Immigration and Spending on Public Education: California,

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Immigration and Spending on Public Education: California,"

Transcription

1 Immigration and Spending on Public Education: California, Daniele Coen-Pirani University of Pittsburgh This version: May Abstract The evolution of education spending in California has received plenty of attention from both academics and practitioners after this state s education finance reform in the 1970 s. This paper quantifies the contribution of immigration to the relative decline in elementary and secondary public education spending per student in California in the period A quantitative model of school choice and voting over public education is used to perform the counterfactual experiments of interest. The model predicts that education spending per student in California would have been 24 percent higher in the year 2000 if U.S. immigration had been restricted to its 1970 level. Keywords: Immigration, Public Education, Private Education, Education Finance Reform, California. JEL Classification: D7, F22, H52, H75, I22. Thanks to seminar participants at Carnegie Mellon, Notre Dame, Cleveland Fed, Federal Reserve Board, University of Pittsburgh, University of Montreal, McGill, RAND, West Virginia University, Econometric Society Meetings 2009 in San Francisco for useful comments. Special thanks, without implication, to two anonymous referees, Dennis Epple, Holger Sieg, Maria Ferreyra, Krishna Kumar, Steven Lugauer, Randy Walsh, Jon Sonstelie, and Chris Sleet for useful comments. 1

2 1 Introduction In this paper I study the impact of immigration on spending on elementary and secondary public education in California over the period In doing so the paper contributes to the debate on two important issues that have attracted much attention from policy makers and academics alike. The first debate concerns the effects of immigration on the wellbeing and economic outcomes of natives. While the literature has focused on the labor market impact of immigrants, less attention has been devoted to the interaction between immigrants and natives that occurs through government spending and taxes. 1 In particular, spending on public education is one of the most important items on the budget of state and local governments. The second debate concerns the significant decline in public education spending per student that occurred in California - the main immigrant-receiving state in the U.S. - relative to the rest of the country since the early 1970 s. While the economics literature has emphasized the role played by education finance reform from a foundation system to a state system, little attention has been paid to the underlying demographic trends over this period. 2 According to U.S. Census data, school-age children from households whose head had immigrated to the U.S. after 1970 accounted for about 40 percent of California s total enrollment in elementary and secondary school in 2000 relative to 8 percent in The corresponding figure for the rest of the U.S. in 2000 was 13 percent. In all Census years, California households whose head had immigrated to the U.S. after 1970 had, on average, more school-age children than native households, and more than twice as many in 1990 and Immigrant-headed households accounted for about 30 percent of all households in California in 2000, while the corresponding figure for the rest of the U.S. was only 8 percent. 3 1 See Borjas (2003) and Ottaviano and Peri (2008) for different views on the effect of immigration on the wages of native workers. Borjas (1999) reviews the literature on immigration, and Borjas (1994) contains a review of the literature on immigration and government outlays and taxes. 2 See Silva and Sonstelie (1995) and Fernandez and Rogerson (1999) for analysis of education finance reform in California. 3 In the rest of the paper I refer to an immigrant-headed or simply immigrant household as a household headed by an immigrant who immigrated to the U.S. after 1970 and to a native-headed or simply native 2

3 The paper develops a quantitative political-economy model of education spending to answer the following counterfactual question: what would have been the level of education spending per student in California in if U.S. immigration had been restricted to its 1970 level? The main result is that immigration has played a quantitatively important role in the decline in education spending per student. Specifically, I find that in the academic year education spending per student in California was about $1,482 (in 1999 dollars) lower than it would have been if U.S. immigration had been restricted to its 1970 level. This represents about 24 percent of actual education spending per student in California in For sake of comparison, education finance reform is estimated to have reduced education spending per student in California by percent (Fernandez and Rogerson, 1999 and Hoxby, 2001). In order to answer the counterfactual question above, I employ a political-economy model where California households vote over expenditures on public education in a state-wide voting round. The latter setting is consistent with the institutional setup of education finance in California where since the early 1980 s current spending for elementary and secondary public education has been largely equalized across students and spending decisions are centralized at the state-level. 4 In the model, households are assumed to be heterogeneous with respect to their income, number of school-age children, immigration status, and the weight they attach to education relative to consumption in their utility function. Households with school-age children choose between private and public education. household as a household headed by either a native or a pre-1970 immigrant. According to the 2000 Census, each immigrant-headed household in California had on average 1 school-age child while a native household had 0.45 school-age children. Out of native households only 26 percent had school-age children in 2000, against 52 percent among immigrant-headed households. Conditional on having at least a school-age child, immigrant-headed households had on average 1.93 school-age children against 1.70 among native households. The fertility differential between natives and immigrants is partly due to demographic differences such as age between the two populations. The argument in the paper does not hinge on the specific reason for the observed difference in fertility. 4 See Sonstelie et al. (2000) for a thorough account of education finance reform in California. As discussed by these authors there are components of education spending such as categorical aid that, although determined at the state level, are not by their nature equalized across students. Thus, more precisely equalization refers to regular per pupil spending, which represents percent of education spending. In the rest of the paper I ignore this distinction. 3

4 The model s parameters are calibrated using micro data from the 1980 U.S. Census and data on public education spending from the National Center for Education Statistics (NCES). The model accounts relatively well for the evolution of education spending in California in the subsequent Census years 1990 and The model is then used to compute counterfactual tax rates and private school enrollment rates for 1980, 1990, and 2000 by excluding from the economy households whose head immigrated to the U.S. after The model predicts increasingly higher levels of spending per student from 1980 to 2000 in the counterfactual economy, culminating with the gain of about $1,482 per student cited above. This paper is related to both the literature on the fiscal impact of immigration and the literature on education finance reform. The former line of research takes an accounting perspective by computing the fiscal costs and benefits of immigration given the existing system of transfers, government spending, and taxes (see Borjas and Hilton, 1996, Clune, 1998 and Garvey and Espenshade, 1998). As argued by the National Research Council (1997 page 259) panel: The assumption of exogenous fiscal policies provides useful shortterm estimates for state and local government effects. Future work in this area could examine how much immigration affects fiscal policies... and incorporate such endogenous effects into the modeling exercise. This paper represents a first step in this direction. 5 California represents the most prominent example of an education finance reform that shifted education funding from the local to the state level. This shift, which began in 1971 with the first Serrano ruling, led to the near-equalization of education spending per student by the early 1980 s. 6 Silva and Sonstelie (1995), Fernandez and Rogerson (1999), Sonstelie et al. (2000), and Hoxby (2001) point to this reform as the main reason for the observed decline 5 An exception is Dottori and Shen (2009) who model the impact of low-skill immigration on public education spending. In their model, as in mine, low-skill immigration reduces the average tax base from which public schools are founded and leads to lower support for public education and increased private school attendance by high-income natives. Differently from their theoretical paper I use the model to quantitatively assess these channels. 6 When the Serrano plaintiffs returned to court in 1983, the judge wrote, rejecting their case, that It is this court s view that the proper standard for testing compliance with the judgement is whether the Legislature has done all that is reasonably feasible to reduce disparities in per-pupil expenditures to insignificant differences. As is discussed, the state has met this standard and surpassed it. (cited by Sonstelie et al., 2000, page 55). 4

