Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework"

Transcription

1 Measuring EU Trade Integration within the Gravity Framework Andrea Molinari INTRODUCTION... 2 CHAPTER I. ECONOMIC HISTORY AND TRADE STYLISED FACTS... 4 CHAPTER II. TRADE INTEGRATION AND GRAVITY MODELS: SURVEY AND SOME THEORETICAL ASPECTS... 5 II.1. GRAVITY MODELS... 5 II.1.1. What do they measure?... 5 II.1.2. On the Theoretical Foundations of Gravity Models... 7 CHAPTER III. THE MODEL... 8 III.2.2. Data and Proxies... 9 III The Baseline Gravity Variables...10 III The Integration (institutional) Effects...11 III Unobservable Time Effects and Country Characteristics...12 III.4. THE RESULTS III.4.1. SURE Estimation III Baseline gravity variables...16 III The integration effects...20 III.5. MAIN FINDINGS CHAPTER IV. FURTHER RESEARCH EXTENSIONS AND CONCLUSIONS APPENDIX A. WELFARE EFFECTS OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS REFERENCES... 27

2 Introduction This thesis focuses on trade integration among the countries that belong to a regional trade agreement. Increase in intra-bloc trade is one of the most crucial ingredients for prosperous economic integration process such as the one implemented by the European Union (EU). We are especially interested in applying this issue to the EU because of the high economic integration reached by its members since the post-war period. Hence, our aim is to assess the contribution of the EU institutional framework and its evolution to the intra-eu trade deepening process. There is no doubt that intra-eu trade has increased after the creation of the European Economic Community (ECC) in the late 1950s. There are many potential explanations for this growth. On the one hand, EU members have experienced, as have most OECD countries, an increase in their economic size and wealth, which may well have stimulated their exports and imports to each other. In addition, doing business has become easier through the past decades due to the growing globalisation process. Proximity among EU members also operates as an important positive determinant of the countries trade flows, given the lower transport and transaction costs that physical closeness entails. Another determinant of the observed rise in trade flows among EU countries may have been the institutional effect entailed on the creation of this regional trade agreement. The well-known gravity framework provides us with the necessary tool to test whether the institutional creation of the EEC in itself has had a significant impact on intra-eu trade. Gravity models have been widely used in the literature to find the determinants of bilateral trade flows. Their baseline specification includes the size of the trading countries, their common characteristics, and the distance between them. By adding a dummy variable for joint membership to a certain regional trade agreement, it is possible to account for EU s institutional incidence in bilateral trade flows. Given that we try to reflect the evolution through time of the integration process, it is necessary to control for unobservable time effects in the baseline gravity equation. These effects capture further trade determinants that are difficult to measure, such as the globalisation process, and therefore cannot be included into the equation explicitly. Along similar lines, it is also important to capture countries specific characteristics. Thus, with a gravity model that controls for the baseline trade determinants (called natural by Frankel, Stein and Wei, 1993) and for the unobservable time and 2

3 individual effects we are able to isolate the institutional effects of the EU. This then allows us to assess whether they were important in determining intra-eu trade flows. Although the gravity framework s lack of theoretical foundations provokes criticism, it also provides some flexibility for application to various samples of countries and years. However, the gravity framework has two intrinsic problems. First, it includes time-invariant regressors, such as distance and common characteristics between countries, which can make estimating their effects on trade more difficult. Moreover, explaining trade with the partners economic sizes generates endogeneity problems. This means that a country s exports both depend on and determine its economic size. We estimate our gravity model by three methods. In order to differentiate EU members from a broader sample of countries with similar characteristics, and to analyse the evolution through time of the institutional EU effect, we estimate our gravity specification for a sample of developed OECD countries over the period To account for the time correlation between the cross-section gravity equations, we first estimate a Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SURE) model. We then consider a panel data General Least Squares (GLS) method to control for unobservable individual effects in the sample. Although this method might provide inconsistent estimators, which are probably due to the mentioned endogeneity problem, GLS is preferable to the within-group, since this sweeps out the effects of time-invariant regressors. Our third method is an Instrumental Variables (IV) GLS method suggested by Hausman and Taylor (1981), a useful way of accounting for both the unobservable individual and time effects and the endogeneity issues. The IV-GLS method uses internal instruments to control for the mass endogeneity and allows for the inclusion of timeinvariant regressors (such as geographical distance and common characteristics). Our main findings indicate that the EU effect decreases when controlling for unobservable individual effects and mass endogeneity. The EU estimate is also sensitive to globalisation and to the three external enlargement effects. In addition, we find a positive long-run external effect for the first and third enlargements on bilateral exports and a negative medium-run external effect for the first enlargement. This is mainly due to a learning process entailed in the accession of new members, UK s joining, and the first oil shock. Finally, our results show a positive globalisation effect on bilateral exports. 3

4 To conclude, we suggest some ideas to include economic distance measures and to disaggregate the model into economic sectors. Finally, we begin analysing possible ways to solve the lack of labour market mobility among EU countries by exploring the wages-trade link. Our work is organised as follows: Chapter I summarises the most relevant post-war developments for the OECD countries, focussing mainly on the European integration process and on stylised facts for intra-eu trade patterns. Chapter II introduces the gravity model, discussing some of the theoretical aspects involved in adopting this framework, and surveying the main studies that measure EU trade integration. Chapter III derives a simple gravity model from an imperfect competition setup to then specify and estimate our model to measure the evolution of trade integration among the EU members by three different methods (SURE, GLS and IV-GLS). Finally, Chapter IV poses further issues and ideas to be developed in relation to finding an economic distance measure, sectoral gravity equations and labour market integration. Chapter I. Economic History and Trade Stylised Facts This chapter presents a brief historical overview and some trade stylised facts in order to define the general settings of the period analysed in our model and to understand the main results of our estimations. Section I.1. focuses on some general aspects of the economic history of industrial countries. 1 The next section describes the main postwar multilateral and regional agreements reached by European countries. The last part of the chapter shows stylised facts of the intra-european trade as well as trade patterns between Europe and the rest of the world. 2 1 Given that most OECD members are industrial (or developed) countries, these terms will be used interchangeably. 2 This comprises third countries that do not form part of the respective agreement. 4

5 Chapter II. Trade Integration and Gravity models: Survey and Some Theoretical Aspects We will use the gravity model as a tool to measure trade integration among EU countries. The first part of this chapter explains the gravity framework and highlights some theoretical issues. The second part of the chapter surveys the main studies that measure trade integration. II.1. Gravity models This section introduces the main tool we are going to use for measuring EU trade integration, the gravity model. We first explain the idea behind it and then describe some of the main theoretical issues posed in the literature. II.1.1. What do they measure? Gravity models derive their inspiration from Newton s law of gravity, which recognises that all material particles, and the bodies that are composed of them, have a property called gravitational mass. This property causes any two particles to exert attractive forces upon each other that are directly proportional to the product of the masses and inversely proportional to the square of the distance between the particles. Gravity models are used to explain bilateral trade links between countries as directly proportional to their size and inversely related to the distance between them. Most models also include some common idiosyncratic characteristics of these countries, such as the sharing of a common language or membership in certain preferential trade agreements. They have proved to be empirically robust and consistent with the observed data and offer a systematic framework for measuring bilateral trade patterns around the world. As Eichengreen and Irwin (1998) assert, Few aggregate economic relationships are as robust 3. Baldwin (1994) makes a useful and intuitive analogy of an individual family s pattern of purchases to explain the idea behind the gravity model: A family lives near two shopping areas. Factors influencing how much the family buys at each shopping area may be divided into those that concern the family s characteristics and those that relate to the particular shopping area s traits. For instance, the richer the family becomes per capita, the more they will tend to spend on goods from both shopping 3 Eichengreen and Irwin (1998), page 34. 5

