Unilateral versus Regional Integration: What Matters More for Economic Development?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Unilateral versus Regional Integration: What Matters More for Economic Development?"

Transcription

1 Unilateral versus Regional Integration: What Matters More for Economic Development? (JEL Category: F16, F43, I47) (Keywords: regional trading arrangements, trade, development, institutions) February 2008 Steven Yamarik and Sucharita Ghosh California State University The University of Akron Department of Economics Department of Economics Long Beach, CA Akron, OH phone: (562) phone: (330) Abstract In this paper, we test for the individual impacts of unilateral and regional integration on long-run economic development. We build a four-part empirical model that links bilateral trade and regional trade arrangement formations to the cross-country determination of per capita income levels. Using a deep determinants approach where per capita income depends upon integration, institutions and geography; we find that regional integration has a positive and robust effect on per capita income, while unilateral trade has a negative and fragile impact. The point estimates indicate that a 1 percent increase in the percentage of intra-bloc trade (relative total trade) raises the level of per capita income by 1.5 to 2.0 percent. We would like to thank Scott Baier, Jeff Bergstrand, Daniel Bernhofen, Jay Shimshack, Chih Ming Tan, and participants of workshops and seminars at IUPUI, Brandeis University, California State University at Long Beach, Clark University, Cleveland State University, Kent State University, and the University of Connecticut for their helpful suggestions and comments.

2 1 The issue is to know first whether there is an interest for individual countries to get into these (regional trading) agreements, what do they have to gain with these agreements and maybe what do they have to lose. Francois Bourguignon at Global Economic Prospects 2005 press briefing on November 16, Introduction During the past 50 years, trade liberalization has occurred along three fronts: multilateral, regional and unilateral. At the multilateral level, membership in the GATT / WTO has increased from 23 at its inception in 1948 to 151 in 2007 (WTO, 2007a). At the regional level, the number of regional trading agreements (RTA) has increased from 2 in 1960 to 380 in 2007 (WTO, 2007b). At the unilateral level, Wacziarg and Welch (2003) estimate that the percentage of nations having an open trade policy, as defined by Sachs and Warner (1995), increased from 16% in 1960 to 73% in Similarly, the world-wide trade share (trade volume/gdp) doubled from 24% to 50% during the same time period (WDI, 2006). In response, an empirical literature has emerged to test the link between trade liberalization and per capita income. One branch of this literature (e.g. Frankel and Romer, 1999 and Irwin and Terviö, 2002) examines the relationship between the trade share (openness) and per capita income. These researchers find that a higher trade share increases the level of real GDP per capita. A second branch (e.g. Edwards, 1998 and Lee, Ricci and Rigobon, 2004) investigates the connection between trade policy and income. They find that higher tariffs, import duties and other non-tariff barriers reduce per capita income. A third branch (e.g. Easterly and Levine, 2003 and Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi, 2004) examines the respective roles of integration, institutions and geography in determining per capita income. These authors find that trade has no significant impact on the level of real GDP per capita once institutions are included. 1 1 One exception is Dollar and Kraay (2003) who estimate a positive coefficient for the trade share in the presence of institutions.

3 2 However, most research in the trade and growth literature uses unilateral measures of integration. There are reasons to believe that regional integration can impact per capita income. For instance, Corden (1972) shows that the formation of a regional trading agreement (RTA) can shift production in favor of intra-regional trade which in turn can lead to greater economies of scale. Moreover, RTAs can erode market power of domestic firms in participating countries by encouraging competition within the bloc (Baldwin and Venables, 1995). Furthermore, RTAs can lead to technology spillovers either directly through greater intellectual property rights (IPR) enforcement or indirectly thorough greater trade flows. Although some of these regional effects may be captured by unilateral measures, it would nonetheless be important to see what role, if any; regional integration plays in the determination of per capita income. In this paper, we test for the individual impact of unilateral and regional integration on long-run economic development. We build an empirical model that links bilateral trade flows and RTA formations to the cross-country determination of per capita income levels. At the bilateral level, we estimate unilateral trade shares and RTA partnership pairs as a function of geographical, historical and political factors. These bilateral variables are summed up across trading partners to generate cross-country measures of unilateral and regional trade. We then include the two trade variables in a cross-country levels regression to disentangle the impact of unilateral and regional integration on per capita income. A few previous studies have attempted to estimate the link between regional integration and per capita income. de Melo et al. (1992, 1993) and Vamvakidis (1998) include a dummy variable for RTA membership into a cross-country growth regression. Under most specifications, the coefficient for the RTA dummy is insignificant. Vamvakidis (1999) includes an RTA dummy along with the unilateral trade share. He finds that an increase in the trade share leads to higher growth, while RTA membership has no impact. In contrast, Schiff and Wang

4 3 (2003) find that Mexico received significant total factor productivity gains from trade with its NAFTA-partner the US, but no gains from trade with other OECD countries. These measures of unilateral and regional integration are likely endogenous. Trefler (1993) and Grossman and Helpman (1995) argue that trade policy is not set in a vacuum but rather is endogenously determined by political and special interests. Empirical work by Dutt and Mitra (2002) find that geographical and political factors explain tariff rates across a sample of countries. Krugman (1991) contends that RTAs form among natural trading partners, which are geographically close to each other and remote from other potential partners. Using bilateral data, Magee (2003) and Baier and Bergstrand (2003, 2004) test the natural trading partners hypothesis by estimating the determinants of regional trade arrangements. They find that geographical, economic and political factors explain the formation of RTAs. Moreover, the impact of regional trade arrangements on per capita income may vary across agreements. As with unilateral trade, the amount of growth-enhancing productivity spillovers and technology transfers in RTAs is likely to be correlated with the volume of intra-bloc trade. For instance, one would expect Mexico to benefit more from NAFTA (with Canada and the U.S.) than from the Group of Three (with Columbia and Venezuela) since the U.S. accounts for around three-quarters of Mexican total trade. In our paper, we control for the endogeneity and magnitude of unilateral and regional integration by constructing a four-part empirical model. The first part of the model describes the bilateral formation of RTA partnership pairs. The second part specifies a gravity equation of bilateral trade based upon Anderson and van Wincoop (2003). The decision to form an RTA pair depends upon relative geography, historical and political factors; while the trade share depends upon geography, historical and unobserved fixed country effects. We estimate the first two parts of the model simultaneously using a Heckman two-step procedure to control for

5 4 endogeneity bias. The third part sums up the predicted bilateral trade shares and RTA pairs to construct cross-country instruments of unilateral and regional integration. We measure unilateral integration using the total trade share and regional integration as the percentage of intra-bloc trade (relative to total trade). The fourth part is a per capita income equation. We estimate the per capita income equation using two-stage least squares (2SLS) to control for the endogeneity of integration and institutions. We find that regional integration has a positive effect on per capita income, while unilateral integration has a limited and fragile impact. We begin with a Frankel and Romer (1999) specification where unilateral and regional trade is included with measures of geography. We estimate a positive and significant coefficient for unilateral and for regional trade. The significance of each trade variable, along with the low correlation between the two, suggests that the positive impact of regional integration operates outside of its effect on the unilateral trade share. We then use a deep determinants specification of Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2004) where per capita income depends upon integration, institutions and geography. By controlling for institutions, we find that regional integration continues to have a positive and robust effect, while unilateral trade has a negative and fragile impact. The point estimates imply that a 1 percent increase in the percentage of intra-bloc trade (relative to total trade) raises the level of per capita income by 1.5 to 2.0 percent. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we discuss the potential dynamic benefits of regional integration. We then construct the empirical model in section 3 and present the estimation strategy in section 4. In section 5, we present the estimation results. We conclude in section 6.