5 in education spending per pupil in California in the 1980 s and early 1990 s. Murray et al. (1998), instead, estimate a positive effect of education finance reform on average spending per pupil using panel data on U.S. states. By focusing on the post-1980 period this paper eschews this debate. Instead, it argues that by the year 2000 immigration had become a more important factor than education finance reform in accounting for the relative drop in spending per student in California. The quantitative results of this paper are consistent with the empirical evidence in Poterba (1997) and Fernandez and Rogerson (2001). Using panel data on U.S. states these authors show that for given level of aggregate income, and controlling for state fixed-effects, the elasticity of education spending per student with respect to changes in the number of students enrolled in school is equal to about minus one. Differently from this exclusively empirical work, I endogenize the choice of education spending and school choice and I focus on a specific demographic shock - immigration. The advantage of the structural model adopted here is that it can be used to evaluate the roles of immigrants political power and of private school choice in performing the counterfactual experiments of interest. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the basic trends about education spending in California and the rest of the U.S. Section 3 describes the model economy. Section 4 discusses the calibration of the model s parameters. Section 5 performs the counterfactual exercise. Section 6 considers a number of extensions of the basic framework of Sections 3 5. Last, Section 7 concludes. A description of the data is contained in the Appendix. 5

6 2 Empirical Evidence 2.1 The Evolution of Spending per Pupil over Time The key variable of interest in this study is current education spending per student enrolled in public elementary and secondary school in California. 7 In this section I consider the evolution of this variable over time in California relative to the rest of the U.S. and analyze its components. To fix ideas, it is convenient to denote aggregate nominal spending for public elementary and secondary education in location k at time t by Ek t, where the index k equals CA (California) or US (the U.S. excluding California). Let H t k denote the total number of households in k at time t, and let N t k stand for enrollment in public schools. Last, Y t k is a measure of total nominal income in k at time t. By definition, log spending per student in CA relative to the rest of the US at time t can be decomposed in the following way: log Et CA /N t CA E t US /N t US = log Et CA /Y t CA E t US /Y t US + log Y t CA /Ht CA Y t US /H t US + log Ht CA /N t CA H t US /N t US, (1) or, in words, as the sum of log relative education spending per unit of income, log relative income per household, and log relative number of households per student enrolled in public schools. I analyze the evolution of these variables starting from a given point in time, the school year This initial date works well because the resurgence of large-scale immigration to the U.S. dates back to the Immigration and Nationality Act Amendments of 1965 which facilitated immigration for family unification purposes. Also, the major education reform that equalized spending per student in California occurred in the 1970 s. Table 1 represents the levels of the main statistics about education spending, household income, and public school enrollment of children from native and immigrant households in the different 7 The NCES defines current expenditures as The expenditures for operating local public schools, excluding capital outlay and interest on school debt. These expenditures include such items as salaries for school personnel, fixed charges, student transportation, school books and materials, and energy costs. 8 As a convention, in what follows I refer to the school year as

7 Census years for California and the rest of the U.S. Taking the difference between equation (1) in year t and its equivalent in 1970 provides the basis for the analysis of the determinants of the evolution of spending per student in California relative to the rest of the U.S. and relative to the year I implement this decomposition empirically using both yearly data for the period (Figure 1) and decennial data for the period (Figure 2). According to both figures California s relative spending per student declines by more than 20 percent between 1970 and 2005, reaching a low point in the mid-1990 s. These figures also suggest that this drop cannot be accounted for by a decline in the fraction of income spent on public education in California relative to the rest of the U.S. 9 The reason why per student spending exhibits such a large decline, instead, is mainly the increase in the student to household ratio in California relative to the rest of the U.S. For example, in 1970 there were 1.40 and 1.35 households in California and in the rest of the U.S., respectively, for each student enrolled in public school. In 2005, there were 2.34 households per student in the rest of the U.S., but only 1.97 in California. Notice how the cumulative change in the relative ratio E/N between 1970 and 2005 is almost identical to the cumulative trend followed by the relative ratio H/N. Note that the demographic shift that led to lower relative H/N ratios in California in 2005 did not start until about Figure 1 also shows how the ratio of education spending to income declined quickly in California between the mid-1970 s and the early 1980 s, remaining constant until the mid 1990 s and then exhibiting an upward trend. Figure 2, which uses income data from the U.S. Census, shows a further decline in spending relative to income for California until However, this decline is simply the counterpart of faster growth in income per household in the 1980 s in California than in the rest of the U.S. as recorded by the Census, suggesting that education spending per household was actually fairly constant 9 According to Figure 1, in 2005 California was spending almost the same fraction of its income on public education relative to the rest of the U.S. as in Figure 2 instead shows a small decline in this indicator. However, the reason for this decline is the fact that relative income per household in California grew faster according to the U.S. Census measure of income than according to the CPS measure of income. In fact, when considering education spending per household, as opposed to per student enrolled, California does not seem to gain or lose relative to the rest of the U.S. between 1970 and

