 4 4. Hospitality and gifts... 5 5. What is not acceptable?...

More information

How to Upgrade Poland s Approach to the Western Balkans? Ideas for the Polish Presidency of the V4

How to Upgrade Poland s Approach to the Western Balkans? Ideas for the Polish Presidency of the V4 PISM Strategic File #23 #23 October 2012 How to Upgrade Poland s Approach to the Western Balkans? Ideas for the Polish Presidency of the V4 By Tomasz Żornaczuk Ever since the European Union expressed its

More information

SUNTORY BEVERAGE AND FOOD EUROPE ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY OCTOBER 2015 EDITION 001

SUNTORY BEVERAGE AND FOOD EUROPE ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY OCTOBER 2015 EDITION 001 SUNTORY BEVERAGE AND FOOD EUROPE ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY OCTOBER 2015 EDITION 001 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. POLICY STATEMENT...3 2. ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION LAWS...4 3. THE PENALTIES...4 4.

More information

Aim is to simplify and update EU public procurement rules

Aim is to simplify and update EU public procurement rules New EU Directives Richard Heath, Associate New EU Directives One of a package of 3 Directives Directive 2014/23/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 February 2014 on the award of concession

More information

ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY

ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY Page 1 of 11 ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY Page 2 of 11 CONTENTS CLAUSE 1. Policy statement... 3 2. Who is covered by the policy?... 4 3. What is bribery?... 4 4. Gifts and hospitality... 5 5. What is not

More information

ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY 1 POLICY STATEMENT

ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY 1 POLICY STATEMENT ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY Issued/approved by: Modern Water plc Board on 14 June 2011 Last updated: 17 September 2014 Applies to: Modern Water plc and any company or other entity (registered or operating anywhere

More information

BRIBERY AND PROCUREMENT POLICY BUCKSBURN STONEYWOOD PARISH CHURCH OF SCOTLAND SC017404

BRIBERY AND PROCUREMENT POLICY BUCKSBURN STONEYWOOD PARISH CHURCH OF SCOTLAND SC017404 BRIBERY AND PROCUREMENT POLICY OF BUCKSBURN STONEYWOOD PARISH CHURCH OF SCOTLAND SC07404 Policy statement. Further to the work and mission of the Church of Scotland and the terms of the Bribery Act 200

More information

GLOBAL NEW CAR ASSESSMENT PORGRAMME ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY [DRAFT]

GLOBAL NEW CAR ASSESSMENT PORGRAMME ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY [DRAFT] GLOBAL NEW CAR ASSESSMENT PORGRAMME ANTI BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY [DRAFT] 1. POLICY STATEMENT 1.1 We take a zero tolerance approach to bribery and corruption and will uphold all laws relevant to countering

More information

ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY

ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY THIS POLICY APPLIES TO MILLFIELD, MILLFIELD PREP SCHOOL, MILLFIELD PRE-PREP SCHOOL (INCLUDING EYFS) AND MILLFIELD ENTERPRISES, TOGETHER REFERRED TO IN THIS POLICY AS

More information

The public sector and prevention of corruption: Strengthening institutional and sectoral integrity

The public sector and prevention of corruption: Strengthening institutional and sectoral integrity The public sector and prevention of corruption: Strengthening institutional and sectoral integrity Presentation on UNDP s Initiatives on Anti-Corruption in Sectors By Anga Timilsina, Programme Manager,

More information

Anti-Bribery Policy WHC reserves the right to amend this policy at its discretion. The most up-to-date version can be downloaded from our website.