6 areas. Similarly, holding constant the per capita income of the family but increasing the family s total income, and thereby the size of the family, would increase the amount bought at both sites. The division of purchases between the two shopping areas would depend primarily on the various characteristics of the shopping areas themselves. It is likely that the family would buy relatively more from the area that offered the wider selection of goods. Also, other things being equal, the family will tend to do more of their shopping at the nearby shopping area. 4 In an international trade setup, the richer and bigger the country, the higher its purchases of foreign goods; i.e. a country s imports increase with its per capita and total income. The volume and the variety of goods produced and available resources will also be greater as a country grows in size and becomes richer. In other words, an exporting country s per capita and total GDP (called mass in the gravity framework) should be positively correlated with its exports. Finally, the greater the goods transportation cost between two countries, the smaller the quantity of trade; i.e. distance (or any other determinant of transaction costs) dampens trade. This positive correlation between exports and GDP is possible as long as greater production is evenly distributed across all goods and services. It is possible that a country s economy responds to an increase in GDP only by expanding its non-traded sector. In that case, there would not be such a correlation between trade and size. Moreover, an argument can be made for bigger countries to be self-sufficient. During the 1990s, gravity models became widely used as a tool to explain bilateral trade flows among countries or regions. Some of their applications incorporate trade blocs dummies to test how natural those blocs are (Frankel, Stein and Wei, 1993 and 1998). A second group of studies includes both internal and external trade and distance proxies (Wei, 1996; Helliwell, 1996, 1997 and 1998; Nitsch, 1999) to measure the width of the borders. The gravity setup has also been used to measure the potential trade of developing countries, such as Eastern Europe EU accession (Wang and Winters, 1991 and 1994; Hamilton and Winters, 1992; Baldwin, 1994), or within the Southern Africa region (Foroutan and Pritchett, 1993; Cassim and Hartzenburg, 2000). Due to our main interest in EU trade integration, our survey focuses on the first two lines of study as well as other studies that measure EU trade integration outside the gravity framework. 4 Baldwin (1994), pages 82 and 83. 6

7 II.1.2. On the Theoretical Foundations of Gravity Models The origins of the gravity model to explore the determinants of bilateral trade flows go back to Linnemann (1966), who proposed to consider the importer s demand, the exporter s supply and the trade costs between them. Since then, the theoretical foundations of gravity models have been questioned. Due to their intuitive specification, gravity models have always been considered to work fairly well in empirical grounds. However, most concerns centre on whether it is possible to derive this model from various theoretical frameworks that adopt different, and sometimes contradictory, assumptions. The critics point out that the gravity framework is compatible both with the perfect competition models, such as Heckscher-Ohlin, and with trade theories that assume imperfect competition. More specifically, Wang and Winters (1991) point out that a simple Cobb-Douglas expenditure system (such as Anderson s, 1979), is not appropriate to derive a gravity specification. As Anderson shows, introducing (...) stochastic errors and/or multiple commodities, (...) the log-linear relationship between aggregates is difficult to support 5. Moving to more comprehensive functional forms, Bergstrand (1989) obtains a gravity equation that explains bilateral trade flows from a general equilibrium model with two differentiated products and two factors. The representative consumer is assumed to maximise a nested Cobb-Douglas-CES-Stone-Geary utility function subject to a budget constraint, whereas the firms produce in a Chamberlinian monopolistic competition setup. Bergstrand shows that, under this framework, demand depends upon relative prices and domestic income. Hence, the gravity equation fits in with both the Heckscher-Ohlin model of inter-industry trade and the Helpman-Krugman- Markusen intra-industry trade models. Deardoff (1995) shows that, starting from a Heckscher-Ohlin model, the gravity model can be derived assuming either frictionless trade or imperfect competition. In the first case, preferences need to be identical and homothetic or demands have to be uncorrelated with supplies. In the context of countries producing differentiated goods, preferences can be either Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) or the special case Cobb-Douglas. However, this argument has been discussed by later work. For example, Helliwell (1998) finds that a model of comparative advantage limited by trade barriers would 7

8 not seem to predict any influence of average incomes on the size of border effects, 6 which he estimates using a gravity model. Moreover, some authors consider this lack of theoretical incompatibility as an attractive feature that gives flexibility to explain (...) bilateral trade flows across a wide variety of countries and periods 7. In sum, some studies have shown that the gravity model can be derived from two opposite theoretical models. However, this only indicates that gravity models cannot be used to test rival trade theories, and hence we believe that the theoretical flexibility of gravity models is an advantage rather than an obstacle for explaining bilateral trade flows. Chapter III. The Model One of the main objectives of an economic union is to increase trade among its members. The trade intensity between countries depends mainly on the explicit and implicit barriers that each imposes on its partners. These barriers generally take the form of transport costs, tariffs, and non-tariff restrictions. Declining costs of transport and communication reduce the economic distance between communities, regardless of which country the communities belong to. These cost reductions are likely to strengthen both domestic and economic linkages, which are necessary for the increased economic integration among the member countries. The stylised facts described in Chapter I show that trade between European Union countries has grown considerably since the creation of the EEC in the late 1950s. However, the simple observation of intra-eu trade patterns does not shed light upon the determinants that caused this significant increase in bilateral exports. These may involve the EU 8 treaties (i.e. institutional effects) or may simply reflect the growth, the wealth and the reduction of countries transport costs attained by trading with their neighbours. A further determinant of intra-eu trade might be the impact of globalisation on trade flows, which reduces international (and national) transaction costs. 5 Wang and Winters (1991), page 7. 6 The border effect measures the extent to which domestic sales of a country are greater than its external trade, after allowing for the effects of economic size, distance, and alternative trading opportunities. 7 Eichengreen and Irwin (1998), pages 33 and For simplicity, we will use the terms EEC, EC and EU interchangeably all throughout this chapter, if this distinction is not fundamental. 8

9 Hence, we need a method that will control for the so-called natural determinants of trade and at the same time capture the institutional effect of the EU integration process, time and country-specific effects. We accomplish this by estimating a gravity equation. As mentioned in Chapter II, the gravity model is a useful tool to explain bilateral trade as a proportion of the product of both countries masses and inversely related to the distance between them. The baseline gravity model that we consider includes mass of the trading countries, their wealth and dissimilarity, and the distance, adjacency and common cultural linkages between them. It is important to clarify that we do not intend to derive economic welfare results. As Viner (1950) noted, there can be are positive and negative welfare effects when creating a customs union (CU). We are just analysing the bilateral trade determinants of intra-eu trade integration. We add variables to the baseline gravity model that will help us explain the effects of EU and EFTA on bilateral trade flows. As noted in Chapter II, some gravity models introduce internal and external trade and distance proxies to measure the width of the borders, and others include trade bloc dummies to test how natural those blocs are. In this paper, we take a combined approach that tries to measure the width of the borders, which we call institutional effects, by also controlling for the specific time and individual effects of our sample. Our approach adds another dimension to the surveyed studies by estimating a panel data model and uses other techniques in order to account for some of the problems generated by this estimation. More specifically, we estimate an Instrumental Variables General Least Squares (IV-GLS) model developed by Hausman and Taylor (1981). This will allow us to instrument for some endogenous time-varying determinants within a setup that includes time-invariant regressors, which would otherwise be swept out from the estimation. III.2.2. Data and Proxies Our sample contains annual data from 1960 to 1997 for twenty-one developed OECD countries 9 and the RW. We included the latter as the twenty-second country to consider the total trade flows of each country in our sample. As the common feature in gravity models, our dependent variable is bilateral exports between these twenty- 9 The OECD countries are the same used in Chapter I: Australia, Austria, Brussels + Luxembourg, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK, and the US. 9