6 5 2. Dynamic Benefits of Regional Integration Lawrence (1996) makes a distinction between shallow and deep types of integration. 2 Shallow integration or trade liberalization involves the lowering or removal of border barriers to trade like tariffs, quotas and other non-tariff barriers. Deep integration, on the other hand, is the removal of internal or behind-the-border barriers that discourage the efficient allocation of international production within the region. These internal barriers include customs procedures, regulation of domestic production, product standards that differ from international norms, regulation of inward investment, competition policy, protection of intellectual policy, and government procurement rules (Evans et al., 2004). Shallow integration is likely to generate static welfare gains. Unilateral trade liberalization will lower domestic prices of imported and imported-competing goods and thus help consumers. Moreover, unilateral trade liberalization will lead to a more efficient reallocation of resources across industries and thus benefit the economy. Regional trade liberalization, on the other hand, can have either a positive or negative impact on welfare depending upon the relative amounts of trade creation and diversion (Viner, 1950). Summers (1991); Frankel, Stein and Wei (1995) and others argue that the beneficial effects of RTAs depends positively upon the geographic proximity and trade dependence upon members (Natural Trade Partners). Deep integration can generate additional growth or dynamic gains. The establishment of investment rules and dispute resolution and the harmonization of tax policy, antitrust rules, product standards, immigration laws and regulation can increase the flows of portfolio investment, foreign direct investment (FDI), labor, and intermediate goods. In addition, FDI and 2 Hoekman (1998) contends that the two types of integration are not mutually exclusive in that you can have four types of RTAs: (i) shallow integration but no deep integration, (ii) no shallow integration but deep integration, (iii) shallow and deep integration, and (iv) no shallow nor deep integration.

7 6 competition rules can reduce monopoly powers of domestic firms. In a neoclassical growth model, an increase in investment and skilled labor will raise the transitional growth rate. 3 In an endogenous growth model, FDI can increase the rate of technology diffusion (Glass and Saggi, 1998); while intermediate goods trade can raise the rate of technology adoption (Coe and Helpman, 1995). Similarly, by reducing the market power of domestic firms tied to current production processes, technology adoption can be raised (Parente and Prescott, 2000). Regional trading arrangements contain elements of deep integration and thus may deliver dynamic benefits. In particular, RTAs possess five possible institutional features that are deep: (1) merchandise trade rules, (2) services liberalization, (3) investment rules and rights, (4) intellectual property rights, and (5) labor mobility. Table 1 provides a matrix that connects each institutional feature to its potential dynamic benefit(s). Merchandise Trade Rules RTAs contain merchandise trade rules that reduce trade costs of goods between member countries by removing tariffs and quotas, creating more efficient customs operations, and establishing standards and conformity in the marketplace (Global Economic Prospects, 2005a). The trade rules are mostly shallow integration and thus expected to lead to static effects through trade creation and diversion. However, there are potential dynamic gains from reducing trade costs. First, the reduction in trade costs could increase the size the product markets. Larger product markets could increase the flow of investment as firms inside the RTA leave some countries and go to others depending upon comparative advantage, location and agglomerations of each member; while firms outside the RTA locate production inside the bloc to take advantage of larger markets and to access the lower internal tariff rates. Second, larger product markets 3 A net inflow of labor will increase the transitional growth rate only if the increase in human capital outweighs the increase in total population (c.f. Mankiw, Romer and Weil, 1992).

8 7 could increase FDI and their knowledge spillovers. Third, merchandise trade rules can lower the price of imported capital and intermediate goods. Depending upon the amount of trade creation and diversion within this sector, there could be an increase in the flow of technology to member countries. Lastly, the increased competition in the product markets reduces monopoly powers of the domestic firms. By reducing the barriers to technology adoption, competition could increase access to the global pool of knowledge. Services Liberalization From 1995 to 2005, 32 services agreements have been signed by RTAs under the General Agreement on Trade in Services (WTO, 2006c). These services agreements contain provisions that allow firms in member countries to provide economic services to other members and more importantly to establish foreign branches or subsidiaries. In general, services liberalization can enlarge the number of competitors and carries fewer income losses than merchandise trade rules because the barriers to service trade are often prohibitive and not revenue gaining. As a result, countries are likely to gain from regional services liberalization since the trade diversion losses are small (Mattoo and Fink, 2002). As with merchandise trade, services liberalization will create larger service markets with economies of scale potential. The economies of scale potential are especially large in service industries such as international transport and communications. The increase in market size and economies of scale will raise the return on investment, especially FDI. With fewer restrictions to prevent entry, firms from developed nations will establish foreign subsidiaries in developing economies and bring new production processes and knowledge. Moreover, since many services are used as intermediate inputs, services liberalization can benefit all sectors of the economy by lowering the price, raising the quality and increasing the variety of these intermediate inputs. Moreover, greater competition in the services sector could increase the adoption of new

9 8 technologies as monopoly powers of domestic firms are broken down. Mattoo, Rathindran, and Subramanian (2006) estimate that full liberalization of the financial and telecommunications sectors generate a 1.5 percent increase in GDP growth ceteris paribus. Investment Rules and Rights RTAs often include new investment rules and investor rights. The new investment rules entail provisions that provide equal treatment of foreign and domestic investors (national treatment); bans on discrimination among investors from member countries (nondiscriminatory treatment); rights to invest in businesses in all sectors, except where expressly prohibited (preestablishment); bans on trade-related investment measures (TRIMs); and investor rights to take foreign governments to dispute resolution for violating the investment provisions (investor-state dispute resolution). As a consequence, these new rules and rights can facilitate access to markets by relaxing restrictions on market entry and providing investor protections. New investment rules and rights can raise investment flows and FDI knowledge spillovers. As with merchandise trade, the preferential treatment of investment inside the RTA leads to investment creation within the trading bloc and investment diversion from outside the bloc. Levy Yeyati, Stein and Daude (2005) find strong evidence of FDI creation but inconclusive evidence of FDI diversion for 13 FTAs. Intellectual Property Rights Regional trade arrangements can also include intellectual property rights (IPR) that go beyond those of the WTO. Under the WTO, intellectual property such as copyrights, trademarks, trade secrets and patents are covered by the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs). Signed in December 1994, TRIPs established minimum levels of protection on intellectual property afforded by member governments. Under TRIPs, any future bilateral and multilateral agreements can only establish higher standards of intellectual

10 9 property rights, known as TRIPs-plus. The TRIPs-plus provisions, contained in many US and EU bilateral regional trade arrangements, extend the patent term for delays, require patent protection for plants and animals, limit the use of compulsory licenses, extend pharmaceutical patent protection, and provide arenas for dispute settlement (Global Economic Prospects, 2005b). The enforcement of TRIPs and TRIPs-plus would raise the expected return of the production of knowledge-based goods and services such as pharmaceuticals, chemicals, food additives and software. As a result, investment and technology transfer in those sectors would increase. The impact of IPR on technology however depends critically on how technology is diffused. If technology is acquired primarily through the details of the patents, then IPR will increase the rate of innovation. However, if technology is acquired primarily through imitation, then IPR will raise the cost of imitation and the rate of innovation would decrease. This question is even more pronounced in technologically-advanced intermediate inputs such as machinery, chemicals, software and so on. Empirically, Eaton and Kortum (1996) found that the value of patent rights is typically high in the OECD countries. Labor Mobility Regional trading agreements vary by the degree of labor mobility allowed between member nations. At the one end, the European Union (EU) and European Free Trade Association (EFTA) allow full labor mobility, with very limited exceptions. At the other end, the South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) and the Central European Free Trade Agreement (CEFTA) have no effective provisions for labor mobility. The regional agreements also tend to discriminate in favor of skilled workers. For example, several Latin American agreements (Group of Three, Brazil FTAs) provide for the movement of some skilled workers, but not for unskilled workers.