Anti-Bribery Policy WHC reserves the right to amend this policy at its discretion. The most up-to-date version can be downloaded from our website. ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY ELT manager Director of Finance Responsible officer Director of Finance Date first approved by BoM 29 th March 2012 Date review approved by BoM 4 th October 2017 Next Review Date October

More information

FirstRand anti-bribery policy

FirstRand anti-bribery policy FirstRand anti-bribery policy - 1 - table of contents 1. DEFINITIONS 3 2. POLICY CONTEXT 4 2.1 Ensuring integrity in all business dealings 4 2.2 What is bribery? 4 2.3 Purpose of the policy? 5 2.4 How

More information

Premise. The social mission and objectives

Premise. The social mission and objectives Premise The Code of Ethics is a charter of moral rights and duties that defines the ethical and social responsibility of all those who maintain relationships with Coopsalute. This document clearly explains

More information

Best Buy Anti-Corruption Policy

Best Buy Anti-Corruption Policy Best Buy Anti-Corruption Policy 1. Scope 2. Policy Statement 3. Prohibited Conduct and Obligations 4. Definitions 5. Transparency 6. Communication and Reporting 7. Business Partners and Commercial Intermediaries

More information

Premium Integrity Program. Anti-Corruption Compliance Program

Premium Integrity Program. Anti-Corruption Compliance Program Premium Integrity Program Anti-Corruption Compliance Program Publication date: October 2013 Contents Indice 1 Pirelli's approach to fighting corruption...4 2 The regulatory context...6 3 Premium Integrity

More information

Transparency, Accountability and Citizen s Engagement

Transparency, Accountability and Citizen s Engagement Distr.: General 13 February 2012 Original: English only Committee of Experts on Public Administration Eleventh session New York, 16-20 April 2011 Transparency, Accountability and Citizen s Engagement Conference

More information

ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY Version 3 January 2018)

ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY Version 3 January 2018) ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY Version 3 January 2018) Applicable to (Group/company/specific groups of staff /third parties) Produced by (Name/s and job title/s) All Group Companies and Staff R. Deards

More information

Anti-corruption and bribery policy.

Anti-corruption and bribery policy. Anti-corruption and bribery policy. 1. Policy statement 1.1 It is our policy to conduct all of our business in an honest and ethical manner. We take a zero-tolerance approach to bribery and corruption

More information

CITIZENS OF SERBIA ON POLICE CORRUPTION

CITIZENS OF SERBIA ON POLICE CORRUPTION CITIZENS OF SERBIA ON POLICE CORRUPTION Edited by: Predrag Petrović Saša Đorđević Marko Savković Draft Report April 2013 The project A-COP: Civil Society against Police Corruption is supported by the Delegation

More information

Simply Media TV Limited: Anti-corruption and bribery policy. DATED JUNE 2013 ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY

Simply Media TV Limited: Anti-corruption and bribery policy. DATED JUNE 2013 ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY Simply Media TV Limited: Anti-corruption and bribery policy. DATED JUNE 2013 ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY CONTENTS CLAUSE 1. Policy statement... 1 2. Who must comply with this policy?... 1 3. What

More information

CHURCH OF SCOTLAND CONGREGATION SC[INSERT CHARITY NUMBER]

CHURCH OF SCOTLAND CONGREGATION SC[INSERT CHARITY NUMBER] BRIBERY AND PROCUREMENT POLICY OF [INSERT NAME] CHURCH OF SCOTLAND CONGREGATION SC[INSERT CHARITY NUMBER] (N.B. WHEN COMPLETING THE POLICY, WHERE THE ALTERNATIVES [KIRK SESSION/CONGREGATIONAL BOARD] ARE

More information

ANTI-CORRUPTION POLICY FOR INNOVATION NORWAY

ANTI-CORRUPTION POLICY FOR INNOVATION NORWAY ANTI-CORRUPTION POLICY FOR INNOVATION NORWAY Document name Legal authority Category Applies to the following business/staff areas Approved by Anti-corruption policy for Innovation Norway Ethical guidelines