8 during the 1980 s also according to the Census data (see footnote 9). It is fair to interpret these trends as suggesting that the effect of the Serrano ruling on education spending relative to income emphasized by Fernandez and Rogerson (1999) had already fully taken place by the early 1980 s. 10 How did the relative decline in education spending affect the education sector in California? Data on pupil-teacher ratios show a dramatic increase in average class size in California relative to the rest of the U.S. during the 1980 s and up to the early 1990 s when this figure stabilizes. Schrag (1998, page 15) describes informally some of the consequences of the relative decline in spending: the unmaintained buildings with leaking roofs, falling ceiling tiles, and unusable toilets; the layoffs of school counselors, librarians and nurses; and the reductions in course offerings in everything from art to zoology. Writer Jonathan Kozol found rotting school facilities in the inner cities; California has them in the suburbs as well Immigration In this section I present results from a simple statistical counterfactual exercise in order to begin assessing the role played by immigration in generating the trends in Figures 1 and 2. Specifically, I generate a new series for the logarithm of relative (California vs the rest of the U.S.) spending per capita in public education replacing the term Hk t/n k t in equation (1) with the ratio of the number of households headed by a U.S. native individual to the number of children living in such households and enrolled in elementary and secondary public schools. Figure 3 reports the actual data series (solid line) of relative spending in public education per school-age child and the corresponding counterfactual series (dashed line). As the figure shows, relative education spending per student in California would have been about the same 10 Interestingly, during the period under consideration California did not experience a relative reduction in non-education spending per capita by state and local governments (Sonstelie et al., 2000, Figure 5.6). 11 The available empirical evidence on educational outcomes in California also suggests a decline. A study by the Rand Corporation (Carroll et al., 2005) shows that California students taking national achievement tests in the period scored worse than students from all other U.S. states except Louisiana and Mississippi. These relatively poor results could not be explained by students family characteristics. Sonstelie et al. (2000) show that California s students performed better than average in earlier - although different - standardized tests administered between 1972 and

9 in 2000 as it was in 1970 if the ratio of households per public-school student in California had been equal to the value computed for native households only. 2.3 Private Schools Downes and Schoeman (1998) have argued that California s school finance reform of the 1970 s has led to a significant increase in enrollment into private schools. A similar argument can be made regarding the reaction of native households to California s immigration wave. Betts and Fairlie (2003) use Census data to document the existence of a negative relationship between immigrant inflow in a metropolitan area and enrollment rates in private schools. In a recent empirical paper on California, Cascio and Lewis (2010) show using district-level data that native households with children respond to an inflow of Hispanic households with low English proficiency in their school district by relocating to other areas or enrolling their children in private school. Specifically, they find that between 1970 and 2000, the average metropolitan school district in California lost about two children to private schools within the district for every ten additional low-english Hispanic arrivals in its public schools. Figure 4 plots the evolution of private school enrollment rates by children from native households in California and in the rest of the U.S. Notice that in 1980 California had approximately the same private school enrollment rate among native households as the rest of the U.S. In the following 20 years California experienced an increase in private school attendance relative to the rest of the U.S., with the gap in enrollment rates being slightly smaller than one percentage point in The quantitative predictions of the model introduced in the next section are consistent with these trends. 3 Model In this section I introduce a simple political-economy model of spending on public education and household choice of public vs private education. The model is then calibrated to 9

10 the data and used to interpret the trends in public education spending per student. The economy (California) is populated by a measure one of households with preferences defined over a composite private good different from education, denoted by c, public education services per student, denoted by e, and private education services per student, z. A household cannot consume both public and private education services. Define an indicator variable I(z) = 1 if z > 0 and I(z) = 0 if z = 0. A household s utility function takes the following form: 12 u(c, e, z; λ, m) = cα α + γ m (1 I (z)) eα α + γ mλi (z) zα α, (2) where α < 1, γ m > 0, and λ > 0 are parameters. The functional form in equation (2) represents a generalization of the one adopted by Fernandez and Rogerson (1999, 2003) along two dimensions. First, the weight γ m on education might differ between immigrant (m = 0) and native (m = 1) households. Second, households with children choose between private and public education. There is unobserved heterogeneity about the intensity of preferences for private education, captured by the household-specific parameter λ. The parameter λ is distributed independently of any other observable household characteristic such as income, etc. Its unconditional mean in the population is set equal to one so that a-priori the average household does not prefer one type of education service over the other keeping quality constant (i.e. for e = z). Differently from most public finance models of education spending (see e.g. Epple and Nechyba, 2004 for a review of the literature), I also explicitly consider heterogeneity among households with respect to their number of school-age children, denoted by n. Households for whom n > 0 can choose between public and private schools. Households with n = 0 are assumed to care about public education. The rationale for this assumption is that according 12 This class of preferences exhibits a unit elasticity of education spending relative to income. This is consistent with the empirical evidence in Fernandez and Rogerson (2001). In assuming that households care about public education spending per student, I am implicitly postulating a constant returns to scale technology in the provision of education, in which marginal and average production costs coincide. 10

11 to the Census data, in any given year, about 70 percent of households have no children enrolled in primary or secondary school, both in California and in the rest of the U.S. A household without school-age children is still likely to care about public education either because its grown-up children have attended public schools or because its pre-school children will attend public schools when they reach the appropriate age. Public school enrollment rates are about 90 percent in the sample period. External effects associated with a more educated population such as lower crime, productivity spillovers, a more educated electorate, etc. (e.g., Lochner and Moretti, 2004) could also rationalize support for public education among households without school-age children. 13 Spending on public education is financed through a linear tax s on household income y. 14 A household that chooses public education receives utility: U (y (1 s), e, m) u(y(1 s), e, 0; 0, m). A household with school-age children can also opt for private education (Epple and Romano, 1996). In this case, its consumption is equal to its after-tax income minus any spending on private education. The relative price of education is denoted by p m and is allowed to differ between children of native and immigrant households: c = y(1 s) p m nzi (z). 13 The argument that households without school-age children care about public education spending because it is capitalized into housing values is less suitable to post-serrano California where per student spending is equalized across school districts. As in Epple and Romano (1996) households with private school children do not support public education. Given that they represent only about 3 percent of all households, the fact that they are assumed not to care about public education is unlikely to play a quantitatively important role. 14 I focus on a linear tax for simplicity and to maintain comparison with the existing literature (e.g. Fernandez and Rogerson, 1999), despite the fact that California s income tax is progressive. It is not a-priori clear how progressivity of the tax system might affect the results of the counterfactual experiment, in light of the fact that marginal tax rates are endogenous. 11