11 10 Regardless, labor mobility provisions have the potential to raise economic growth by increasing the inflow of labor and reducing barriers to technological adoption. First, depending upon the nature of growth and the skill set of immigrants; the inflow of labor could decrease the transitional growth rate, increase the transitional growth rate or increase the steady-state growth rate. Second, if the migration of labor increases the stock of human capital, then member countries will be more able to adopt new technologies. As a result, barriers to the adoption of the global pool of knowledge would fall. 3. Empirical Model We develop a four-part empirical model to estimate the effects of unilateral and regional integration on per capita income. The first part of the model develops a gravity equation that describes bilateral trade flows. The second part describes the endogenous formation of bilateral regional trade arrangements. The third part sums up the bilateral variables to create crosscountry measures of unilateral and regional integration. The fourth part estimates the impact of integration, institutions and geography on the level of per capita income across economies. Bilateral Gravity Equation The gravity equation has long been the workhorse model used to explain bilateral trade flows. The gravity equation can be derived from models of complete specialization and identical preferences (Anderson, 1979 and Anderson and van Wincoop, 2003); product differentiation with imperfect competition (Helpman, 1987); and incomplete specialization and trading costs (Haveman and Hummels, 2004). We use the Anderson and van Wincoop model of complete specialization, homothetic preferences and iceberg trade costs. Our intention here is to adopt a bilateral gravity equation that is grounded in trade theory, parsimonious in its specification, and easily summed up across trading partners.

12 11 Each country i produces a single good i but derives utility from all goods 1,, i, j, N. Each country i bears a trade cost c ij when exporting their good i so that country j pays p ij = p i (1+c ij ) for a good produced at p i. Assuming that the bilateral trade costs are symmetric, c ij =c ji, the equilibrium price level P in country j is P = S ( c / P) (1) 1 σ 1 σ j i ij i i where S = Y / Y is country i's share in World GDP and s is the constant elasticity of i i World substitution. We denote bilateral variables with lower-case letters and cross-country variables with upper-case letters. Anderson and van Wincoop refer to P as 'multilateral resistance' variables as they depend on all bilateral costs {c}, including those not directly involving i. Using (1), the following gravity equation emerges: t ij YY i j ij = Y c PP World i j 1 σ (2) where t is the bilateral trade flow. 4 Taking logs of each side of (2), we get t ij ln = (1 σ)ln cij (1 σ)ln Pi (1 σ)ln P. (3) j YS i j The left-hand side is the log of bilateral trade divided by the relative economic size of countries i and j. The right-hand side is the log of bilateral trade costs minus the log sum of the implicit price levels. Letting bilateral trade costs c depend stochastically upon geographic factors g (distance, common borders) and RTA membership, we can rewrite (3) as 4 Note that Anderson and van Wincoop use t to represent trade costs and x to represent trade flows.

13 12 t ij ln = (1 σ) β0 + (1 σ) β1rta + g (1 σ) ρ (1 σ)ln P (1 σ)ln P + (1 σ) u YS i j ij ij i j ij (4) where u is a random error and ( β0, β1, ρ) are coefficients to be estimated. Anderson and van Wincoop estimate a variant of equation (4) using a customized constrained minimization technique. Instead, Rose and van Wincoop (2001) and Feenstra (2004, Ch. 5) adopt a fixed individual country effects specification: t ij ln = µ + αrta + g λ + δ + δ + e YS i j ij ij i j ij (5) where d i is a fixed effect for country i, d j is a fixed effect for country j and e is the error term. 5 Feenstra (2002) shows that the estimation of (5) is easier to implement than (4) and yields similar results. Moreover, unlike paired fixed effects, individual fixed effects permit us to include timeinvariant variables like distance and common border. Bilateral RTA Formation A regional trade arrangement, like any trade policy, is a potentially endogenous variable. In the words of Lawrence (1998), free trade areas may well be an endogenous variable that is, a response to, rather than a source of, large trade flows (p. 59). For instance, Krugman (1991) shows that most RTAs tend to form among natural trading partners nations that are geographically close and alike. de Melo, Panagariya and Rodrik (1993) show how regional integration can arise from strategic interaction. Magee (2003) and Baier and Bergstrand (2003, 2004) estimate a qualitative choice model and find that countries are more likely to form an RTA (i) the closer in distance, (ii) the more remote from the rest of the world, (iii) the larger and more economically similar, and (iv) the bigger difference in factor endowments. 5 Eaton and Kortum (2002) and Baier and Bergstrand (2007) also use fixed individual country effects to account for multilateral price terms.

14 13 Following Baier and Bergstrand, we model the determination of an RTA using a qualitative choice model of McFadden (1975, 1976). Let u * represent an unobservable variable capturing the difference in utility levels from forming an RTA versus not forming an RTA: u = π + π g + π z + v (6) * ij 0 1 ij 2 ij ij where g are geography and historical variables, z are political measures and v is an error term (uncorrelated with g and z). With u * unobservable, we define an indicator variable rta, which is 1 if the two countries are in a regional trade arrangement (u * > 0) and 0 otherwise (u * = 0). The response probability for rta is Prta = g z = Pu > g z = Φ + g + z (7) * ( 1, ) ( 0, ) ( π π π ) ij ij 0 1 ij 2 ij where F is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. The standard errors for the estimates of ( π 0, π 1, π 2 ) are asymptotically standard normal. Aggregate Unilateral and Regional Trade We next examine the relationship between the bilateral trade and RTA variables and their aggregate or cross-country counterparts. The observed cross-country unilateral trade share is defined as the sum of aggregate exports and imports divided by GDP. For each country i, we take a weighted average of the bilateral trade share, t / YS, where the weights are the GDP ij i j share of country j, to arrive at the cross-country trade share: T / Y = S ( t / YS ). (8) i i j ij i j j i We use predetermined GDP shares S as weights to create instruments for the trade share.

15 14 We measure cross-country regional integration as a trade-weighted average of bilateral RTA memberships: RTA = ( t / T ) rta (9) i ij i ij j i where t ij is bilateral trade between countries i and j and T i is the aggregate trade of country i. As before, we use predetermined bilateral and cross-country trade shares as weights to create instruments for the regional integration variable. The RTA variable (9) has three important properties. First, the value of RTA increases with the amount of trade conducted inside each regional agreement. This property is consistent with the idea that the dynamic benefits of regional integration are carried by or at least correlated with the volume of intra-bloc trade. Second, there is no systematic relationship in the construction of the unilateral trade share (8) and the regional RTA variable (9). As a consequence, movements in the RTA variable will not simply be mimicking movements in the unilateral trade share. Third, the use of predetermined trade shares in conjunction with predicted values for rta will create exogenous instruments for the observed RTA variable. Cross-Country per Capita Income Equation The final piece of our empirical model is a cross-country per capita income equation. We adopt the deep-determinants approach of Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2004). 6 Under this approach, a distinction is made between the proximate (i.e. capital accumulation and education) and deep (i.e. geography and institutions) sources of economic growth. Rather than attempting to isolate the impact of each proximate source, a deep-determinants approach 6 Easterly and Levine (2003), Dollar and Kraay (2003) and Glaeser et al. (2004) also follow a deep determinants approach in their analysis.