More information

TECHNO BRAIN ANTI-BRIBERY AND ANTI-CORRUPTION POLICY

TECHNO BRAIN ANTI-BRIBERY AND ANTI-CORRUPTION POLICY TECHNO BRAIN ANTI-BRIBERY AND ANTI-CORRUPTION POLICY 1 INTRODUCTION This document sets out the Anti-Bribery and Anti-Corruption Policy ( Policy ) of TechnoBrain group of companies ( Group ). The Group

More information

Civil Society Organizations in Montenegro

Civil Society Organizations in Montenegro Civil Society Organizations in Montenegro This project is funded by the European Union. This project is funded by the European Union. 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS EVALUATION OF LEGAL REGULATIONS AND CIRCUMSTANCES

More information

Contract and Procurement Fraud. Bribery and Corruption

Contract and Procurement Fraud. Bribery and Corruption Contract and Procurement Fraud Bribery and Corruption Corruption The wrongful use of influence to procure a benefit for the actor or another person, contrary to the duty or the rights of others Forms of

More information

Law & Economics Lecture 1: Basic Notions & Concepts

Law & Economics Lecture 1: Basic Notions & Concepts I. What is law and economics? Law & Economics Lecture 1: Basic Notions & Concepts Law and economics, a.k.a. economic analysis of law, is a branch of economics that uses the tools of economic theory to

More information

Risk First Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy

Risk First Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy Risk First Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy Policy Owner Executive Leadership Team (ELT) Administrator General Counsel Latest Approval April 2017 Next review February 2018 Document History See final

More information

Bartington Instruments Ltd. Anti-Bribery Manual. The copyright of this document is the property of Bartington Instruments Ltd.

Bartington Instruments Ltd. Anti-Bribery Manual. The copyright of this document is the property of Bartington Instruments Ltd. Anti-Bribery Manual The copyright of this document is the property of Bartington Instruments Ltd. DCN 1109 DO0067 Issue 2 Page 1 of 10 Contents 1. Introduction to this manual... 3 2. Who is covered by

More information

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

Market failures. If markets work perfectly well, governments should just play their minimal role, which is to: Market failures If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to: (a) protect property rights, and (b) enforce contracts. But usually markets fail. This happens

More information

This Policy sets out Sewtec s position on any form of bribery and corruption and provides guidelines aimed at:

This Policy sets out Sewtec s position on any form of bribery and corruption and provides guidelines aimed at: ANTI-BRIBERY & CORRUPTION POLICY Introduction Sewtec Automation Limited ( The Company ) is committed to promoting and maintaining the highest level of ethical standards in relation to all of its business

More information

ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY

ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY Date Approved by Governors March 2017 Review Date March 2019 On behalf of Governors signed Print name On behalf of Governors signed Print name Principal s signature All

More information

2. WHY IS COMBATING CORRUPTION SO IMPORTANT FOR COMPANIES AND INVESTORS?

2. WHY IS COMBATING CORRUPTION SO IMPORTANT FOR COMPANIES AND INVESTORS? ANTI-CORRUPTION 1. INTRODUCTION 2 2. WHY IS COMBATING CORRUPTION SO IMPORTANT FOR COMPANIES AND INVESTORS? 3 3. ADVICE FOR FUND MANAGERS 4 4. FURTHER RESOURCES 6 1. INTRODUCTION CDC defines corruption

More information

International recruitment of health personnel: draft global code of practice

International recruitment of health personnel: draft global code of practice SIXTY-THIRD WORLD HEALTH ASSEMBLY Provisional agenda item 11.5 15 April 2010 International recruitment of health personnel: draft global code of practice 1. This information document has been prepared

More information

CHAPTER 3 THE SOUTH AFRICAN LABOUR MARKET

CHAPTER 3 THE SOUTH AFRICAN LABOUR MARKET CHAPTER 3 THE SOUTH AFRICAN LABOUR MARKET 3.1 INTRODUCTION The unemployment rate in South Africa is exceptionally high and arguably the most pressing concern that faces policy makers. According to the

More information

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy 1. Policy Statement In accordance with the highest standards of professional practice and good governance, the University does not tolerate bribery or corruption of any