12 In case the household opts for private education, its indirect utility is defined as: V (y (1 s), n, λ, m) max {u(y(1 s) p m nz, 0, z; λ, m)}. z Conditional on opting for private education, the optimal quantity of private education services chosen by a household is given by: z ((1 s)y, n, λ, m) = (1 s)y p m n + [(p m n) / (γ m λ)] 1 1 α. (3) Notice that the per-child optimal quantity of private education is increasing in the household s after-tax income, and in its preference for private education, and decreasing in the price of education and the household s number of children. A household chooses public over private school if and only if: U (y (1 s), e, m) V (y (1 s), n, λ, m). Denote by ŷ the level of income at which a household is indifferent between private and public schools: ŷ (n, s, e, λ, m) = e 1 s γ 1 α m [ ( 1 + (p m n) α 1 α (γm λ) 1 1 α ) ] 1. (4) 1 α α 1 The income cut-off for attending private school increases with the level of public education services, the tax rate, the household s number of children and the price of education. Moreover, if α < 0, the cut-off decreases with the education preference parameter γ m. Let f(y, n, m, λ) denote the joint density of income, number of children, immigration status, and the parameter λ in the population of households. For given s and e, the per household measure of children attending public school by immigration status is then given 12

13 by: n m = n ŷ(n,s,e,λ,m) 0 0 n f(y, n, m, λ)dydλ, for m = 0, 1. (5) The government s budget is assumed to be balanced: (p 0 n 0 + p 1 n 1 ) e = sy, (6) where y denotes average household income in the economy. The government s budget allows for the possibility that the cost of educating immigrant children might differ from the cost of educating native ones. Equation (6) assumes that the income of all households is taxed at the same rate s. In particular, the model abstracts from issues of tax evasion and illegal immigration for lack of reliable data. Note, however, that the explicit consideration of tax evasion is likely to generate larger declines in education spending associated with immigration than the numbers reported in this paper. The tax rate s is assumed to be determined by majority voting by all native households. 15 In what follows I focus on a majority-voting equilibrium in which, when voting, native households take as given their own choice of school as well as the choice of all other households. This guarantees that household preferences are single-peaked over tax rates. Formally, a majority-voting equilibrium is comprised of a tax rate s, a level of public school services per student e, private school services per student z ((1 s )y, n, λ, m), and measures of students attending public school (n 0, n 1) by immigration status, such that: 1. Private school services per student, z ((1 s )y, n, λ, m) are given by equation (3) if y > ŷ (n, s, e, λ, m) and zero else; 2. The government s budget constraint, equation (6), is satisfied; 3. Public school attendance by immigration status n m is given by equation (5); 4. The equilibrium tax rate and education services per student (s, e ) are preferred by at least 50 percent of 15 In reality the amount of education spending in California is determined by the interaction of the legislature and the governor. Education spending represents one dimension of the overall budget process. While more sophisticated modelling of the legislative process might be feasible, here I adopt the median voter approach to aggregation of policy preferences to keep comparability with the previous literature which uses the same framework (e.g. Fernandez and Rogerson, 1999). 13

14 the voters to any alternative (ŝ, ê) such that ê = ŝy/ (p 0 n 0 + p 1 n 1). The majority-voting equilibrium tax rate s is the median tax rate when households preferred rates are sorted from lowest to highest. The equilibrium level of education spending per student, the object of my analysis, is given by sy/ (n 0 + n 1). It is straightforward to show that, at a majority-voting equilibrium, the preferred tax rate by a household characterized by (y, n, λ, m) is given by: { } γ 1 α 1 m [(p 0 n 0 + p 1 n 1) y/y] α 1 α if y ŷ (n, s, e, λ, m) or n = 0 ŝ = 0 if y > ŷ (n, s, e, λ, m) and n > 0 (7) This expression is useful to discuss a couple of important issues. The first concerns the uniqueness of equilibrium in this economy. Multiplicity might in general arise due to the existence of a private school option (Epple and Romano, 1996). While, I cannot prove uniqueness in general, there is an important special case in which this can be done. Specifically, if utility takes the logarithmic form (α = 0) then the preferred tax rate of a native household without children in private school is equal to γ 1 / (1 + γ 1 ). A suffi cient condition for this tax rate to be the unique majority-voting equilibrium is then that native households with n = 0 are a majority of the native population, as it is the case empirically. Since the calibrated value of α is different from zero, I verify numerically that the equilibrium of the model is unique. The second issue is how native households react to an inflow of immigrants. There are two mechanisms. First, an inflow of immigrants tends to increase the tax price of education services, represented by the term [(p 0 n 0 + p 1 n 1) y/y] in equation (7), for all households. This increase might occur for three reasons: immigrant households tend to have lower average income; they tend to have more children per household; the cost of educating immigrant children might be larger than the cost of educating native children. The tax price is the amount by which a household s taxes would have to increase to increase e by one unit. The level 14

15 of public education services per student e preferred by a native household with children in public school and preferred tax rate ŝ can be shown to fall by 1 αŝ 1 α percent for an increase in the tax price by one percent. The magnitude of the decline depends on the elasticity parameter α, with lower values of α associated with a more price-inelastic demand. When α = 0, this elasticity is equal to one, as native households without children in private school prefer to keep the tax rate constant at γ 1 / (1 + γ 1 ) when faced with an inflow of immigrants. When α < 0, instead, as will be assumed in the empirical section of the paper, the increase in the tax price induced by the inflow of immigrants makes all households without private school children increase their support for higher tax rates. The resulting increase in the tax rate partially offsets the direct effect of immigration on e, leading to a less than proportional decline in households preferred amount of education services. Second, the reduction in e that follows an inflow of immigrants induces some native households who previously attended public schools to move to the private system because the quality of the public system declines. Formally, for given tax rate, a one percent increase in the tax price causes the private school cut-off in equation (4) to fall by one percent. The reduction in public school attendance by native households contributes to further reduce political support for the public system. In the following I describe the calibration of the model and use the latter to quantify the magnitude of these effects. 4 Empirical Implementation The model is calibrated to the beginning of the post-education reform period in California, around To calibrate the economy I need to specify the values of the parameters that are constant over time (α, γ 0, γ 1, p 0, p 1 ) and the joint density f(y, n, m, λ) which varies across Census years. 15