10 two countries. Thus, we are working with 462 pairs of countries per year, which without considering missing data becomes a total of 15,178 observations. Bilateral exports and exports price indices are provided by the Directions of Trade Statistics (IMF), and the constant mass measures by the World Development Indicators (World Bank). Pairwise great circle distance measures were taken from Frankel, Stein and Wei (1995) and Wei and Frankel (1995). We created the dummy variables. Our model is based upon four main determinants of bilateral exports: (i) the baseline gravity variables; (ii) the integration effects; (iii) the time effects; (iv) the individual countries characteristics. Each of them comprises a set of regressors. Meanwhile the first two sets capture the main economic and institutional determinants of bilateral exports flows; (iii) and (iv) allow us to explore further the stylised facts described in Chapter I. III The Baseline Gravity Variables Like most of the studies within the gravity framework, our specification includes the following baseline variables: Mass of both importer and exporter countries. In order to capture the exporter s production we take its GDP, and to proxy the importing country s absorption we use GNP. They are estimated separately to explain exports, as opposed to trade flows, and there is no prior reason to impose a common coefficient between them. Wealth of both exporting and importing countries, as a means of reflecting each country s prosperity. The proxies used are GDP (GNP) per capita for the exporter (importer). 10 Dissimilarity between trading countries, to reflect the relative wealth between them. We measure it as the absolute difference between the wealth of exporting and importing countries. This variable is partly included to control for the potential multicollinearity between the mass and wealth measures. 11 Transport costs, proxied by the great circle physical distance between the capital cities 12 of the trading countries and an adjacency dummy variable. 10 Including global per capita GDP together with GDP is equivalent to taking the latter with population, as Brun, Guillaumont and de Melo (1998) show. 11 One of the ways of solving this problem is to formalise a relationship among these regressors. 12 As will be discussed in the next chapter, a better way of capturing the transport costs involved in trade would be to find a measure of economic distance. 10

11 Linguistic ties, given that having a language in common may have an impact on transaction costs and increase the transborder contacts and information flows. III The Integration (institutional) Effects As mentioned in Chapter II, some of the literature uses the gravity equation to measure the width of the borders between two countries. However, this approach needs not only external but also internal bilateral trade and distance measures. For most countries, internal trade and distance proxies are difficult to find, and thus require ad-hoc calculations. Another way of measuring trade integration effects is to estimate a gravity equation for international trade flows, including dummies to account for the determinants of regionalisation among countries. We consider the latter approach more accurate and less sensitive to the calculations adopted, given that it only relies on observed data. In order to test for the EU trade integration process itself, i.e. to distinguish between globalisation and European integration effects, we add the following variables to the baseline gravity model: An EU and an EFTA dummy variables to reflect the time-average effect of the trade between two EU or EFTA member countries. They include the countries joining these blocs at each point in time, and thus vary both through time and across individuals. The idea is to consider the EU (EFTA) as one single country (with the bilateral internal trade given by the individual members), and measure the width of its border with non-eu (EFTA) countries. Some of our panel data specifications include a timeinteracting EU dummy to analyse the evolution of the EU institutional effect over time. For capturing the external effect 13 of the EU enlargements, three types of dummies for exporting countries were included: Enlargement: indicate the long-run external effects of each EU enlargement. New member: to capture the medium-run external effects of a country being a new EU partner. Joining country: to look at the short-run (or first-year impact) of joining EU members. 11

12 III Unobservable Time Effects and Country Characteristics As described in Chapter I, along the period economic conditions have changed considerably. Hence, accounting for unobservable time effects is useful to capture certain trade determinants that could bias our estimates of EU integration. Time effects can be partly due to the globalisation process. Depending on the specification of the model, we proxy globalisation effects with a time trend or time dummies. The former measures the average effects and the latter is useful to analyse the time effects evolution at each point in time and to identify structural time breaks in the sample. Following Brun, Guillaumont and de Melo (1998), we include a linear time trend. We also tried to include a quadratic time trend, 14 but this was not significantly different from zero. Country individual characteristics can be proxied by including n-1 exporting country dummies, taking as base country the RW. Hence, these dummies measure the relative impact of each exporter to the bilateral trade flows with respect to the RW s. The inclusion of these country-specific effects is important to capture any determinant not accounted for in the mass and wealth measures. This not the same as estimating panel data individual effects, since given our individuals are pairs of countries. III.2.3. Parameters of Interest Incorporating the four sets of regressors described in the previous section, the general log linear specification for our gravity model is: (III.10) where: x, m exporting and importing countries, respectively. X xmt natural logarithm of real bilateral exports between x and m in year t. M xt and M mt natural logarithms of real masses of x and m (respectively) in year t. Mpc xt and Mpc mt natural logarithms of real wealth of x and m (respectively) in year t. DISIM xmt natural logarithm of dissimilarity between x and m in year t. 13 Eichengreen and Irwin (1998) add this dummy for only one of the two countries participating in the trade arrangement to test for the external effect of the grouping on trade with nonmembers. 12

13 DIST xm natural logarithm of distance between x and m. 15 D xm is a partitioned matrix of dummy variables to control for adjacency (ADJ xm) and linguistic ties (LINGTIE xm) between x and m:, and hence EU xmt and EFTA xmt dummy variables for common EU or EFTA membership in t. E xt a partitioned matrix to account for enlargement external effects:, and hence where: ENLARj xt = 1 from the t that x joined the EU onwards, if x joined the EU in the jth. enlargement. NEWj xt = 1 from the t that x was a new member of the EU until the following enlargement, if x joined the EU in the jth. enlargement. JOINj xt = 1 on the year of joining the EU if x joined in the jth. enlargement. for (j = 1, 2, 3) and zero otherwise. t linear time trend. T t set of T-1 time dummies, with 1960 as the base year. C x set of n-1 country dummies, with the RW as the base country. ε xmt error term. Let us first briefly describe the baseline parameters, i.e. the (i) set of regressors. Income (wealth) elasticities of bilateral exports for exporting and importing countries are α 1 and α 2 (α 3 and α 4), respectively. A positive α 5 indicates that two countries trade more with each other the more their wealth differs and could be interpreted as favouring comparative advantage inter-industry trade theory. Conversely, a negative coefficient for DISIM xm, suggesting that two countries with similar endowments trade more, would support an intra-industry trade explanation. Given that we take DIST xm, ADJ xm and LINGTIE xm as proxies for transportation and transaction costs, we expect α 6 14 They expect a concave evolution of the time trend, mainly due to the 1970s oil shocks and the contrashocks of 1985 and late 1990s. 15 Although the Newtonian formula indicates that square distance enters the equation, we follow the usual approach of including a linear distance, since the former was not statistically significant. 13