More information

Annex B. Application of Chapter Five and Relationship to other Chapters

Annex B. Application of Chapter Five and Relationship to other Chapters A. Purpose Annex 502.4 Procurement - Provisions for municipalities, municipal organizations, school boards and publicly-funded academic, health and social service entities This Annex establishes the provisions

More information

2. Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy

2. Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy 2. Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy This document sets out the policy of Canary Wharf Group plc and its group of companies (the Group ) in relation to bribery and corruption. It may be amended by the

More information

REF: Legal & Resources Recommended Policy. APPROVAL BODY: DATE: July 2016 REVIEW DATE: July 2019

REF: Legal & Resources Recommended Policy. APPROVAL BODY: DATE: July 2016 REVIEW DATE: July 2019 POLICY: ANTI-BRIBERY & CORRUPTION REF: Legal & Resources Recommended Policy VERSION: 1 APPROVAL BODY: DATE: July 2016 REVIEW DATE: July 2019 LEAD PERSON/ COMPLIANCE OFFICER: VERSION REVIEWER/ APPROVAL

More information

ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY AND PROCEDURES

ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY AND PROCEDURES ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY AND PROCEDURES For use by: All Society employees; Members undertaking activities on behalf of the Society; agents, consultants and contractors acting for the Society. Owner Director

More information

The LTE Group. Anti-Bribery Policy Produced by. The LTE Group. LTEG anti-bribery policy v4 06/2016

The LTE Group. Anti-Bribery Policy Produced by. The LTE Group. LTEG anti-bribery policy v4 06/2016 The LTE Group Produced by The LTE Group LTEG anti-bribery policy v4 06/2016 All rights reserved; no part of this publication may be photocopied, recorded or otherwise reproduced, stored in a retrieval

More information

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy

Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy Anti-Bribery and Corruption Policy CONTENTS CLAUSE 1. Policy statement... 1 2. Who is covered by the policy?... 1 3. What is bribery?... 2 4. Gifts and hospitality... 2 5. What is not acceptable?... 3

More information

ANNEX 1 1 IDENTIFICATION

ANNEX 1 1 IDENTIFICATION Ref. Ares(2017)1012433-24/02/2017 ANNEX 1 SPECIAL MEASURE ON SUPPORTING SERBIA, THE FORMER YUGOSLAV REPUBLIC OF MACEDONIA AND OTHER IPA II BENEFICIARIES IN THE WESTERN BALKANS TO IMPROVE THEIR BORDER AND

More information

ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY - INCLUDING CODE OF PRACTICE ON BUSINESS GIFTS AND HOSPITALITY

ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY - INCLUDING CODE OF PRACTICE ON BUSINESS GIFTS AND HOSPITALITY ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY - INCLUDING CODE OF PRACTICE ON BUSINESS GIFTS AND HOSPITALITY Policy Number 5 July 2015 This Document is for the use of Scotmid Employees and their advisors only. No

More information

Anti-Corruption & Bribery Policy (including gifts and hospitality)

Anti-Corruption & Bribery Policy (including gifts and hospitality) Anti-Corruption & Bribery Policy (including gifts and hospitality) Academy Transformation Trust Further Education (ATT FE) Policy adopted by FE Board 4 th November 2015 This policy links to: Whistle Blowing

More information

SCOTTISH JUNIOR FOOTBALL ASSOCIATION ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY

SCOTTISH JUNIOR FOOTBALL ASSOCIATION ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY SCOTTISH JUNIOR FOOTBALL ASSOCIATION ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY CONTENTS CLAUSE 1. Policy statement 3 2. About this policy 3 3. Who must comply with this policy?

More information

Anti Bribery Policy. 1.2 We will uphold all laws relevant to countering bribery and corruption, including the Bribery Act 2010.