16 To calibrate the density f(y, n, m, λ), I assume that the taste parameter λ is independent of (y, n, m) in the population. The distribution of λ is taken to be lognormal with constant parameters (µ λ, σ λ ). The parameter µ λ must equal σ 2 λ /2 for the mean of λ to equal one. The joint distribution of (y, n, m) can be written as: g(y, n, m) = g(y n, m)h (n, m), (8) where h (n, m) is the joint density of (n, m). The conditional density g(y n, m) is assumed to be lognormal with parameters µ y (n, m) and σ y (n, m). The latter are estimated by matching the conditional mean (E [y n, m]) and variance (V [y n, m]) of household income in the population: µ y (n, m) = ln E [y n, m] 1 ( )] V [y n, m] [1 2 ln + E [y n, m] 2, (9) { [ ( )]} 1 V [y n, m] 2 σ y (n, m) = ln 1 +. (10) E [y n, m] 2 Immigration status (m) takes two possible values according to whether the household head is a U.S. born individual or a foreign-born person who immigrated to the U.S. before 1970 (m = 1), or alternatively, is a foreign-born individual who immigrated to the U.S. in or after 1970 (m = 0). A household s number of children (n) is assumed to take four possible values: 0, 1, 2, and 3 +, where 3 + equals the average number of children in households with at least 3 children. The density h (n, m) is estimated non-parametrically using the frequency count of each cell (n, m). The relative price of education for a native household p 1 is normalized to one without loss of generality. The relative price of education spending for an immigrant child is set conservatively to p 0 = 1.04 or four percent above the price for native children. I compute this figure using the data on California s categorical aid per student compiled by Sonstelie et al. (2000, table 4.7). Categorical aid represents about 20 percent of spending per student and 16

17 compensatory education, which covers students with limited English proficiency, represents about 20 percent of categorical aid over the sample period. I calibrate the remaining four parameters (α, γ 0, γ 1, σ λ ) to match four key moments in the data reported in Table 3. The first two moments are the per household number of native and immigrant children enrolled in public school in Higher values of γ 1 and γ 0 are associated with lower public school attendance by native and immigrant children respectively if α < 0 (see equation 4). The third targeted moment is the share of income spent on public primary and secondary education in California in 1980, s = The elasticity parameter α contributes to determine the share of income devoted to education spending. To see this, it is convenient to consider a representative-agent version of the model in which all households have the same preferences, income, and number of children. In this ) setting it is straightforward to check that the equilibrium tax rate is s = ((γ/n) α + 1 (see equation 7). Given γ/n, the elasticity parameter α determines s uniquely. Specifically, if γ/n < 1, as is the case empirically, smaller values of α map into smaller equilibrium tax rates. The fourth and last moment is the ratio between the average incomes of households with children in public and private schools in The parameter σ λ determines the degree of income mixing in private schools, with higher levels of σ λ associated with a higher ratio of average income in public relative to private schools. Table 2 reports the calibrated values of the parameters. The calibrated value of the parameter α is This is very close to the value of 0.25 preferred by Fernandez and Rogerson (1999) in their study of education finance reform in California. 16 The tax price elasticity of the demand for education for the median voter implied by α = 0.34 is equal to This value is slightly higher in absolute value than the range ( 0.25, 0.5) reported by Bergstrom et al. (1982) in their survey of the literature, but smaller than the value implied by Fernandez and Rogerson (1999) s calibration. A second feature of the calibration is that immigrant households place a smaller weight on education relative to native households. 16 Their preferred value is such that their model generates the best fit for the observed distribution of spending per student across students in California before education finance reform. 17

18 This is an implication of the fact that immigrant households are less likely to have children in private school conditional on income and number of students. 17 The calibration procedure then accounts for the observed enrollment of immigrant children in public school by selecting a value for γ 0 smaller than the corresponding one for γ 1. The calibrated model can be used to predict the income share of spending in education, enrollment in public schools, and other moments of interest for the Census years 1990 and In using the model to predict outcomes for 1990 and 2000, I keep the same parameters (α, γ 0, γ 1, σ λ, µ λ, p 0 ) from Table 2, and re-calibrate the density g(y, n, m) for 1990 and 2000 along the lines described above for Table 3 summarizes the moments predicted by the model and presents them together with the actual data for California. Notice that the model accounts reasonably well for the evolution of the triple (s, n 0, n 1 ) observed in California in 1990 and Specifically, the model correctly predicts the reduction in the share of income devoted to public education between 1980 and 1990 and the subsequent rise between 1990 and As discussed at the end of Section 3, there are two main forces that drive the dynamics of s in the model. The first one is the variation over time in the tax price of public education services. The tax price of public education services declined in the 1980 s and increased in the 1990 s, as the ratio y/ (p 0 n 0 + p 1 n 1) went from $97,050 in 1980 to $131,500 in 1990 and subsequently fell to $123,040 in The model correctly predicts that, following this variation in the tax price, the income share of education spending (i.e. s) should have decreased in the 1980 s and increased in the 1990 s. The second major force that determines the dynamics of s is private school attendance. Higher private school attendance reduces the support for public education and tends to lower the equilibrium tax rate. Notice that the model correctly predicts higher private school enrollment by native households in 2000 than in 1980, even if it incorrectly gives rise to a decline in private enrollment between 1980 and A logistic regression using 1980 Census data for California reveals that an immigrant-headed household is 0.7 percent less likely to have children in private school than a native household with the same income level and number of children. 18

19 Table 3 contains additional information about the relative incomes of public and private school households and their average number of children. Note that, consistently with the data, the model predicts a decline in public school households income relative to their private school counterpart in the 1980 s and 1990 s. Also, the model correctly predicts that public school households have, on average, more school-age children than private school ones. 5 Counterfactual Exercise In this section I use the model developed so far to provide an answer to the following question: what would have been the level of education spending per student in California in if U.S. immigration had been restricted to its 1970 level? The model can be used to compute counterfactual enrollment rates in private school and education spending relative to income. To perform such exercise a stand has to be taken about the effect of restricted immigration on the income of native households residing in California. Ignoring this general equilibrium effect might lead one to either under or overstate the negative impact of immigrants on relative spending per student in California. The effect of immigration on the labor income of natives and previous cohorts of immigrants is the subject of some controversy in the literature (see e.g., Borjas, 2003 and Card, 2001). Recent research by Ottaviano and Peri (2008) points to a possible positive effect of immigrants on the average wages of natives, but their finding has been challenged by Borjas, Grogger, and Hanson (2008). In light of the uncertainty about the effect of immigration on the wages of natives, I take as a benchmark the case in which the income of natives and pre-1970 immigrants is unaffected by restrictions to immigration. Section 6.2 of the paper discusses the consequences of relaxing this assumption. 5.1 Counterfactual The model is used to compute the counterfactual level of spending per child and other indicators of interest in 1980, 1990, and 2000 in a version of the economy without households 19