14 <0, and the vector α 7 to have positive elements. In other words, the greater the distance between two countries, the smaller their trade (ceteris paribus), and the greater the link between two countries (either geographical or cultural), the greater the amount of bilateral trade between them. Our main interest is in the β coefficients, i.e. the institutional effects of the creation of the EU and EFTA on bilateral exports. These dummies take the value of one if both countries in the trading pair belong to the corresponding trade agreement in year t. For example, the pair France-Italy will have a 1 for the whole period, whereas France-Spain will only have a one since 1986, when the latter became a member of the EU, and similarly for EFTA. Hence, the base categories for the EU (EFTA) dummy is composed by the pairs of non-eu (EFTA) with non-eu (EFTA) countries and those of EU (EFTA) with non-eu (EFTA) members. The definition of our EU dummy differs with that used in Frankel (1997), where the EC bloc dummy does not vary over time. In a panel data model, the EU effect is composed of β 1 and β 3. The latter is the EU effect at each point in time. If the former were not included, the EU estimate would be biased (i.e., we allow for a non-zero origin of the trended EU coefficient). These semielasticities indicate that two EU members trade more with one another than predicted by their natural trade determinants and the average behaviour of the developed OECD countries. In other words, it suggests an increase in intra-bloc trade. We look at the external effects of the three EU enlargements with the vector of coefficients β 4. To differentiate between the speeds of adjustment of each group of joiners, we define three types of external effects of each enlargement depending on its persistence over time. The long-run (ENLARj xt) measures the effect of joiners since they became EU members; the medium-run effect (NEWj xt) shows the period during which joiners are new members of the EU; and the short-run (JOINj xt) captures the one-year effect of joining the EU. In order to facilitate the interpretation of these enlargement dummies, it is convenient to clarify the base countries of these dummies: The base countries for ENLAR1 xt are all but the UK, Denmark and Ireland for all t, and all countries for all t < ENLAR2 xt has all countries other than the Mediterranean new members for all t, Greece for all t < 1981, and Portugal and Spain for all t < 1986 as base. For ENLAR3 xt the base are all countries but Austria, Finland and Sweden for all t, and all countries for all t <

15 The base countries for NEW1 xt are all but the three first joiners for all t, and all countries for all t < 1973 and t In NEW2 xt, all except the Mediterranean countries for all t, Greece for all t < 1981 and t 1995, and Portugal and Spain for all t < 1986 and t 1995; and for ENLAR3 xt the non-eu15 and the EC12 members for all t, and all countries for all t < The base countries for JOIN1 xt are all but the first joiners for all t, and all countries for all t 1973; for JOIN2 xt, all countries except the Mediterranean for all t, Greece for all t 1981, and Spain and Portugal for all t 1986; and for ENLAR3 xt all countries except the last joiners for all t, and all countries for all t Hence, for example, a positive and significant indicates that Denmark, Ireland and the UK increased their bilateral exports relatively more than the other EU and OECD countries. A negative indicates a medium-run decrease in the bilateral exports due to Greece, Portugal and Spain joining the EC. A positive shows a short-run increase in the bilateral exports of Austria, Finland and Sweden after joining the EU. In addition, a positive ϕ indicates that on average, globalisation (among other unobservable time effects) increases bilateral exports. 16 Similarly, a negative γ t for a given period indicates that unobservable time effects decreased bilateral exports compared to the beginning of the period. Finally, a negative coefficient for a particular exporting country (δ x ) suggests that this has a smaller impact on bilateral trade flows than the RW s. We will interchange some of the proxies defined in (ii)-(iv) according to the different dimensions of the alternative methods estimated, without any loss of generality or change in the interpretation of the results obtained. III.4. The Results This section presents the results for the three methods described in III.3. In sum, SURE, accounts for the time correlation between the gravity cross-sections, whereas GLS controls for unobserved time and individual specific effects. Finally, IV-GLS 16 This could also be indicating a positive globalisation effect lower, in absolute value, than the other unobservable time effects. 15

16 solves the endogeneity problem together with estimating the marginal effects of the time-invariant regressors. III.4.1. SURE Estimation The first step towards estimating our gravity model is to run cross-section estimations. This allows us to test for the baseline model predictions, together with the additional trade determinants included in our model. Following Wei (1996) and Helliwell (1996, 1997), we estimate a system of cross-section equations of the form of (III.11) for each time period of our sample. The Breusch-Pagan test rejects the null hypothesis of a diagonal variance-covariance of the estimated errors matrix, thus confirming the presumed time correlation between the countries cross-sections for different years. This means that it is appropriate to estimate a SURE system of gravity cross-section equations, since it links them through their error terms. These reflect, among other things, the time differences between the cross sections. Although estimating cross sections is not the most efficient way of analysing the effects of different regressors on bilateral trade flows, they allow us to look at the time paths of the estimated export elasticities. Moreover, in this setting we can test for structural change in the coefficients. The overall fit of the model is similar to the ones reported in previous studies. An increasing Adjusted R-squared, with a mean of 86%, shows the good joint significance of the regressors in explaining the bilateral exports. 17 For convenience, we present here the estimated coefficients in graphs. The values for these coefficients and the result of the Breusch-Pagan test can be found in Appendix B. III Baseline gravity variables Graphs III.1., III.2. and III.3. show the estimated elasticities and semi-elasticities of bilateral exports with respect to the baseline gravity variables. These are the coefficients of the estimated SURE model for the masses of exporting and importing countries, the distance between them, their wealth and their common characteristics. The mass elasticities of the bilateral exports predicted by our model are similar to those found in the literature. We find that on average, a marginal increase in a 17 The number of observations decreases when estimating a SURE, given that availability of observations around the whole time period is imposed. However, estimating a SURE for less years, and then getting more observations per year, gave smaller Adjusted-R 2. 16

17 country s real size (GDP) or in its real absorption (GNP) generates a significant 18 average increase of 0.7% in both its real 19 exports to and its imports from the other developed OECD countries and the RW. If two countries were twice as apart from each other as from a third country, their trade is on average 0.9% lower. Graph III.1. shows the evolution through time of these elasticities. Graph III.1. Wald tests indicate a significant change over the period for GDP x and for DIST xm. The significantly decreasing relative importance of the exporting country s mass measure, indicates that the size of a country has lost some relevance in explaining its exports. Moreover, size has become a relatively better determinant for the imports of a country, thus indicating a higher preference for imported goods of industrial countries. In order to verify some of the facts described in Chapter I, we performed various Wald tests to account for the significant structural change in the coefficients over time. 20 We found that the break-up of Bretton Woods (1971) has increased significantly the exporter s income elasticity of exports for OECD countries. The drop in this elasticity, which may be partly due to the first oil crisis, is also significant. We also find that the second oil crisis has apparently increased significantly the sensitivity of exports to the importer s income. The relatively stationary pattern around a significantly decreasing trend of the distance elasticity of exports might be due to a shrinking in the transport costs during 18 Unless otherwise stated, this refers to a significantly different from zero at a 1% level. 19 From now on we will refer to real economic variables. 20 The null hypothesis for these tests is that the corresponding coefficient did not change from one year to the following. 17

18 the last four decades. Moreover, this finding may also be indicating a missspecification problem because of only including a geographical (constant) distance measure, which we tackle in Chapter IV. Graph III.2. shows that the estimated exporting country s wealth effect has been steady until the early 1980s, when it begins to decline. Moreover, this coefficient only becomes non-significantly different from zero towards the end of the period. Throughout the period considered, a one-percentage change in the wealth of a country increases its exports by almost the same amount, whereas decreases its imports by 0.8% on average. Graph III.2. Wald tests indicate a significant change over the period for GDPpc x GDPpc m (at a 5% level). (at a 1% level) and for The negative (and generally significant) elasticity of the bilateral exports with respect to the importer s wealth seems to contradict the common finding of a positive correlation between a country s wealth and its imports. This may be due to a higher domestic income effect, which makes people consume relatively more domestically produced goods the wealthier they are. As mentioned above, to control for multicollinearity of wealth and mass measures, we include DISIM xm. While its mean increases considerably over time, its elasticity is rather small compared to the wealth effects. We find that if two countries become 1% more similar, their trade is on average a 0.1% lower. In addition, the significance of the coefficient varies over time. The positive coefficient of DISIM xm supports the hypothesis of high correlation between GDP per capita differences and differences in factor endowments. This 18