Anti Bribery Policy. 1.2 We will uphold all laws relevant to countering bribery and corruption, including the Bribery Act 2010. Anti Bribery Policy 1. Policy statement 1.1 It is our policy to conduct all of our business in an honest and ethical manner. We take a zerotolerance approach to bribery and corruption and are committed

More information

POLICY AGAINST BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION. Introductory Guidance. This policy has been introduced in response to the Bribery Act 2010 ( the Act )

POLICY AGAINST BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION. Introductory Guidance. This policy has been introduced in response to the Bribery Act 2010 ( the Act ) POLICY AGAINST BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION Introductory Guidance This policy has been introduced in response to the Bribery Act 2010 ( the Act ) The Act creates four key offences:- Active bribery (the offence

More information

CONTROL ON THE ADMINISTRATIVE ACTS BY THE ADMINISTRATIVE COURTS

CONTROL ON THE ADMINISTRATIVE ACTS BY THE ADMINISTRATIVE COURTS BULGARIA CONTROL ON THE ADMINISTRATIVE ACTS BY THE ADMINISTRATIVE COURTS Scope of jurisdiction 1.1. What types are the controlled acts (bylaw/individual)? As per the Bulgarian legal theory and practice

More information

1.3 The required standards of integrity confer a level of personal responsibility upon individuals. This Policy thus applies to:

1.3 The required standards of integrity confer a level of personal responsibility upon individuals. This Policy thus applies to: ANTI-BRIBERY POLICY 1. Introduction 1.1 The University has an absolute commitment to acting ethically, lawfully and with integrity in all its dealings, wherever it operates in the world. As part of this

More information

ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY POLICY

ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY POLICY ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY POLICY REVISION HISTORY: ISSUE CHANGES DATE 1 Initial Issue 30/07/2015 2 General updates 09/03/2016 AUTHORISED BY: NAME TITLE SIGNATURE DATE Deon van Aswegen Quality Manager 09/03/2016

More information

Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy

Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy 1. POLICY STATEMENT 1.1 It is our policy to conduct all of our business in an honest and ethical manner. We take a zerotolerance approach to bribery and corruption and are committed to acting professionally,

More information

Corruption and Organised Crime Threats in Southern Eastern Europe

Corruption and Organised Crime Threats in Southern Eastern Europe Corruption and Organised Crime Threats in Southern Eastern Europe Ugljesa Zvekic Global Initiative against Transnational Organized Crime 1 Organised Crime and Corruption in the Global Developmental Perspective

More information

Zen Internet ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY. Zen Legal Department. Issue: v.2.final. Date: Wednesday, 05 August 2015

Zen Internet ANTI-CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY POLICY. Zen Legal Department. Issue: v.2.final. Date: Wednesday, 05 August 2015 Zen Internet Zen Legal Department Issue: v.2.final Date: Wednesday, 05 August 2015 Contents 1 Policy Statement...1 2 About this policy...2 3 Who must comply with this policy?...3 4 Who is responsible for

More information

Closed and Banned Visits. Easy Read Self Help Toolkit

Closed and Banned Visits. Easy Read Self Help Toolkit Closed and Banned Visits Easy Read Self Help Toolkit About this document This document was made by CHANGE, a charity led by people with learning disabilities. This document uses easy words and pictures

More information

I. STATEMENT OF COMMITMENT AGAINST CORRUPTION, BRIBERY & EXTORTION

I. STATEMENT OF COMMITMENT AGAINST CORRUPTION, BRIBERY & EXTORTION CITY DEVELOPMENTS LIMITED ANTI-CORRUPTION POLICY & GUIDELINES* (*All employees of CDL are required to read the full version of the CDL Anti-Corruption Policy & Guidelines, which is available on CDL s intranet,

More information

Jurisdictional control and the Constitutional court in the Tunisian Constitution

Jurisdictional control and the Constitutional court in the Tunisian Constitution Jurisdictional control and the Constitutional court in the Tunisian Constitution Xavier PHILIPPE The introduction of a true Constitutional Court in the Tunisian Constitution of 27 January 2014 constitutes

More information

Anti-Corruption Compliance Programme

Anti-Corruption Compliance Programme Anti-Corruption Compliance Programme Contents Contents... 1 I The Prometeon Tyre Group's approach to fighting corruption... 3 The commitment to fight corruption:... 4 The commitment to comply with laws:...