20 whose head immigrated to the U.S. in or after 1970, according to the U.S. Census. Formally, the following density: g(y, n, m m = 1) = g(y, n, 1) n h (n, 1) (11) is used in the counterfactual exercise, instead of the one in equation (8). Table 4 contains the results of this exercise. A comparison of Tables 3 and 4 reveals that in the economy with post-1970 immigration restrictions public education spending per student in California is 3, 15, and 24 percent higher than in the benchmark in 1980, 1990, and 2000 respectively. In the year 2000, in the economy with immigration restrictions spending per student would have been $1,482 higher than in the benchmark economy and $1,295 higher than in reality Decomposition The reduction in spending per student associated with immigration can be attributed to differences between natives and immigrants in: 1) the number of school-age children per household; 2) average income; 3) cost of education; 4) preferences for education. Table 5 presents the results of a decomposition of the overall change in spending per student moving from the benchmark economy to the counterfactual one into these different components. In this table I also evaluate the consequences of relaxing the assumption that immigrant households do not vote in the benchmark version of the model. The second and last columns of Table 5 present the level of spending per student in the benchmark and counterfactual economies respectively. The middle columns of Table 5, instead, present the level of spending per student in economies that might be thought of as alternative benchmarks against which to compare the level of spending in the counterfactual economy. For example, column A in Table 5 represents spending per student corresponding to an economy identical to the benchmark one except for the fact that immigrants are allowed to vote on education spending. This economy is characterized by a lower level of 18 Recall that the model underpredicts education spending per student in California in the year 2000 by about $

21 spending per student than the benchmark for two reasons. First, immigrant households have on average a lower income level than native households, so that, given α < 0, they prefer lower levels of spending. Second, according to the calibrated parameters immigrants are found to care relatively less about education than natives, i.e. γ 0 < γ 1. This experiment also clarifies that the assumption that immigrants do not vote in the benchmark version of the model is conservative in the sense of reducing the magnitude of the spending gains associated with restricting immigration. Column B presents the results for an economy similar to the benchmark except for the fact that both the preference for education and the cost of education are equal for immigrants and natives, i.e. γ 0 = γ 1 and p 0 = p 1. The level of spending per student in this economy is very close to the benchmark. Finally, column C is the same as B except that immigrants income is scaled up to be the same as that of natives, on average. Spending in economy C is higher than in all the other economies, except for the counterfactual, as scaling up immigrants income results in a large tax base. I interpret the comparison of spending per student between economy C and the counterfactual economy with restricted immigration (last column of Table 5) as providing a measure of the contribution of demographic factors to the gain in spending resulting from switching from the benchmark to the counterfactual model. The comparison between these two columns shows how even if immigrants had the same average income, cost of education, and preferences as natives, but kept their own demographic characteristics, spending per student in the year 2000 would still be $1,253 below the counterfactual economy with no immigrants. This is 84 percent of the gap in spending between the benchmark and counterfactual economies. The remaining 16 percent of this gap is attributable to factors different from demographics with a major role attributable to the lower average income of immigrants. The decomposition indicates that the lower average income of immigrants accounts for a drop of $210 in spending per student in the year 2000, or 14 percent of the gap between the benchmark and counterfactual economy. 19 The remaining factors appear to play 19 The $210 figure is obtained by subtracting spending per student in column B from spending per student in column C for the year

22 relatively negligible roles. 5.3 Private School In the economy with restricted immigration (Table 4), native households increase their public school attendance relative to the benchmark model (Table 3). This switch has in principle an ambiguous effect on education spending. On the one hand, as native households move into the public system they support higher levels of spending per student. One the other hand, as these households move into the public system, their children use some of its resources. In order to assess the contribution of this mechanism to the results of Table 4, I recomputed the majority voting equilibrium in the counterfactual economy keeping native households choice of private vs public schooling constant at what it was in the benchmark model. I find that quantitatively the second effect is larger than the first one, so that education spending per student is higher if households school choice is kept constant in the counterfactual exercise. The net effect is, however, quantitatively small, amounting to $58 additional spending per student in the year Comparison with the Literature The magnitude of the counterfactual results in Table 4 is consistent with Poterba (1997) and Fernandez and Rogerson (2001). Using panel data for U.S. states these authors estimate that the elasticity of public education spending per student in a state with respect to the average number of students per household is equal to 1. In the counterfactual economy (Table 4), the number of students per household is 0.42 in 2000 while the corresponding figure in reality is 0.52 (Table 1), or about 21 percent higher. An elasticity of 1 implies a counterfactual amount of education spending per student of $7,692 in 2000 in California. This is very close to my finding in Table 4. Several authors have estimated (Fernandez and Rogerson, 1999 and Silva and Sonstelie, 1995) that education finance reform reduced education spending per student in California by percent. According to my model, 22

23 in 1990 immigration generates declines (relative to a non-immigration benchmark) in public education spending by 15 percent, a figure comparable to those often attributed to education finance reform. 6 Sensitivity Analysis and Extensions In this section I discuss some of the assumptions of the basic model presented in Sections 3 5, and evaluate the impact of relaxing them on the main results. 6.1 Sensitivity Analysis In this section I explore the sensitivity of the main results in Table 4 to the model s parameters. Specifically, the percentage gain in spending per student associated with restricting immigration is computed by varying one parameter at a time, while keeping the other ones fixed. 20 The results are summarized in Table 6 which contains the results for the year The top portion of this table focuses on the key elasticity parameter α. A larger (absolute value) value of this parameter implies a more inelastic demand for education, and a smaller counterfactual gain in spending per student. A wide range of values of α is considered, from 0.25, as assumed by Fernandez and Rogerson (1999), to 3.74 corresponding to the smallest tax price elasticity reported by Bergstrom et al. (1982) in their survey of the literature. The top panel of Table 6 shows that the percentage gain in spending per student from restricting immigration decreases proportionately to the size of the tax price elasticity. For example, as this elasticity declines from 0.76 (α = 0.34) to 0.50 (α = 1.11), the counterfactual gain in spending declines by about a third too (from 24 to 16 percent). The bottom portion of Table 6 considers the sensitivity of results to doubling the absolute value of each parameter (other than α) at a time while keeping the other ones constant at their 20 Notice that in order to focus on the effect of changing a single parameter, the parameters of the model that are not subject to sensitivity analysis are not recalibrated to match the moments discussed in Section 4. 23

Immigration, Naturalization, and the Future of Public Education

Immigration, Naturalization, and the Future of Public Education Immigration, Naturalization, and the Future of Public Education Ryuichi Tanaka National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies Lidia Farre University of Barcelona and IAE-CSIC March 6, 2014 Francesc Ortega

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 56 Number 4 Article 5 2003 Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men Chinhui Juhn University of Houston Recommended Citation Juhn,

More information

Immigration, Naturalization, and the Future of Public Education

Immigration, Naturalization, and the Future of Public Education DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 8342 Immigration, Naturalization, and the Future of Public Education Ryuichi Tanaka Lidia Farre Francesc Ortega July 2014 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute

More information

WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased?

WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased? WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased? Nathaniel Baum-Snow, Brown University Matthew Freedman, Cornell University Ronni Pavan, Royal Holloway-University of London June, 2014 Abstract The increase in wage inequality

More information

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution? Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution? Catalina Franco Abstract This paper estimates wage differentials between Latin American immigrant

More information

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations The Determinants and the Selection of Mexico-US Migrations J. William Ambrosini (UC, Davis) Giovanni Peri, (UC, Davis and NBER) This draft March 2011 Abstract Using data from the Mexican Family Life Survey

More information

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California, 1960-2005. Giovanni Peri, (University of California Davis, CESifo and NBER) October, 2009 Abstract A recent series of influential

More information

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1 Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1 Gaetano Basso (Banca d Italia), Giovanni Peri (UC Davis and NBER), Ahmed Rahman (USNA) BdI-CEPR Conference, Roma - March 16th,

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

Lured in and crowded out? Estimating the impact of immigration on natives education using early XXth century US immigration

Lured in and crowded out? Estimating the impact of immigration on natives education using early XXth century US immigration Lured in and crowded out? Estimating the impact of immigration on natives education using early XXth century US immigration June 2013 Abstract Immigration can impact educational decisions of natives through

More information

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015.

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015. The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015 Abstract This paper explores the role of unionization on the wages of Hispanic

More information

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales Nils Braakmann Newcastle University 29. August 2013 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/49423/ MPRA

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SCHOOLING SUPPLY AND THE STRUCTURE OF PRODUCTION: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES Antonio Ciccone Giovanni Peri

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SCHOOLING SUPPLY AND THE STRUCTURE OF PRODUCTION: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES Antonio Ciccone Giovanni Peri NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SCHOOLING SUPPLY AND THE STRUCTURE OF PRODUCTION: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES 1950-1990 Antonio Ciccone Giovanni Peri Working Paper 17683 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17683 NATIONAL

More information

Gains from "Diversity": Theory and Evidence from Immigration in U.S. Cities

Gains from Diversity: Theory and Evidence from Immigration in U.S. Cities Gains from "Diversity": Theory and Evidence from Immigration in U.S. Cities GianmarcoI.P.Ottaviano,(Universita dibolognaandcepr) Giovanni Peri, (UC Davis, UCLA and NBER) March, 2005 Preliminary Abstract

More information

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities National Poverty Center Working Paper Series #05-12 August 2005 Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities George J. Borjas Harvard University This paper is available online at the National Poverty Center

More information

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages Declan Trott Research School of Economics College of Business and Economics Australian

More information

Abstract/Policy Abstract

Abstract/Policy Abstract Gary Burtless* Gary Burtless is a senior fellow at the Brookings Institution. The research reported herein was performed under a grant from the U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA) funded as part

More information

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL:

School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg. and. Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL: Forthcoming, Economic Inquiry School Quality and Returns to Education of U.S. Immigrants Bernt Bratsberg and Dek Terrell* RRH: BRATSBERG & TERRELL: SCHOOL QUALITY AND EDUCATION RETURNS OF IMMIGRANTS JEL

More information

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano 5A.1 Introduction 5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano Over the past 2 years, wage inequality in the U.S. economy has increased rapidly. In this chapter,

More information

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008) MIT Spatial Economics Reading Group Presentation Adam Guren May 13, 2010 Testing the New Economic

More information

Potential Economic Impacts in Oregon of Implementing Proposed Department of Homeland Security No Match Immigration Rules

Potential Economic Impacts in Oregon of Implementing Proposed Department of Homeland Security No Match Immigration Rules Potential Economic Impacts in Oregon of Implementing Proposed Department of Homeland Security No Match Immigration Rules Prepared by: William K. Jaeger, Ph.D. Professor Department of Agricultural and Resource

More information

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, December 2014.

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, December 2014. The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, December 2014 Abstract This paper explores the role of unionization on the wages of Hispanic

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Settling In: Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia. Deborah A. Cobb-Clark

Settling In: Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia. Deborah A. Cobb-Clark Settling In: Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia Deborah A. Cobb-Clark Social Policy Evaluation, Analysis, and Research Centre and Economics Program Research School

More information

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America Advances in Management & Applied Economics, vol. 4, no.2, 2014, 99-109 ISSN: 1792-7544 (print version), 1792-7552(online) Scienpress Ltd, 2014 Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century

More information

Trading Goods or Human Capital

Trading Goods or Human Capital Trading Goods or Human Capital The Winners and Losers from Economic Integration Micha l Burzyński, Université catholique de Louvain, IRES Poznań University of Economics, KEM michal.burzynski@uclouvain.be

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices Kim S. So, Peter F. Orazem, and Daniel M. Otto a May 1998 American Agricultural Economics Association

More information

Cracks in the Melting Pot: Immigration, School Choice, and Segregation *

Cracks in the Melting Pot: Immigration, School Choice, and Segregation * Cracks in the Melting Pot: Immigration, School Choice, and Segregation * Elizabeth U. Cascio Dartmouth College and NBER Ethan G. Lewis Dartmouth College December 1, 2010 Abstract Recent research finds

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983-2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri July 2014 Abstract This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India

More information

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 Charles Simkins Helen Suzman Professor of Political Economy School of Economic and Business Sciences University of the Witwatersrand May 2008 centre for poverty employment

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMMIGRANTS' COMPLEMENTARITIES AND NATIVE WAGES: EVIDENCE FROM CALIFORNIA. Giovanni Peri

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMMIGRANTS' COMPLEMENTARITIES AND NATIVE WAGES: EVIDENCE FROM CALIFORNIA. Giovanni Peri NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMMIGRANTS' COMPLEMENTARITIES AND NATIVE WAGES: EVIDENCE FROM CALIFORNIA Giovanni Peri Working Paper 12956 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12956 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada,

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada, 1987-26 Andrew Sharpe, Jean-Francois Arsenault, and Daniel Ershov 1 Centre for the Study of Living Standards