16 15 specifies that the level of per capita income Y/POP depends upon integration TRADE, institutions I and geography G: ln( Y / pop ) = b + btrade + bi + bg + ε (10) i i 0 1 i 2 i 3 i i where e is an error term. In this paper, we measure TRADE as the unilateral trade share T/Y and regional integration RTA using (9). 4. Estimation Strategy and Identification We adopt a three-part estimation strategy. First, we estimate the gravity model (5) and bilateral RTA formation (7) equations using a Heckman two-step procedure. Second, using equations (8) and (9), we sum up the predicted bilateral trade shares and RTA variables to obtain our cross-country instruments Tˆ i and RTA i and actual membership RTA. Third, we estimate the cross-country output equation (10) using two-stage least squares (2SLS). Average Treatment Effect In the first part, we are estimating the effects of an endogenous binary variable ( rta ) on a continuous endogenous variable ( t / YS ). A basic problem in such a situation is that we do not ij i j observe the same individual (bilateral pair of nations) in both the treated (RTA membership) and untreated (no RTA membership) states at the same time. We instead observe one outcome for each country pair (i, j): ij ln( t / SY) = ( rta )ln( t / SY) + (1 rta )ln( t / SY) (11) 1 0 ij j i ij ij j i ij ij j i where the superscript refers to the outcome (1=RTA, 0=no RTA). Each trade share outcome is determined by a separate gravity model equation:

17 16 ln( t / SY) = µ + α rta + g λ + δ + δ + e = η + xβ + e (12) ij j i ij ij i j ij ij ln( t / SY) = µ + α rta + g λ + δ + δ + e = η + xβ + e (13) ij j i ij ij i j ij ij where η is the intercept term and x are a vector of geography and historical variables and country-specific dummies. In equations (12) and (13), we allow both the intercept and slope coefficients to vary across regimes. The average treatment effect (ATE) is defined as the expected difference of bilateral trade shares under the two outcomes: 1 0 ATE( tij / SY j i) E ln( tij / SY j i) ln( tij / SY j i) xij, zij, rta ij (14) Substituting in equations (12) - (14) into (11), we get that the observed trade t is ln( t / SY) = η + E ( ) ij j i rta e e ATErta x β ij ij ij ij ij rtaij( xij x)( β β ) + eij + rtaij( eij eij) E rtaij( eij eij ). (15) where x are the demeaned values of x. Wooldridge (2002, Ch. 18) describes four IV procedures to consistently estimate (15). Each procedure is based upon the correlation between the treatment indicator rta with (i) the error term 0 e, (ii) the differences in how factors affect trade flows for partners with RTAs versus those without (x- x ), and (iii) differences in unobservables for partners with RTAs versus those without 1 0 ( e e ). The last correlation occurs due to selection bias. We choose a "Heckman" two-step procedure (Procedure 18.4 in Wooldridge) to estimate (15). The Heckman procedure allows the treatment indicator rta to be correlated with 0 e, (x- x ) and 1 0 ( e e ). In the first step, we run a probit on (7) to form the predicted probabilities ˆΦ and ˆ φ for all i,j. In the second step, we use OLS to estimate

18 ln( tij / SY j i) η ATE rtaij xijβ rtaij( xij x)( β β ) = ρ rta [ φˆ / Φˆ ] ρ (1 rta )[ φˆ /(1 Φ ˆ )] + error. (19) 0 ij ij ij 1 ij ij ij ij The terms [ φˆ / Φ ˆ ] and [ φˆ /(1 Φ ˆ )] are called the inverse of Mill's ratios or hazard rates and control for unobservable heterogeneity and selection bias. A test of joint significance of? 0 and? 1 can test for the endogeneity of rta. The Heckman two-step procedure does require that the error structure 1 0 (, ve, e ) is independent of (x,z) and trivariate normal in (6) and (19). We were willing to make this assumption because the IV estimates obtained under a less-restrictive alternative (Procedure 18.3) were very imprecise. The imprecision was a byproduct of using the predicted values ˆΦ as instrument for rta and all interaction terms. Moreover, Wooldridge (2002, Ch. 18) argues that the Heckman two-step procedure is likely to be more efficient than Procedure 18.3 because it is based on Etrta (, xz, ) as opposed to Etxz (, ). Cross-Country Unilateral and Regional Trade We next construct actual and predicted cross-country unilateral and regional trade variables. We use the ratio of nominal exports plus imports to nominal GDP to measure the actual trade share. For the predicted trade share, we use equation (8) and add up the predicted bilateral trade share tˆ / Y S from (5), weighed by the 1960 GDP shares S. Equation (9) is used to create the actual and predicted regional integration variables. For actual regional integration, we use the realized values of rta, t and T to construct RTA. For predicted regional integration, we add up the predicted probit values rta from (7), weighed by the 1970 trade shares t and T,

19 18 to construct RTA. We use the 1960 GDP share and 1970 trade share in the construction of the predicted values to maintain exogeneity of our instruments. 7 Two-Stage Least Squares We estimate the cross-country income equation (10) using 2SLS. There are three potential endogenous variables: T/Y, RTA and I. In the first stage, we run the following three regressions: T Y = c + cg + ct / Y i + crtai + cz+ ε (19) / i 0 1 i i i RTA = d + dg + d T / Y i + drtai + dz + µ (20) i 0 1 i i i I = e + eg + et / Y i + ertai + ez + ω (21) i 0 1 i i i where G are cross-country geography measures and Z are instruments for institutions. The set of variables ( T / Y, RTA, Z) are the excluded instruments, which allow us to identify the three endogenous variables. In the second stage, we regress Y on the three fitted values of (19)-(21) and G. An instrumental variable must satisfy two requirements: it must be orthogonal to the error term (validity) and it must be correlated with the included endogenous variable (relevance). We use the Hansen J statistic to test for the orthogonality of the instruments when there are more excluded instruments than endogenous variables (overidentification). Relevance can be examined through the first-stage R-square and F-statistics. However, the recent literature on weak instruments (c.f. Stock, Wright and Yogo, 2002) has shown that mere instrument relevance is insufficient. In other words, rejection of the null of underidentification does not ensure reliable IV inference. 7 For those countries like the former Soviet republics, Czech Republic, Slovakia and Yemen that did not exist in 1970; we use the GDP share and trade data for the first available year.

20 19 With more than one endogenous variable, we use the Shea (1997) partial R-square and the Stock and Yogo (2002) weak instrument test to determine the strength of our instruments. The Shea partial R-square records the additional explanatory power of the excluded instruments. Unlike the conventional partial R-square, the Shea partial R-square takes the intercorrelations of the instruments into account. The Stock and Yogo weak instrument test compares the Cragg- Donald statistic to critical values based upon the worst possible case of weak instruments. The Cragg-Donald statistic is the minimum eigenvalue of the generalized F-statistic from the firststage, reduced form regression. Stock and Yogo (2002) present a testing procedure where the Cragg-Donald statistic is compared to pre-determined critical values under which the size of a nominal 5% test about a parameter of interest where actually r percent. Specification and Identification Table 2 summarizes the specification and identification scheme for the bilateral RTA (7), bilateral gravity (5), institutions (21), and per capita income (10) equations. There are four categories of variables: endogenous, geography, endowment and political. Each variable can be measured bilaterally (ij), cross-country (i) or both (ij) / (i). We choose our specifications to be parsimonious and consistent with earlier work. Furthermore, when possible we include crosscountry counterparts to any commonly-used bilateral variables and visa versa. For instance, we include the number of island nations in the bilateral equations and a dummy for an island nation in the per capita income equation. The bilateral RTA equation includes geography, historical and political variables, while the bilateral gravity equation includes geography and historical factors. The geography factors are log of bilateral distance; dummy for a common border; log sum of surface area and remoteness; and the number (0,1,2) of island nations and landlocked nations. The historical variables are dummies for a colonial link, common colonizer and common language. The political factors are

21 20 dummies for both free, current political alliance and correlation of voting in the United Nations. The political variables are excluded from the gravity equation to achieve identification. We consider three different specifications of the per capita income equation (10). First, we use the Frankel-Romer (FR) specification where Y/POP depends upon trade, log of population and log of surface area. The FR specification has been used by Irwin and Treviö (2002), Noguer and Siscart (2005), and Alcalá and Ciccone (2006) to test the link between unilateral openness and per capita income. Second, we consider a geography (GEO) specification where all the bilateral geography measures are summed up to form a set of cross-country geography variables G. The geography variables G are log of population, log of surface area, log of remoteness, and dummies for island and landlocked. Third, we use the Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (RST) specification where per capita income depends upon integration measured by trade share; geography measured by distance from equator; and institutions measured by rule of law. We include our regional integration variable in each specification. The institutions and growth literature recognizes that growth may lead to better institutions. To correct for this endogeneity, researchers have proposed different instruments to identify institutions. In two important studies, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2001, 2002) argue that the actions of European colonizers shaped the institutions of their colonies. As a consequence, they use settler mortality rates or population density in 1500 as instruments for current institutions of former colonies. Mauro (1995) and La Porta et al. (1998) argue that language and legal origin play a critical role in determining institutions. In response, Hall and Jones (1999); Dollar and Kraay (2003); and Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2004) use European and English language fractionalization as instruments. Moreover, Easterly and Levine (2003) and Glaeser et al. (2004) also include legal origin in their instrument set.