More information

Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy

Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy 1. Introduction Anti-Corruption and Bribery Policy 1.1 It is the School's policy to conduct all of our business in an honest and ethical manner. We take a zero-tolerance approach to bribery and corruption

More information

From a Case of a Multinational Pharmaceutical Company: A

From a Case of a Multinational Pharmaceutical Company: A From a Case of a Multinational Pharmaceutical Company: A View of Commercial Bribery Laws in China Consultant Zhang Jiemin Shanghai SHIMIN Law Offices On July 11, 2013, Chinese Ministry of Public Security

More information

UNIVERSITY OF ROEHAMPTON ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY POLICY

UNIVERSITY OF ROEHAMPTON ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY POLICY UNIVERSITY OF ROEHAMPTON ANTI-CORRUPTION & BRIBERY POLICY Originated by Legal Officer: May 2014 Recommended by Nominations & Governance Committee 2 March 2015 Endorsed by Senate: 18 June 2014 Approved

More information

Prime Ministerial Decree No of 2005 Issuing the executive regulations of Protection of Competition and

Prime Ministerial Decree No of 2005 Issuing the executive regulations of Protection of Competition and Prime Ministerial Decree No. 1316 of 2005 Issuing the executive regulations of Protection of Competition and Prohibition of Monopolistic Practices law No. 3 of 2005 The Prime Minister After reviewing the

More information

Public Procurement. Stéphane Saussier Sorbonne Business School IAE de Paris Class 2

Public Procurement. Stéphane Saussier Sorbonne Business School IAE de Paris   Class 2 Public Procurement Stéphane Saussier Sorbonne Business School IAE de Paris Saussier@univ-paris1.fr http://www.webssa.net Class 2 Today! Public procurement, transaction costs and incomplete contracting

More information

Anti-bribery and corruption policy & guidelines. December 2011

Anti-bribery and corruption policy & guidelines. December 2011 Anti-bribery and corruption policy & guidelines December 2011 Progressio s organisational statement : Progressio seeks to operate to a high standard in all it does. It works with integrity, accountability

More information

Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community

Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community 24.11.2016 RELATED Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community Training Course Challenges and Opportunities of the ASEAN Economic Community

More information

Terry and Substantive Law

Terry and Substantive Law St. John's Law Review Volume 72 Issue 3 Volume 72, Summer-Fall 1998, Numbers 3-4 Article 30 March 2012 Terry and Substantive Law William J. Stuntz Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.stjohns.edu/lawreview

More information

C. THE FIGHT AGAINST CORRUPTION IN THE ECONOMY

C. THE FIGHT AGAINST CORRUPTION IN THE ECONOMY 25 C. THE FIGHT AGAINST CORRUPTION IN THE ECONOMY The need to fight corruption in the economy could not be overstated, as this is the domain of the so-called big corruption characteristic for illegal transfers

More information

PUBLIEUROPE LIMITED SUMMARY OF ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY

PUBLIEUROPE LIMITED SUMMARY OF ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY PUBLIEUROPE LIMITED SUMMARY OF ANTI-BRIBERY AND CORRUPTION POLICY We operate under the laws of England and Wales, including the Bribery Act 2010. We are committed to conducting all of our business in an

More information

ASTRAZENECA GLOBAL STANDARD EXPECTATIONS OF THIRD PARTIES

ASTRAZENECA GLOBAL STANDARD EXPECTATIONS OF THIRD PARTIES ASTRAZENECA GLOBAL STANDARD EXPECTATIONS OF THIRD PARTIES This Global Standard sets out AstraZeneca s ethical business expectations of Third Parties with which it interacts to ensure their conduct is consistent