19 correlation leads us to conclude that smaller differences between countries could reduce trade, especially inter-industry trade driven by comparative advantage. Hence, our results would be more in favour of a Heckscher-Ohlin explanation of trade flows. Moreover, this result opposes the Linder Hypothesis, where trade is higher between countries with similar living standards, given that they share a broader range of goods to trade. Testing for yearly structural breaks in these variables we found that the second oil crisis has increased significantly the sensitivity of exports to the importer s wealth and its dissimilarity with respect to its partner. Graph III.3. shows the path of the adjacency (ADJ xm) and linguistic ties (LINGTIE xm) effects on two countries exports. 21 While a marginal effect of being next to the importing country would make the exports of a country an average of 0.4% greater, sharing a common language would increase its exports by an average of 0.6%. However, these results should be considered with care, given that these coefficients on both dummies are in general not significantly different from zero, even at a 10% level. Graph III.3. Wald tests indicate that neither ADJ xm nor LINGTIE xm have experienced a significant change, even at a 10% level. Although not too significant, the trend seems to indicate that sharing a common language has become less important for doing business during the last four decades. This may be due to the widespread usage of English as the international business language. The fact that having a common border is slightly becoming a better determinant of bilateral trade patterns is perhaps related to a decrease in the transportation costs over the period considered. Given that our time-invariant 19

20 distance measure does not capture these effects, we would expect to account for them by finding a measure of economic distance that varies through time. III The integration effects The semi-elasticity of bilateral trade with respect to the EU dummy allows us to measure the so-called border effect of the European Union trade with non-eu countries. Graph III.4. shows the evolution of the implied integration elasticities (or estimated coefficients) for EU and EFTA blocs. 22 We find that on average EU membership has increased bilateral exports by 26%, 23 whereas this has decreased for two members of the EFTA by approximately 16% (although this is not too significantly different from zero). 24 The decreasing path of the EU xm coefficient since the late 1960s may be partly due to the consolidation of the bloc after each enlargement, thus leaving less and less scope to trade with the new joining countries. However, we will see later that unobservable time and individual effects account for much of this trend. Graph III.4. Wald tests indicate that only EFTA xm changed significantly over the period (at a 1% level). Although, as far as we are aware, there are no studies that estimate the evolution of the EU integration, our findings coincide with other results found in the literature, for somewhat different set-ups and models. 21 In this case, we refer to the vector of coefficients in equation (III.11). 22 External effects of exporting EU countries were not significantly different from zero at a 10%, and hence were not included. 23 In this case, it is more convenient to work with 100% changes of the explanatory variables. 24 To a smaller extent, EFTA dummy depends inversely on the enlargements of the EU, since countries like Denmark, the UK and Finland left it as were joining the EU. 20

21 Nitsch (1999) estimates a SURE system of gravity equations using internal and external measures of trade, masses and distance, for the first twelve EU members 25 over the period Bearing in mind the different methodologies and data employed, our results do not differ from his findings of a decreasing home bias. 26 Frankel (1997) estimates gravity cross-section equations for every-five years and finds that the EU effect is not significant until 1985, when it attains a 20%, which then rises to 30% in The positive trend of our EU integration indicator during the 1960s reflects the increase in trade integration of the EEC6 countries. This was mainly favoured by the stability of having their currencies fully convertible at fixed, but adjustable, exchange rates ruled by the Bretton Woods System. Our indicator also shows a positive and significant 27 response to the completion of the customs union in The benefit of the EU effect slowed in 1970, mainly due to the inflationary pressures on the stable fixed exchange rates system, which drove to the adoption of flexible exchange rates regimes by De Grauwe (1988) finds that, although with relatively stable exchange rates, EEC6 members experienced a strong decline in their tradeintegration process since the 1970s. In the early 1970s, EU integration seemed to be recovering its upward path. However, the first oil shock of 1973 exacerbated the very strong inflationary pressures and plunged most oil importing countries into massive trade deficits. This led most OECD countries in general to adopt national protectionist measures, thus reducing their trade. Given the relatively high trade integration achieved by the EEC6, this change in policies might have dampened their intra-eec trade even further. Moreover, EU effect s main drops coincide with the three enlargements of the European Union. 28 This finding can be explained by three different motives, concerning the trade orientation of joiners, their size and the external economic circumstances of each period. 25 Given the period of his sample, Nitsch does not consider the third enlargement. 26 Although Nitsch employs a different methodology, this variable is capturing the EU effect, comparable with our EU dummy. 27 We ran Wald tests to check for structural changes on the EU coefficients, and rejected the null of equal coefficients at a 1% level. 28 This is the other reason why Frankel (1997) adopts as time-invariant EU dummy. However, given that our arguments are plausible with the stylised facts described in Chapter I, we will keep a time-varying EU dummy. 21

22 The trade orientation cause entails a learning process for the trade patterns among the old and the new EU countries when the latter first enter the union. This process partly determines the extent to which the integration coefficient falls and then recuperates. 29 By learning process we mean the adjustment that new members necessarily do in order to catch up with the degree of integration achieved by the old EU countries. For example, in the first enlargement, the three new members had to go through a transitional process to finally approach the degree of integration achieved in fifteen years by the EEC6. Moreover, specially UK s stronger ties with non-eec6 countries also contributed to its learning process. The second and third causes can also be better observed taking the first enlargement. The significant 30 decrease in the EU coefficient may also be picking up the arrival of a big country, the UK, into the EU group. Finally, the temporary increase in the weight of imports from OPEC countries during the 1960s may have contributed to lowering the intra-eec trade share during the early 1970s. In other words, the first oil shock, together with the inclusion of three countries that handled their economic policies differently to the EEC6 s, might also have affected trade patterns between the EEC9. Other results of the yearly-structural change Wald tests on the EU estimated coefficients indicate that neither the establishment of the EMS (1979) nor the inclusion of Greece (1981) significantly affected EU integration. Spain and Portugal EU only had a significant negative effect on EU trade integration one year after joining this bloc during the same year that the SEA was adopted (1987). The late 1980s sought a change in trade patterns in favour of intra-eec trade. The early 1990s significant recovery may have been partly favoured by the repercussion of the SEA (1987) and the Maastricht treaty of EU trade integration appears to recover a slightly positive trend in 1993, with a smaller but significant learning process negative effect after the third enlargement. Finally, the decrease of the EFTA coefficient since the first EU enlargement, which coincided with the loss of two important member countries, indicates an increase in the relative importance of the EU over the other European free trade agreement. This could be partly explained by the more limited agreements taken by EFTA members, as explained in Chapter I. Conversely, EU countries, by adopting a customs union by 29 The decrease in the significance of this dummy after the mid-1990s does not allow us to observe a reversion of the trend after the third enlargement. 30 Wald test rejected at a 1% level. 22