22 21 We use European and English language fractionalization as instruments for institutions. First, unlike settler mortality rates, these instruments are available for a large sample of countries. Second, European and English language fractionalization are commonly-used and thus allow us to directly compare our results to other papers, especially Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2004). Third, diagnostic tests found that this instrument set was the most relevant and strong. We conduct robustness tests to alternative instrument sets later in the paper. Data We use bilateral and a cross-country data to conduct our empirical analysis. The bilateral data set is a series of five panels for 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995 and In each panel, there are 5,000 to 10,000 bilateral observations. The trade flow t is an average of imports plus exports for each country in the pair. The trade flow data is drawn from the IMF Direction of Trade. We then divide trade flow by YY i j / Y World to get the bilateral trade share (see equation 2). The geography and historical data are from Mayer and Zignago (2006) and the CIA World Factbook (2006). The political variables are from Polity IV (2002), Gibler and Sarkees (2004) and Gartz, Jo and Tucker (1999), respectively. The cross-country data set is a cross-section of countries. Appendix A presents the basic data. The dependent variable is the log of real GDP per capita in PPP-adjusted dollars in We measure trade share T as nominal openness (= nominal trade / nominal GDP) averaged for The GDP, population and trade data are from PWT 6.2 in Heston et al. (2006). Institutions I are measured as the rule of law indicator of Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2005) averaged from 1995 to The geography variables are taken from the CIA Factbook (2006). European and English language fractionalization are from Hall and Jones (1999) with data for the former Soviet Republics obtained from Gordon (2005).

23 22 Unfortunately, there is no straightforward way to determine which RTAs are deep and which are not. First, the concept of depth is not easy to measure. There are a multitude of incongruent policies ranging from the elimination of contingent protect to the complete liberalization of factor flows that make up the depth of integration. For instance, Hoekman (1988) lists 9 specific policies for deep integration, while Evans et al. (2004) count 8 broad features. Second, deep integration is less about reducing trade barriers and more about the harmonization of regulatory practices in the trading bloc. As a result, it becomes quite difficult to talk about the degree of harmonization. Third, like shallow integration, there often can be a large disparity in the policies called for in the regional agreements and those actually implemented. We therefore use all RTAs that were in force from 1980 to Appendix B lists the regional trading arrangements. We include those RTAs notified to the GATT / WTO and also some that were not notified. The data were obtained from Medvedev (2006) and WTO (2007b). We did exclude those regional agreements that have no binding economic policies like the Arab Maghreb Union (AMU), Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC), Organization of Eastern Caribbean States (OECS) and other agreements. We believe that the inclusion of all types is more defensible than including some and excluding others based upon incomplete and imprecise measures of depth. Furthermore, if we introduce a bias by including RTAs that are not deep, we are likely to underestimate the positive impact of regional integration on the level of per capita income.

24 23 5. Empirical Results Bilateral Estimation Results We begin by estimating the bilateral RTA equation (7) using probit. Table 3 presents the results for 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995 and We estimate each year individually to allow for differences in the slope coefficients. The geography and historical variables are included in both the RTA and trade share equations, while the political variables are included only in the RTA equation. In general, the coefficients have the correct sign and are mostly significant. For geography, two economies are more likely to form an RTA if they are close to each other; large in area; remote from other countries; and an island(s). For historical variables, two economies are more likely to create an RTA if they share a common colonizer and a common language. For political variables, two countries are more likely to form an RTA if they are both free; in a current political alliance; and share similar voting patterns in the United Nations. We next estimate the bilateral gravity equation (5). Table 4 presents the OLS and Heckman two-step results for each year. The OLS regressions include the geography and historical variables; while the Heckman regressions include the geography and historical variables, interaction terms and individual fixed country effects. The regression diagnostics are shown at the bottom. The OLS results explain 0.14 to 0.30 of the variation in the trade share, while the Heckman results explain around one-half. The F-test statistics indicate evidence of selection bias, especially in 1990 and 1995, and variation in the slope coefficients? across the treated and non-treated. The results show that the bilateral trade share increases in border, landlocked, colonial link, common colonizer and common language; while it decreases in bilateral distance. The coefficients for area, remoteness and island change signs and are generally insignificant.

25 24 Turning to the treatment variable rta, the trade creation estimate is much larger for Heckman (with fixed effects) than for OLS (without fixed effects). Using OLS, the coefficient for rta is 0.44 to 1.48 in value. However, using the Heckman two-step procedure, the coefficient for rta increases to 1.01 to 4.93 in value. Baier and Bergstrand (2007) also find that the trade creation estimate becomes larger and more variable when individual fixed effects are included. Nevertheless, our objective here is not to estimate the amount of trade creation, but rather to produce fitted bilateral values of the trade share and RTA membership that can be used to create instruments for cross-country analysis. Predicted Trade Shares and Regional Integration We next construct actual and fitted trade share and regional integration variables for our cross-country analysis. As with Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2004), we compute the actual trade share T using data for 1960 to Unlike the unilateral trade share, intra-bloc RTA trade varies markedly across time as new trading blocs are formed. Therefore, we create weighted averages of actual and fitted RTA variables using observed outcomes rta and the predicted probabilities rta for 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995 and We then take a simple mean across time for each country to produce our cross-country variables RTA and RTA. Table 5 presents the correlation matrix of the cross-country variables. Each cell contains the Pearson correlation coefficient (r). There are two results of interest. First, there is little correlation between unilateral and regional integration (r = 0.19). At first blush, the low correlation suggests that RTA trade could exert an independent effect on per capita income. Second, the positive correlation between the fitted and actual cross-country variables (shown as highlighted elements) is moderate to strong (r = 0.31 to 0.72). The relatively strong correlation indicates that the fitted values will serve as good instruments.

26 25 Cross-Country per Capita Income Results We are now ready to estimate the per capita income equation (10). Table 6 presents the OLS results for the Frankel and Romer (FR) and geography (GEO) specifications. The FR specification is shown in the first six columns, while the GEO specification is displayed in columns 7-9. In columns 1-3, we measure the dependent variable as the log of real GDP per capita in 1985 from PWT 5.6 to compare our results with those of Frankel and Romer (1999). We then use the log of real GDP per capita in 2000 from PWT 6.2 in columns 4-9. The OLS results show that both unilateral and regional integration are positively correlated with the level of per capita income. In each specification, the coefficient for the unilateral trade share and for regional trade is positive and strongly significant. The point estimate of the trade share is 0.73 to 1.09, which is close to the 0.85 found by Frankel and Romer (1999). The point estimate for RTA trade, on the other hand, ranges from 1.85 to 2.52 in value. However, because of the possibility of endogeneity bias, the OLS results cannot be interpreted as accurate or causal. Table 7 presents the 2SLS results for the FR and GEO specifications. The top panel presents the second-stage estimates for each regression; while the bottom panel shows the firststage results for the regressions in columns 3, 6 and 9. As before, we measure the dependent variable as the log of real GDP per capita for 1985 in columns 1-3 and for 2000 in columns 4-9. In the first-stage regressions, the coefficients for fitted trade share and fitted RTA trade are positive and strongly significant. The two instruments are clearly relevant with high R-squares and F-statistics. Moreover, the values of the Shea partial R-squares and the Cragg-Donald statistic indicate the instruments are not weak. In particular, the Cragg-Donald statistic exceeds the r = 0.10 critical value and thus we reject the null hypothesis of weak instruments that would lead to size distortions of 10% or more.