More information

III. FINANCING OF THE ELECTION CAMPAIGN FOR THE ELECTION OF MEMBERS OF PARLIAMENT AND COUNCILLORS

III. FINANCING OF THE ELECTION CAMPAIGN FOR THE ELECTION OF MEMBERS OF PARLIAMENT AND COUNCILLORS LAW ON FINANCING OF POLITICAL ENTITIES AND ELECTION CAMPAIGNS (Official Gazette of MNE no. 52/2014, dated 16 December 2014, came into effect on 24 December 2014, and is in force since 1 January 2015) I.

More information

CORRUPTION REPORTS 2016: PUBLIC PERCEPTIONS

CORRUPTION REPORTS 2016: PUBLIC PERCEPTIONS CORRUPTION REPORTS 2016: PUBLIC PERCEPTIONS Authors and Contributors Prof. Dr. Hasan Kirmanoğlu K. İpek Miscioğlu Research Conducted By Infakto Southeast European Leadership for Development and Integrity

More information

Malaria Consortium Anti-Bribery Policy

Malaria Consortium Anti-Bribery Policy Malaria Consortium Anti-Bribery Policy Last updated: October 2018 Author: Finance Director Review date: October 2020 Anti-bribery policy, September 2018 Page 1 1. Purpose and context This policy applies

More information

Corruption and Good Governance

Corruption and Good Governance Corruption and Good Governance Discussion paper 3 Management Development and Governance Division Bureau for Policy and Programme Support United Nations Development Programme New York July 1997 Copyright

More information

Boris Divjak Director of U4 Anti-Corruption Resource Centre (Bergen, Norway) Transparency International School on Integrity, Vilnius 07 July 2015

Boris Divjak Director of U4 Anti-Corruption Resource Centre (Bergen, Norway) Transparency International School on Integrity, Vilnius 07 July 2015 Petty Corruption Hitting hardest the poorest Boris Divjak Director of U4 Anti-Corruption Resource Centre (Bergen, Norway) Transparency International School on Integrity, Vilnius 07 July 2015 Corruption

More information

Anti-bribery policy. Jesuit Provincial Offices 114 Mount Street London W1K 3AH Index

Anti-bribery policy. Jesuit Provincial Offices 114 Mount Street London W1K 3AH Index Jesuit Provincial Offices 114 Mount Street London W1K 3AH 020 7499 0285 www.jesuit.org.uk Anti-bribery policy Index 1. Purpose of the policy 2. Overall approach 3. Policy statements 4. Scope of the policy

More information

[company name] Anti-Bribery & Anti-Corruption Policy

[company name] Anti-Bribery & Anti-Corruption Policy [company name] Anti-Bribery & Anti-Corruption Policy Contents 1. What does your policy cover?...3 2. Policy statement...3 3. Who is covered by the policy?... 3-4 4.. Definition of bribery...4 5.. What

More information

This policy and Code of Conduct will form part of the induction of new EMPLOYEES (as defined below).

This policy and Code of Conduct will form part of the induction of new EMPLOYEES (as defined below). ANTI CORRUPTION POLICY STATEMENT OF COMMITMENT RICHLAND GROUP (as defined below) is fully committed to conduct our business with utmost integrity and with the highest ethical standards, and in compliance

More information

EC consultation Collective Redress

EC consultation Collective Redress EC consultation Collective Redress SEC(2011)173 final: Towards a Coherent European Approach to Collective Redress. Morten Hviid, ESRC Centre for Competition Policy, University of East Anglia, Norwich UK.

More information

Why has Sweden as a society taken this step?

Why has Sweden as a society taken this step? Speech by Kajsa Wahlberg, Swedish National Rapporteur on Trafficking in Human Beings at the Conference on Trafficking in Human Beings and Prostitution Global Problems-Local and regional solutions, Copenhagen,

More information