23 signing the Treaty of Rome, and then an economic union with the Maastricht Treaty, compromised committed themselves to a higher degree of economic integration. III.5. Main Findings This chapter has focused on three methods to measure EU trade integration. Given that there is a significant time-correlation between the errors of each cross-section gravity equation, we have first estimated a SURE model for a system of thirty-eight cross-sections. We find that being in the EU increases bilateral exports by 26%. Because of the need to control for unobserved individual effects without sweeping out the effects of observable time-invariant regressors, our second chosen method is a panel data GLS. Given the panel data time dimension, we add a globalisation proxy and the high degrees of freedom allow us to incorporate long, medium and short-run external effects of the three EU enlargements. However, GLS seems to derive inconsistent estimators, may be due to an endogeneity problem between masses and exports. Hence, we finally adopt the HT method that allows us to instrument the mass variables by using internal instruments and is able to estimate the marginal effects of time-invariant regressors. Rejecting the equality between the estimated coefficients of HT and GLS methods, we can conclude that the former derives (at least) more consistent estimators. Our main general result is that not accounting for unobservable individual effects and for the endogeneity of mass measures biases upwards the EU effect on bilateral trade. Since HT, unlike SURE, controls for unobserved individual effects and because, converse to both SURE and GLS, it solves the endogeneity problem, we next analyse in greater detail the EU integration effects results from the HT method. EU integration was positively affected by globalisation: not including time effects (model A) gives us an EU coefficient of 12%, whereas doing so (model B) leads to an EU estimate of 20%. In addition, accounting for the external effects of enlargements (model C) take much of the EU effect: it goes down to 3%. Our results are consistent with Frankel s (1997), who finds an EEC12 bloc effect of 16%, and a decrease in the EC bloc when including openness effects. With regard to the significant enlargement effects, our findings coincide with the evolution of the EU effect for the SURE method. The first and third enlargements show positive long-run external effects on bilateral exports of 48% and 32%, 23

Working Papers in Economics

Working Papers in Economics University of Innsbruck Working Papers in Economics Foreign Direct Investment and European Integration in the 90 s Peter Egger and Michael Pfaffermayr 2002/2 Institute of Economic Theory, Economic Policy

More information

The Economic and Social Review, 30 (4): Economic and Social Studies, Dublin.

The Economic and Social Review, 30 (4): Economic and Social Studies, Dublin. Provided by the author(s) and University College Dublin Library in accordance with publisher policies. Please cite the published version when available. Title Explaining the volume of north south trade

More information

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias Michele Fratianni * and Chang Hoon Oh** *Indiana University and Università Politecnica delle Marche **Indiana University Abstract We test the relationship

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction Jiri Mazurek School of Business Administration in Karviná 13. January 2014 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/52920/

More information

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand Murat Genç University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand Email address for correspondence: murat.genc@otago.ac.nz 30 April 2010 PRELIMINARY WORK IN PROGRESS NOT FOR

More information

The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization in Central and Eastern Europe

The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization in Central and Eastern Europe Working Papers No. 21/2011 (61) Andrzej Cieślik Jan Hagemejer The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization in Central and Eastern Europe Warsaw 2011 The Effectiveness of Preferential Trade Liberalization

More information

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection 1 Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection Erica Owen University of Minnesota November 13, 2009 Research Question 2 Low levels of FDI restrictions in developed democracies are

More information

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES By Bart Verspagen* Second draft, July 1998 * Eindhoven University of Technology, Faculty of Technology Management, and MERIT, University of Maastricht. Email:

More information

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach 103 An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach Shaista Khan 1 Ihtisham ul Haq 2 Dilawar Khan 3 This study aimed to investigate Pakistan s bilateral trade flows with major

More information

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins Shan Jiang November 7, 2007 Abstract Recent theories suggest that better information in destination countries could reduce firm s fixed export costs, lower uncertainty

More information

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads 1 Online Appendix for Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads Sarath Balachandran Exequiel Hernandez This appendix presents a descriptive

More information

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP) GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP) Intro: increasing returns to scale and international trade

More information

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS Export, Migration, and Costs of Market Entry: Evidence from Central European Firms 1 The Regional Economics Applications Laboratory (REAL) is a unit in the University of Illinois focusing on the development

More information

Effects of the EU-Turkish Customs Union on the Intra-EU Trade Flows

Effects of the EU-Turkish Customs Union on the Intra-EU Trade Flows Department of Economics Effects of the EU-Turkish Customs Union on the Intra-EU Trade Flows NEKN01 Economics: Master Essay I Author: Erik Dahlberg (881017-0392) Supervisor: Joakim Gullstrand Presented:

More information

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 Authorised by S. McManus, ACTU, 365 Queen St, Melbourne 3000. ACTU D No. 172/2018

More information

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports Abstract: The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports Yingting Yi* KU Leuven (Preliminary and incomplete; comments are welcome) This paper investigates whether WTO promotes

More information

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, 1870 1970 IDS WORKING PAPER 73 Edward Anderson SUMMARY This paper studies the impact of globalisation on wage inequality in eight now-developed countries during the

More information

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa International Affairs Program Research Report How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa Report Prepared by Bilge Erten Assistant

More information

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust? Comment on Corak (2013) Bradley J. Setzler 1 Presented to Economics 350 Department of Economics University of Chicago setzler@uchicago.edu January 15, 2014 1 Thanks to James Heckman for many helpful comments.

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

Determinants of Intra-Industry Trade between Zimbabwe and its Trading Partners in the Southern African Development Community Region ( )

Determinants of Intra-Industry Trade between Zimbabwe and its Trading Partners in the Southern African Development Community Region ( ) Journal of Social Sciences 5(1): 16-21, 2009 ISSN 1549-3652 2009 Science Publications Determinants of Intra-Industry Trade between Zimbabwe and its Trading Partners in the Southern African Development

More information

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Martin Falk FIW workshop foreign direct investment Wien, 16 Oktober 2008 Motivation large and persistent trade deficits USA, Greece, Portugal,

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

ROMANIA-EU ACTUAL AND POTENTIAL TRADE

ROMANIA-EU ACTUAL AND POTENTIAL TRADE Annals of the University of Petro ani, Economics, 5 (2005), 117-124 117 ROMANIA-EU ACTUAL AND POTENTIAL TRADE ANNA FERRAGINA, GIORGIA GIOVANNETTI, FRANCESCO PASTORE * ABSTRACT: This is a companion paper

More information

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016 Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016 1 Table of content Table of Content Output 11 Employment 11 Europena migration and the job market 63 Box 1. Estimates of VAR system for Labor

More information

3. THE BALTIC SEA REGION S ROLE IN TRADE INTEGRATION

3. THE BALTIC SEA REGION S ROLE IN TRADE INTEGRATION 3. THE BALTIC SEA REGION S ROLE IN TRADE INTEGRATION Tiiu Paas, Egle Tafenau Introduction International trade is the most expedient economic factor in pushing economies into integration. International

More information

The Trade Potential of Pakistan: An Application of the Gravity Model

The Trade Potential of Pakistan: An Application of the Gravity Model The Lahore Journal of Economics 16 : 1 (Summer 2011): pp. 23-62 The Trade Potential of Pakistan: An Application of the Gravity Model Nazia Gul * and Hafiz M. Yasin ** Abstract This paper attempts to estimate

More information

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH Edris H. Seid The Horn Economic & Social Policy Institute (HESPI) 2013 African Economic Conference Johannesburg, South Africa

More information

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development December 26 1 Introduction For many OECD countries,

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

Immigration, Emigration and Trade in Sweden

Immigration, Emigration and Trade in Sweden Södertörns Högskola Department of Economics, Master Thesis Immigration, Emigration and Trade in Sweden An Empirical Analysis: (2000-2010) Supervisor: Professor Mats A Bergman Author: Sobia Safdar 20/1/2012

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) MIT Spatial Economics Reading Group Presentation Adam Guren May 13, 2010 Testing the New Economic

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

How Does Aid Support Women s Economic Empowerment?