27 26 The use of 2SLS raises the estimated impact of integration, especially unilateral trade, on the level of per capita income. The point estimate of the unilateral trade share nearly doubles in value to 1.33 to As before, our estimate of the trade share is close to the 1.85 found by Frankel and Romer (1999). Similarly, the coefficient for RTA trade increases to 2.21 to 3.65 in value. The increase in the point estimates suggest that the attenuation bias from endogeneity of integration is negative The results of Tables 6 and 7 suggest that the positive impact of regional integration on the level of per capita income operates outside of its effect on unilateral trade. If the two trade variables were linked, then the inclusion of the two would lead to a decrease in the significance of one or even both of them. Moreover, the point estimate for the unilateral trade share remains relatively stable and close to the estimate found by Frankel and Romer. However, there is likely omitted variable bias due to the low R-square. The institutions and growth literature has shown the importance of institutions in explaining cross-country income differences. We therefore include our RTA trade variable in a deep determinants specification. Table 8 shows the OLS results. We include the integration variables in columns 1-3, add institutions (rule of law) in columns 4-6, and then add geography (distance from equator) in columns 7-9. The results are similar to those found by Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi (2004). The coefficients for integration, institutions and geography are all positive and strongly significant. The one exception is column 9 where the coefficient for RTA membership is not significant at the 10% level. Table 9 presents the 2SLS results for the RST specification. The top panel shows the second-stage estimates for each regression; while the bottom panel shows the first-stage results for the regressions in columns 3, 6 and 9. The Hansen J statistic and the corresponding p-value indicate that the instruments are orthogonal. In the first-stage regressions, the coefficients for the

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias Michele Fratianni * and Chang Hoon Oh** *Indiana University and Università Politecnica delle Marche **Indiana University Abstract We test the relationship

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

Working Papers in Economics

Working Papers in Economics University of Innsbruck Working Papers in Economics Foreign Direct Investment and European Integration in the 90 s Peter Egger and Michael Pfaffermayr 2002/2 Institute of Economic Theory, Economic Policy

More information

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Preliminary version Do not cite without authors permission Comments welcome Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Joan-Ramon Borrell

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin February 20, 2006 Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The Group of Eight (G8) is an unofficial forum of the heads of state of the eight leading industrialized

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach 103 An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach Shaista Khan 1 Ihtisham ul Haq 2 Dilawar Khan 3 This study aimed to investigate Pakistan s bilateral trade flows with major

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data

Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* & Suryadipta Roy** September 2006 Abstract We complement the existing literature on corruption and trade policy by providing

More information

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP) GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP) Intro: increasing returns to scale and international trade

More information

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival WWW.DAGLIANO.UNIMI.IT CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N. 350 April 2013 Export Growth and Firm Survival Julian Emami Namini* Giovanni Facchini** Ricardo A. López*** * Erasmus

More information

The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization in Central and Eastern Europe

The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization in Central and Eastern Europe Working Papers No. 21/2011 (61) Andrzej Cieślik Jan Hagemejer The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization in Central and Eastern Europe Warsaw 2011 The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES. Giovanni Peri

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES. Giovanni Peri NBER WKG PER SEES THE EFFE OF IMGRATION ON PRODUIVITY: EVEE FROM US STATES Giovanni Peri Working Paper 15507 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15507 NATION BUREAU OF ENOC RESECH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES. Open For Business? Institutions, Business Environment and Economic Development

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES. Open For Business? Institutions, Business Environment and Economic Development UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES 2010 Open For Business? Institutions, Business Environment and Economic Development Robert Gillanders and Karl Whelan, University College Dublin WP10/40

More information

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) MIT Spatial Economics Reading Group Presentation Adam Guren May 13, 2010 Testing the New Economic

More information

Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore

Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore 178903 Associate Professor of Economics 05-042 School of Economics School of Economics plchang@smu.edu.sg Singapore Management University +65 68280830 International

More information

Migration and Regional Trade Agreement: a (new) Gravity Estimation

Migration and Regional Trade Agreement: a (new) Gravity Estimation Migration and Regional Trade Agreement: a (new) Gravity Estimation Abstract This paper investigates the role of Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs) on bilateral international migration. Building on the gravity

More information

EU accession and income growth: an empirical approach

EU accession and income growth: an empirical approach EU accession and income growth: an empirical approach Arjan M. Lejour *, Vladimir Solanic, Paul J.G. Tang * Abstract The dynamic gains from EU membership are crucial for the new member states to catch

More information

INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH IN SAARC COUNTRIES

INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH IN SAARC COUNTRIES International Journal of Economics, Commerce and Management United Kingdom Vol. VI, Issue 7, July 2018 http://ijecm.co.uk/ ISSN 2348 0386 INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH IN SAARC COUNTRIES Sazzadul Arefin Collage

More information

THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ECONOMIC INTEGRATION: EVIDENCE ON ASEAN-5 COUNTRIES 1

THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ECONOMIC INTEGRATION: EVIDENCE ON ASEAN-5 COUNTRIES 1 Journal of Indonesian Economy and Business Volume 24, Number 3, 2009, 291 300 THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ECONOMIC INTEGRATION: EVIDENCE ON ASEAN-5 COUNTRIES 1 Lukman Hakim Faculty of Economics Universitas

More information

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018 Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University August 2018 Abstract In this paper I use South Asian firm-level data to examine whether the impact of corruption

More information

THE IMPACT OF TRANSPORTATION COSTS AND TRADE BARRIERS ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE FLOWS

THE IMPACT OF TRANSPORTATION COSTS AND TRADE BARRIERS ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE FLOWS THE IMPACT OF TRANSPORTATION COSTS AND TRADE BARRIERS ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE FLOWS by JASON ALAN QUERY A DISSERTATION Presented to the Department of Economics and the Graduate School of the University

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA Ismet Voka University, Aleksander Moisiu Durres, ALBANIA Bardhyl Dauti State University of Tetovo Tetovo,

More information

Borders, Trade and Welfare

Borders, Trade and Welfare Borders, Trade and Welfare James E. Anderson and Eric van Wincoop* James E. Anderson Eric van Wincoop Department of Economics Federal Reserve Bank of New York Boston College 33 Liberty St Chestnut Hill,

More information

THE EFFECT OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY AND SOCIETY

THE EFFECT OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY AND SOCIETY THE EFFECT OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY AND SOCIETY A Thesis Submitted to the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences at Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements

More information

Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in Deep Agreements

Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in Deep Agreements Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in Deep Agreements AADITYA MATTOO, ALEN MULABDIC, MICHELE RUTA Disclaimer: The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and they do not necessarily represent

More information

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Shan Jiang November 7, 2007 Abstract Recent theories suggest that better information in destination countries could reduce firm s fixed export costs, lower uncertainty

More information

The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was formally

The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was formally WILLIAM EASTERLY NORBERT FIESS DANIEL LEDERMAN NAFTA and Convergence in North America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was formally implemented

More information

Migration, Trade and Income

Migration, Trade and Income DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7325 Migration, Trade and Income Francesc Ortega Giovanni Peri April 2013 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Migration, Trade

More information

Recent RSIE Discussion Papers are available on the World Wide Web at:

Recent RSIE Discussion Papers are available on the World Wide Web at: RESEARCH SEMINAR IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS School of Public Policy The University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109-1220 Discussion Paper No. 509 Fooling Ourselves: Evaluating the Globalization and

More information

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust? Comment on Corak (2013) Bradley J. Setzler 1 Presented to Economics 350 Department of Economics University of Chicago setzler@uchicago.edu January 15, 2014 1 Thanks to James Heckman for many helpful comments.