How Does Aid Support Women s Economic Empowerment? How Does Aid Support Women s Economic Empowerment? OECD DAC NETWORK ON GENDER EQUALITY (GENDERNET) 2018 Key messages Overall bilateral aid integrating (mainstreaming) gender equality in all sectors combined

More information

Shake Hands or Shake Apart? Pre-war Global Trade and Currency. Blocs: the Role of the Japanese Empire

Shake Hands or Shake Apart? Pre-war Global Trade and Currency. Blocs: the Role of the Japanese Empire HEI Working Paper No: 05/2006 Shake Hands or Shake Apart? Pre-war Global Trade and Currency Blocs: the Role of the Japanese Empire Toshihiro Okubo Graduate Institute of International Studies Abstract Despite

More information

The Effect of Membership in the European Monetary Union on Trade Between Member Countries (An Empirical Study)

The Effect of Membership in the European Monetary Union on Trade Between Member Countries (An Empirical Study) The Effect of Membership in the European Monetary Union on Trade Between Member Countries (An Empirical Study) Ihor Soroka Abstract The question of whether or not to adopt the euro is a very important

More information

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients) Section 2 Impact of trade on income inequality As described above, it has been theoretically and empirically proved that the progress of globalization as represented by trade brings benefits in the form

More information

What Creates Jobs in Global Supply Chains?

What Creates Jobs in Global Supply Chains? Christian Viegelahn (with Stefan Kühn) Research Department, International Labour Organization (ILO)* Employment Effects of Services Trade Reform Council on Economic Policies (CEP) November 25, 2015 *All

More information

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010 The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 996 to 2 Authors: Jonathan Fox, Freie Universitaet; Sebastian Klüsener MPIDR;

More information

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey 3 Wage adjustment and in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey This box examines the link between collective bargaining arrangements, downward wage rigidities and. Several past studies

More information

Trade, Diaspora and Migration to New Zealand

Trade, Diaspora and Migration to New Zealand Trade, Diaspora and Migration to New Zealand Paper prepared for the NZIER 50th Anniversary Research Award David Law Murat Genç John Bryant 31 March 2009 Executive summary Debates about the economic contribution

More information

Employment Outlook 2017

Employment Outlook 2017 Annexes Chapter 3. How technology and globalisation are transforming the labour market Employment Outlook 2017 TABLE OF CONTENTS ANNEX 3.A3 ADDITIONAL EVIDENCE ON POLARISATION BY REGION... 1 ANNEX 3.A4

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin February 20, 2006 Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The Group of Eight (G8) is an unofficial forum of the heads of state of the eight leading industrialized

More information

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization 3 Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization Given the evidence presented in chapter 2 on preferences about globalization policies, an important question to explore is whether any opinion cleavages

More information

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD o: o BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD Table of Contents Acronyms and Abbreviations 11 List of TL2 Regions 13 Preface 16 Executive Summary 17 Parti Key Regional Trends and Policies

More information

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries. HIGHLIGHTS The ability to create, distribute and exploit knowledge is increasingly central to competitive advantage, wealth creation and better standards of living. The STI Scoreboard 2001 presents the

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

National borders and international trade: evidence from the European Union

National borders and international trade: evidence from the European Union National borders and international trade: evidence from the European Union Volker Nitsch Bankgesellschaft Berlin Abstract.In this paper the impact of national borders on international trade within the

More information

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Industrial & Labor Relations Review Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 60, Issue 3 2007 Article 5 Labor Market Institutions and Wage Inequality Winfried Koeniger Marco Leonardi Luca Nunziata IZA, University of Bonn, University of

More information

DPRU WORKING PAPERS. The Determinants of Intra-Regional Trade in Southern Africa with Specific Reference to South African and the Rest of the Region

DPRU WORKING PAPERS. The Determinants of Intra-Regional Trade in Southern Africa with Specific Reference to South African and the Rest of the Region DPRU WORKING PAPERS The Determinants of Intra-Regional Trade in Southern Africa with Specific Reference to South African and the Rest of the Region Rashad Cassim No 01/51 June 2001 ISBN: 0-7992-2057-4

More information

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY. Pınar Narin Emirhan 1. Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw)

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY. Pınar Narin Emirhan 1. Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw) DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY Pınar Narin Emirhan 1 Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw) Abstract This paper aims to test the determinants of international

More information

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states Skupnik IZA Journal of Migration 2014, 3:15 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Open Access EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states Christoph Skupnik Correspondence: christoph.skupnik@fu-berlin.de School

More information

The Role of Income and Immigration Policies in Attracting International Migrants

The Role of Income and Immigration Policies in Attracting International Migrants D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R S E R I E S IZA DP No. 6655 The Role of Income and Immigration Policies in Attracting International Migrants Francesc Ortega Giovanni Peri June 2012 Forschungsinstitut zur

More information

5. Destination Consumption

5. Destination Consumption 5. Destination Consumption Enabling migrants propensity to consume Meiyan Wang and Cai Fang Introduction The 2014 Central Economic Working Conference emphasised that China s economy has a new normal, characterised

More information

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA by Robert E. Lipsey & Fredrik Sjöholm Working Paper 166 December 2002 Postal address: P.O. Box 6501, S-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden.

More information

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach European Journal of Sustainable Development (2014), 3, 3, 149-158 ISSN: 2239-5938 Doi: 10.14207/ejsd.2014.v3n3p149 The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach Marku Megi 1 ABSTRACT Foreign

More information

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK ANALYSIS DANMARKS NATIONALBANK 10 JANUARY 2019 NO. 1 Intra-EU labour mobility dampens cyclical pressures EU labour mobility dampens labour market pressures Eastern enlargements increase access to EU labour

More information

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA Ismet Voka University, Aleksander Moisiu Durres, ALBANIA Bardhyl Dauti State University of Tetovo Tetovo,

More information

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper)

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper) INTERNATIONAL TRADE (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper) J. Peter Neary University College Dublin 25 September 2003 Address for correspondence:

More information

What is the Role of Cultural Factors in the Gravity model of FDI?

What is the Role of Cultural Factors in the Gravity model of FDI? What is the Role of Cultural Factors in the Gravity model of FDI? ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM Erasmus School of Economics Department of Economics Supervisor: Dr. E.M. Bosker Name: Diederick de Ruijter

More information

An Investigation of Brain Drain from Iran to OECD Countries Based on Gravity Model

An Investigation of Brain Drain from Iran to OECD Countries Based on Gravity Model Iranian Economic Review, Vol.15, No.29, Spring 2011 An Investigation of Brain Drain from Iran to OECD Countries Based on Gravity Model Heshmatollah Asgari Abstract B Received: 2010/12/27 Accepted: 2011/04/24

More information

Policy Discussion Paper

Policy Discussion Paper Policy Discussion Paper No. 97/11 University of Adelaide Adelaide SA 5005 Australia LABOUR STANDARDS AND TRADE FLOWS OF OECD COUNTRIES Cees van Beers October 1997 CIES POLICY DISCUSSION PAPER 97/11 LABOUR

More information

The migration of professionals within. the EU: any barriers left?