More information

An Assessment of the Europe Agreements Effects on Bilateral Trade, GDP, and Welfare

An Assessment of the Europe Agreements Effects on Bilateral Trade, GDP, and Welfare An Assessment of the Europe Agreements Effects on Bilateral Trade, GDP, and Welfare Peter Egger and Mario Larch 2nd July 2007 Abstract The so-called Europe Agreements had been enacted more than a decade

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Trading Goods or Human Capital

Trading Goods or Human Capital Trading Goods or Human Capital The Winners and Losers from Economic Integration Micha l Burzyński, Université catholique de Louvain, IRES Poznań University of Economics, KEM michal.burzynski@uclouvain.be

More information

International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework

International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework Mario Larch 1 Steffen Sirries 2 1 University of Bayreuth, ifo Institute, CESifo, and GEP 2 University of Bayreuth ETSG 2013 1 / 31 Why international

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRADE CREATION EFFECT OF IMMIGRANTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE REMARKABLE CASE OF SPAIN. Giovanni Peri Francisco Requena

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRADE CREATION EFFECT OF IMMIGRANTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE REMARKABLE CASE OF SPAIN. Giovanni Peri Francisco Requena NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRADE CREATION EFFECT OF IMMIGRANTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE REMARKABLE CASE OF SPAIN Giovanni Peri Francisco Requena Working Paper 15625 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15625 NATIONAL

More information

The Evolutionary Effects of Democracy: In the long run, we are all trading?

The Evolutionary Effects of Democracy: In the long run, we are all trading? The Evolutionary Effects of Democracy: In the long run, we are all trading? CHRISTOPHER J. BOUDREAUX * AR Sanchez, Jr. School of Business, Texas A&M International University, Laredo, Texas, USA Please

More information

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014 ASIA-PACIFIC RESEARCH AND TRAINING NETWORK ON TRADE ARTNeT CONFERENCE ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity 22-23 rd September

More information

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, 1960-2005. Giovanni Peri, (University of California Davis, CESifo and NBER) October, 2009 Abstract A recent series of influential

More information

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH Edris H. Seid The Horn Economic & Social Policy Institute (HESPI) 2013 African Economic Conference Johannesburg, South Africa

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Long-Run Causes of Comparative Economic Development Institutions University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Outline 1 Introduction 2 3 The Korean Case The Korean

More information

Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework

Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework Andrea Molinari INTRODUCTION... 2 CHAPTER I. ECONOMIC HISTORY AND TRADE STYLISED FACTS... 4 CHAPTER II. TRADE INTEGRATION AND GRAVITY MODELS:

More information

Joining the World Trade Organization: It s All About the Exports

Joining the World Trade Organization: It s All About the Exports Joining the World Trade Organization: It s All About the Exports By: Christopher Balding University of California, Irvine August 31, 2005 The author would like to thank the insightful comments and assistance

More information

The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was formally

The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was formally WILLIAM EASTERLY NORBERT FIESS DANIEL LEDERMAN NAFTA and Convergence in North America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was formally implemented

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

International Migration and Trade Agreements: the new role of PTAs

International Migration and Trade Agreements: the new role of PTAs International Migration and Trade Agreements: the new role of PTAs Gianluca Orefice a (CEPII, Paris) Abstract This paper investigates empirically the role of Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs) as determinants

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

Income and Democracy

Income and Democracy Income and Democracy Daron Acemoglu Simon Johnson James A. Robinson Pierre Yared First Version: May 2004. This Version: July 2007. Abstract We revisit one of the central empirical findings of the political

More information

Exports and Governance: is Middle East and North Africa different? InmaculadaMartínez-Zarzoso 1,2 and Laura Márquez-Ramos 2,3

Exports and Governance: is Middle East and North Africa different? InmaculadaMartínez-Zarzoso 1,2 and Laura Márquez-Ramos 2,3 Exports and Governance: is Middle East and North Africa different? InmaculadaMartínez-Zarzoso 1,2 and Laura Márquez-Ramos 2,3 1 Department of Economics, Georg-August University of Goettingen, Goettingen,

More information

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities Job Market Paper Sreenath Majumder Draft: November 2008 Abstract This paper examines the effect of public policy on population

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel Sturm. University of Munich May 7, 2004 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that membership

More information

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector Pierre Mérel and Zach Rutledge July 7, 2017 Abstract This paper provides new estimates of the short-run impacts of

More information

Regional Economic Cooperation of ASEAN Plus Three: Opportunities and Challenges from Economic Perspectives.

Regional Economic Cooperation of ASEAN Plus Three: Opportunities and Challenges from Economic Perspectives. Regional Economic Cooperation of ASEAN Plus Three: Opportunities and Challenges from Economic Perspectives. Budiono Faculty of Economics and Business, Universitas Padjadjaran. Presented for lecture at

More information

An Empirical Investigation into the Determinants of Trade Policy Bias

An Empirical Investigation into the Determinants of Trade Policy Bias An Empirical Investigation into the Determinants of Trade Policy Bias Matthew J. Hink, Ryan Cardwell and Chad Lawley Department of Agribusiness and Agricultural Economics, University of Manitoba Winnipeg,

More information

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51 THE IMPACT OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION ON TRADE SHARE AND PER CAPITA GDP: EVIDENCE FROM SUB SAHARAN AFRICA Abdurohman Ali Hussien, Terrasserne 14, 2-256, Brønshøj 2700; Denmark ; abdurohman.ali.hussien@gmail.com

More information

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H. The China Syndrome Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson AER, 2013 presented by Federico Curci April 9, 2014 Autor, Dorn,

More information

The Effect of Membership in the European Monetary Union on Trade Between Member Countries (An Empirical Study)

The Effect of Membership in the European Monetary Union on Trade Between Member Countries (An Empirical Study) The Effect of Membership in the European Monetary Union on Trade Between Member Countries (An Empirical Study) Ihor Soroka Abstract The question of whether or not to adopt the euro is a very important

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

Would a Russian WTO accession increase the country s export?

Would a Russian WTO accession increase the country s export? School of Economics and Management Bachelor thesis DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS June 2011 Would a Russian WTO accession increase the country s export? Abstract Russia began its accession process to become a

More information

A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources

A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources The Journal of Private Enterprise 31(3), 2016, 69 91 A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources Ryan H. Murphy Southern Methodist University Abstract Do social scientists

More information

Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from

Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from Bowdoin College Bowdoin Digital Commons Honors Projects Student Scholarship and Creative Work 5-2017 Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from 1975-2015 Michael

More information

Poverty, Inequality and Trade Facilitation in Low and Middle Income Countries

Poverty, Inequality and Trade Facilitation in Low and Middle Income Countries MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Poverty, Inequality and Trade Facilitation in Low and Middle Income Countries Cuong Nguyen 15. September 2013 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/50312/ MPRA Paper

More information

The Primacy of Education in Long-Run Development

The Primacy of Education in Long-Run Development The Primacy of Education in Long-Run Development Gregory P. Casey 1 (Cornerstone Research, Boston, Massachusetts, USA) And Patrick Kent Watson 2 Sir Arthur Lewis Institute of Social & Economic Studies,

More information

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand David Law and John Bryant N EW Z EALAND T REASURY W ORKING P APER 04/## J UNE 2004 Treasury:625092v1 [473620-1] NZ TREASURY WORKING PAPER 04/## Trade Flows and

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

Regional Integration and Trade in Africa: Augmented Gravity Model Approach

Regional Integration and Trade in Africa: Augmented Gravity Model Approach Regional Integration and Trade in Africa: Augmented Gravity Model Approach The Horn Economic and Social Policy Institute (HESPI) Working Paper no. 3/13 Edris H. Seid (MSc) December 2013 2013 The Horn Economic

More information

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation Hung- Ju Chen* ABSTRACT This paper examines the effects of stronger intellectual property rights (IPR) protection

More information

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants George Borjas (1987) Omid Ghaderi & Ali Yadegari April 7, 2018 George Borjas (1987) GSME, Applied Economics Seminars April 7, 2018 1 / 24 Abstract The age-earnings

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

China s Foreign Trade, WTO Accession, and Institutional Quality

China s Foreign Trade, WTO Accession, and Institutional Quality China s Foreign Trade, WTO Accession, and Institutional Quality 1 Miaojie Yu 2 China Center for Economic Research (CCER) Peking University, China August 8, 2008 [Abstract] China s trade volume has grown

More information

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES CHAIR OF MACROECONOMICS AND DEVELOPMENT Bachelor Seminar Economics of the very long run: Economics of Islam Summer semester 2017 Does Secular

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

Unreported Trade Flows and Gravity Equation. Estimation

Unreported Trade Flows and Gravity Equation. Estimation Unreported Trade Flows and Gravity Equation Estimation Thomas Baranga May 15, 2009 Abstract Some widely used trade databases do not distinguish between zero and unreported trade flows. The number of unreported

More information

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data (work-in-progress draft)

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data (work-in-progress draft) The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data (work-in-progress draft) Katrin Kamin, Department of Economics, Chair of International Economics, University of Kiel Abstract This paper analyses

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INCOME AND DEMOCRACY. Daron Acemoglu Simon Johnson James A. Robinson Pierre Yared

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INCOME AND DEMOCRACY. Daron Acemoglu Simon Johnson James A. Robinson Pierre Yared NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INCOME AND DEMOCRACY Daron Acemoglu Simon Johnson James A. Robinson Pierre Yared Working Paper 11205 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11205 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 7019 English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap Alfonso Miranda Yu Zhu November 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Bankgesellschaft Berlin. Daniel Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Bankgesellschaft Berlin. Daniel Sturm. University of Munich April 29, 2003 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Bankgesellschaft Berlin Daniel Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that membership

More information

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL:

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL: Forthcoming, Economic Inquiry School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants Bernt Bratsberg and Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL: SCHOOL QUALITY AND EDUCATION RETURNS OF IMMIGRANTS JEL

More information

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

The Political Economy of Trade Policy The Political Economy of Trade Policy 1) Survey of early literature The Political Economy of Trade Policy Rodrik, D. (1995). Political Economy of Trade Policy, in Grossman, G. and K. Rogoff (eds.), Handbook

More information

How Much Do Institutions Matter for Trade? Evidence from Transition Countries

How Much Do Institutions Matter for Trade? Evidence from Transition Countries How Much Do Institutions Matter for Trade? Evidence from Transition Countries Astghik Mavisakalyan 1 ABSTRACT What is the effect of institutions on trade? A line of recent literature has observed an apparent

More information

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2018 Monday and Wednesday ROOM CAS 227

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2018 Monday and Wednesday ROOM CAS 227 EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2018 Monday and Wednesday 2.30-3.45 ROOM CAS 227 Office hours Course content Prerequisites Requirements Monday 12.30-2.20; Wednesday 11.30-12.20.

More information

Effects of globalization - economic growth. Giovanni Marin Department of Economics, Society, Politics Università degli Studi di Urbino Carlo Bo

Effects of globalization - economic growth. Giovanni Marin Department of Economics, Society, Politics Università degli Studi di Urbino Carlo Bo Effects of globalization - economic growth Giovanni Marin Department of Economics, Society, Politics Università degli Studi di Urbino Carlo Bo References for this lecture BBGV Chapter 13 All paragraphs

More information

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence Philip Keefer All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth

More information

TRADE, POLITICS AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT - EXPLORING THE RELEVANCE OF THE TRADE-GROWTH LINK IN SELECTED DEVELOPING COUNTRIES BETWEEN 1996 AND 2006

TRADE, POLITICS AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT - EXPLORING THE RELEVANCE OF THE TRADE-GROWTH LINK IN SELECTED DEVELOPING COUNTRIES BETWEEN 1996 AND 2006 TRADE, POLITICS AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT - EXPLORING THE RELEVANCE OF THE TRADE-GROWTH LINK IN SELECTED DEVELOPING COUNTRIES BETWEEN 1996 AND 2006 A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Labor versus capital in trade-policy: The role of ideology and inequality

Labor versus capital in trade-policy: The role of ideology and inequality Journal of International Economics 69 (2006) 310 320 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Labor versus capital in trade-policy: The role of ideology and inequality Pushan Dutt a,1, Devashish Mitra b,c, * a

More information

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Remittances and Poverty in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK Alfonso Miranda a Yu Zhu b,* a Department of Quantitative Social Science, Institute of Education, University of London, UK. Email: A.Miranda@ioe.ac.uk.

More information

The long-run trade costs of the American Secession

The long-run trade costs of the American Secession The long-run trade costs of the American Secession Gabriel Felbermayr and Jasmin Gröschl October 14, 2011 Abstract Based on the US commodity flow survey, we show that the historical Union-Confederacy border

More information

AWARENESS is growing of the crippling effect of corruption

AWARENESS is growing of the crippling effect of corruption CORRUPTION AND BILATERAL TRADE FLOWS: EXTORTION OR EVASION? Pushan Dutt and Daniel Traca* Abstract We analyze the impact of corruption on bilateral trade, highlighting its dual role in terms of extortion

More information

International Migration:

International Migration: International Migration: A Panel Data Analysis of Economic and Non-Economic Determinants Anna Maria Mayda March 2004 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Welcome Abstract In this paper I empirically investigate

More information

The Diffusion Of Innovations In Central And Eastern Europe: A Study Of The Determinants And Impact Of Foreign Direct Investment.

The Diffusion Of Innovations In Central And Eastern Europe: A Study Of The Determinants And Impact Of Foreign Direct Investment. The Diffusion Of Innovations In Central And Eastern Europe: A Study Of The Determinants And Impact Of Foreign Direct Investment. by Dawn Holland & Nigel Pain Abstract The diffusion of innovations plays

More information

Trade and the Spillovers of Transnational Terrorism

Trade and the Spillovers of Transnational Terrorism Trade and the Spillovers of Transnational Terrorism José de Sousa a, Daniel Mirza b and Thierry Verdier c JEL-Classification: F12, F13 Keywords: terrorism, trade, security 1. Introduction Terrorist organizations,

More information

Lessons from Europe s internal

Lessons from Europe s internal Lessons from Europe s internal market for TTIP Prof. Gabriel Felbermayr, PhD Ludwig Maximilians Universität München The Transatlantic Trade and Investment Pact (TTIP) Bruegel, Brussels, July 18, 2013 Ifo

More information

Chapter 1. NAFTA and Convergence in North America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time. First Draft: October 2, 2002

Chapter 1. NAFTA and Convergence in North America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time. First Draft: October 2, 2002 Chapter 1 NAFTA and Convergence in North America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman First Draft: October 2, 2002 This version: March 27, 2003

More information

The impact of CEFTA Agreement on its members export flows

The impact of CEFTA Agreement on its members export flows The impact of CEFTA Agreement on its members export flows Evidence From a Country-Pair Panel Master Thesis Name: Bujar Maxhuni Student Number: 428818 Faculty: Erasmus School of Economics Supervisor: Laura

More information