The migration of professionals within. the EU: any barriers left? The migration of professionals within the EU: any barriers left? Stella Capuano, Silvia Migali January 19, 2016 Abstract Despite the effort at EU level to harmonize the process of recognition of foreign

More information

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research hfi@nova.no Introduction Motivation Robin Hood paradox No robust effect of voter turnout on

More information

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT THE STUDENT ECONOMIC REVIEWVOL. XXIX GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT CIÁN MC LEOD Senior Sophister With Southeast Asia attracting more foreign direct investment than

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIETY D THESIS 2006 A GRAVITY MODEL FOR TRADE BETWEEN VIETNAM AND TWENTY-THREE EUROPEAN COUNTRIES

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIETY D THESIS 2006 A GRAVITY MODEL FOR TRADE BETWEEN VIETNAM AND TWENTY-THREE EUROPEAN COUNTRIES DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIETY D THESIS 2006 A GRAVITY MODEL FOR TRADE BETWEEN VIETNAM AND TWENTY-THREE EUROPEAN COUNTRIES Supervisor: Reza Mortazavi Author : Thai Tri Do Abstract This thesis examines

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

April aid spending by Development Assistance Committee (DAC) donors in factsheet

April aid spending by Development Assistance Committee (DAC) donors in factsheet April 2017 aid spending by Development Assistance Committee (DAC) donors in 2016 factsheet In this factsheet we provide an overview of key trends in official development assistance (ODA) emerging from

More information

Trading Goods or Human Capital

Trading Goods or Human Capital Trading Goods or Human Capital The Winners and Losers from Economic Integration Micha l Burzyński, Université catholique de Louvain, IRES Poznań University of Economics, KEM michal.burzynski@uclouvain.be

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning of the transitional arrangements Tatiana Fic, Dawn Holland and Paweł Paluchowski National Institute of Economic and Social

More information

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE DETERMINANTS OF FDI IN TUNISIA: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY THROUGH A GRAVITY MODEL

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE DETERMINANTS OF FDI IN TUNISIA: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY THROUGH A GRAVITY MODEL Asian Economic and Financial Review ISSN(e): 2222-6737/ISSN(p): 2305-2147 URL: www.aessweb.com THE DETERMINANTS OF FDI IN TUNISIA: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY THROUGH A GRAVITY MODEL Souad BANNOUR Ep SFAR 1 ---

More information

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, 1960-2005. Giovanni Peri, (University of California Davis, CESifo and NBER) October, 2009 Abstract A recent series of influential

More information

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Appendix to Sectoral Economies Appendix to Sectoral Economies Rafaela Dancygier and Michael Donnelly June 18, 2012 1. Details About the Sectoral Data used in this Article Table A1: Availability of NACE classifications by country of

More information

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development Eric A. Hanushek Stanford University in conjunction with Ludger Wößmann University of Munich and Ifo Institute Overview 1.

More information

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51 THE IMPACT OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION ON TRADE SHARE AND PER CAPITA GDP: EVIDENCE FROM SUB SAHARAN AFRICA Abdurohman Ali Hussien, Terrasserne 14, 2-256, Brønshøj 2700; Denmark ; abdurohman.ali.hussien@gmail.com

More information

8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy*

8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy* 8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy* Dennis Coates and Jac C. Heckelman The literature on growth across countries, regions and states has burgeoned in recent years. Mancur

More information

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Jun Saito, Senior Research Fellow Japan Center for Economic Research December 11, 2017 Is inequality widening in Japan? Since the publication of Thomas

More information

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective Richard Disney*, Andy McKay + & C. Rashaad Shabab + *Institute of Fiscal Studies, University of Sussex and University College,

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU Luminita VOCHITA, Lect, Ph.D. University of Craiova George CIOBANU,

More information

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis?

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis? 3 Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis? Tatu Vanhanen * Department of Political Science, University of Helsinki The purpose of this article is to explore the causes of the European

More information

The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach

The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach The political economy of electricity market liberalization: a cross-country approach Erkan Erdogdu PhD Candidate The 30 th USAEE/IAEE North American Conference California Room, Capital Hilton Hotel, Washington

More information

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS)

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS) Governance Institutions and FDI: An empirical study of top 30 FDI recipient countries ABSTRACT Bhavna Seth Assistant Professor in Economics Dyal Singh College, New Delhi E-mail: bhavna.seth255@gmail.com

More information

BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION AND ITS LINKS TO TRADE INTEGRATION IN NEW EU MEMBER STATES

BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION AND ITS LINKS TO TRADE INTEGRATION IN NEW EU MEMBER STATES BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION AND ITS LINKS TO TRADE INTEGRATION IN NEW EU MEMBER STATES IVAN SUTÓRIS Center for Economic Research and Graduate Education Economics Institute, Prague, Politických vězňů

More information

European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey

European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey International Journal of Business and Social Science Vol. 5, No. 13; December 2014 European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey Cynthia Royal Tori, PhD Valdosta State University Langdale

More information

Evaluation of Trade Dynamics in East Asia: Impact of Industrial Trade Structures on Australian Exports

Evaluation of Trade Dynamics in East Asia: Impact of Industrial Trade Structures on Australian Exports Evaluation of Trade Dynamics in East Asia: Impact of Industrial Trade Structures on Australian Exports By: Kevin Ma 1 Supervisor: A/Prof. Trevor Stegman Honours Thesis Bachelor of Economics (Financial

More information

Ever freer union? Economic freedom and the EU

Ever freer union? Economic freedom and the EU Introduction Ever freer union? Economic freedom and the EU Alexander Fritz Englund 1 By performing an econometric analysis on the Fraser Institute s Economic Freedom of the World: Annual Report 2015, it

More information

Economics of European Integration Lecture # 6 Migration and Growth

Economics of European Integration Lecture # 6 Migration and Growth Economics of European Integration Lecture # 6 Migration and Growth Winter Semester 2013/14 Gerald Willmann Gerald Willmann, Department of Economics, Bielefeld University Migration Facts and Theory Immigration:

More information

Impact of Trade blocs on Agricultural Trade and Policy Implications. for China: Gravity Model Study. Lin SUN

Impact of Trade blocs on Agricultural Trade and Policy Implications. for China: Gravity Model Study. Lin SUN Impact of Trade blocs on Agricultural Trade and Policy Implications for China: Gravity Model Study Lin SUN Department of Economics, College of Business Administration Zhejiang University of Technology

More information

Quantitative evidence of post-crisis structural macroeconomic changes

Quantitative evidence of post-crisis structural macroeconomic changes Quantitative evidence of post-crisis structural macroeconomic changes Roberto Camagni, Roberta Capello, Andrea Caragliu, Barbara Chizzolini Politecnico di Milano To be discussed at the Advisory Board Forum,

More information

Analysing Economic and Financial Power of Different Countries at the End of the Twentieth Century

Analysing Economic and Financial Power of Different Countries at the End of the Twentieth Century Modern Economy, 212, 3, 25-29 http://dx.doi.org/1.4236/me.212.3228 Published Online March 212 (http://www.scirp.org/journal/me) Analysing Economic and Financial Power of Different Countries at the End

More information

THE EFFECT OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY AND SOCIETY

THE EFFECT OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY AND SOCIETY THE EFFECT OF REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY AND SOCIETY A Thesis Submitted to the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences at Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements

More information

Delocation. and European integration SUMMARY. Is structural spending justified?

Delocation. and European integration SUMMARY. Is structural spending justified? Blackwell Oxford, ECOP Economic 0266-4658 2002-10 35 1000 Original DELOCATION Karen Delocation Is CEPR, structural Midelfart-Knarvik UK Article CES, Publishing Policy and spending AND European MSH, EUROPEAN

More information

International Economics, 10e (Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz) Chapter 2 World Trade: An Overview. 2.1 Who Trades with Whom?

International Economics, 10e (Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz) Chapter 2 World Trade: An Overview. 2.1 Who Trades with Whom? International Economics, 10e (Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz) Chapter 2 World Trade: An Overview 2.1 Who Trades with Whom? 1) Approximately what percent of all world production of goods and services is exported

More information

Forecasting EU-Romania Trade by Gravity Analysis

Forecasting EU-Romania Trade by Gravity Analysis Forecasting EU-Romania Trade by Gravity Analysis Anna Ferragina, Giorgia Giovannetti and Francesco Pastore Abstract # This paper attempts to forecast EU-Romania trade using the gravity approach developed

More information

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data 1 (11) Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data Survey response rates are declining at an alarming rate globally. Statisticians have traditionally used imputing

More information