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 8945 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8945 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

Immigration, Human Capital and the Welfare of Natives

Immigration, Human Capital and the Welfare of Natives Immigration, Human Capital and the Welfare of Natives Juan Eberhard January 30, 2012 Abstract I analyze the effect of an unexpected influx of immigrants on the price of skill and hence on the earnings,

More information

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility Vincenzo Caponi, CREST (Ensai), Ryerson University,IfW,IZA January 20, 2015 VERY PRELIMINARY AND VERY INCOMPLETE Abstract The objective of this paper is to

More information

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Zachary Mahone and Filippo Rebessi August 25, 2013 Abstract Using cross country data from the OECD, we document that variation in immigration variables

More information

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana Journal of Economics and Political Economy www.kspjournals.org Volume 3 June 2016 Issue 2 International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana By Isaac DADSON aa & Ryuta RAY KATO ab Abstract. This paper

More information

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings Part 1: Focus on Income indicator definitions and Rankings Inequality STATE OF NEW YORK CITY S HOUSING & NEIGHBORHOODS IN 2013 7 Focus on Income Inequality New York City has seen rising levels of income

More information

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009 The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009 1. The question Do immigrants alter the employment opportunities of native workers? After World War I,

More information

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data Neeraj Kaushal, Columbia University Yao Lu, Columbia University Nicole Denier, McGill University Julia Wang,

More information

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009 Appendix to Attitudes Towards Highly Skilled and Low Skilled Immigration: Evidence from a Survey Experiment: Formal Derivation of the Predictions of the Labor Market Competition Model and the Fiscal Burden

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Evaluating the Role of Immigration in U.S. Population Projections

Evaluating the Role of Immigration in U.S. Population Projections Evaluating the Role of Immigration in U.S. Population Projections Stephen Tordella, Decision Demographics Steven Camarota, Center for Immigration Studies Tom Godfrey, Decision Demographics Nancy Wemmerus

More information

The wage gap between the public and the private sector among. Canadian-born and immigrant workers

The wage gap between the public and the private sector among. Canadian-born and immigrant workers The wage gap between the public and the private sector among Canadian-born and immigrant workers By Kaiyu Zheng (Student No. 8169992) Major paper presented to the Department of Economics of the University

More information

Travel Time Use Over Five Decades

Travel Time Use Over Five Decades Institute for International Economic Policy Working Paper Series Elliott School of International Affairs The George Washington University Travel Time Use Over Five Decades IIEP WP 2016 24 Chao Wei George

More information

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B by Michel Beine and Serge Coulombe This version: February 2016 Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

More information

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector Pierre Mérel and Zach Rutledge July 7, 2017 Abstract This paper provides new estimates of the short-run impacts of

More information

George J. Borjas Harvard University. September 2008

George J. Borjas Harvard University. September 2008 IMMIGRATION AND LABOR MARKET OUTCOMES IN THE NATIVE ELDERLY POPULATION George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2008 This research was supported by the U.S. Social Security Administration through

More information

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION Laura Marsiliani University of Durham laura.marsiliani@durham.ac.uk Thomas I. Renström University of Durham and CEPR t.i.renstrom@durham.ac.uk We analyze

More information

UC San Diego Recent Work

UC San Diego Recent Work UC San Diego Recent Work Title Explaining Ethnic, Racial, and Immigrant Differences in Private School Attendance Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/9n44g161 Authors Betts, Julian Fairlie, Robert

More information

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer Hassan Aly, Department of Economics, The Ohio State University, E-mail: aly.1@osu.edu Mark Strazicich, Department of Economics,

More information

Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector.

Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector. Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector. Ivan Etzo*; Carla Massidda*; Romano Piras** (Draft version: June 2018) Abstract This paper investigates the existence of complementarities

More information

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany Carsten Pohl 1 15 September, 2008 Extended Abstract Since the beginning of the 1990s Germany has experienced a

More information

Immigration and Poverty in the United States

Immigration and Poverty in the United States April 2008 Immigration and Poverty in the United States Steven Raphael and Eugene Smolensky Goldman School of Public Policy UC Berkeley stevenraphael@berkeley.edu geno@berkeley.edu Abstract In this paper,

More information

Changes in rural poverty in Perú

Changes in rural poverty in Perú Lat Am Econ Rev (2017) 26:1 https://doi.org/10.1007/s40503-016-0038-x Changes in rural poverty in Perú 2004 2012 Samuel Morley 1 Received: 15 October 2014 / Revised: 11 November 2016 / Accepted: 4 December

More information

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES, 1870 1970 IDS WORKING PAPER 73 Edward Anderson SUMMARY This paper studies the impact of globalisation on wage inequality in eight now-developed countries during the

More information

Immigration, Wage Inequality and unobservable skills in the U.S. and the UK. First Draft: October 2008 This Draft March 2009

Immigration, Wage Inequality and unobservable skills in the U.S. and the UK. First Draft: October 2008 This Draft March 2009 Immigration, Wage Inequality and unobservable skills in the U.S. and the First Draft: October 2008 This Draft March 2009 Cinzia Rienzo * Royal Holloway, University of London CEP, London School of Economics

More information

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK Alfonso Miranda a Yu Zhu b,* a Department of Quantitative Social Science, Institute of Education, University of London, UK. Email: A.Miranda@ioe.ac.uk.

More information

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus Cyprus Economic Policy Review, Vol. 1, No. 2, pp. 37-49 (2007) 1450-4561 The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus Louis N. Christofides, Sofronis Clerides, Costas Hadjiyiannis and Michel

More information

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers Giovanni Peri Immigrants did not contribute to the national decline in wages at the national level for native-born workers without a college education.

More information

Inequality in Labor Market Outcomes: Contrasting the 1980s and Earlier Decades

Inequality in Labor Market Outcomes: Contrasting the 1980s and Earlier Decades Inequality in Labor Market Outcomes: Contrasting the 1980s and Earlier Decades Chinhui Juhn and Kevin M. Murphy* The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect

More information

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration?

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration? Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration? David M. Frankel (Iowa State University) January 23, 24 Abstract Cutler, Glaeser, and Vigdor (JPE 1999) find evidence that the late 19th century

More information

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations Amparo Castelló and Rafael Doménech 2016 Annual Meeting of the European Economic Association Geneva, August 24, 2016 1/1 Introduction

More information

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks Lee Tucker Boston University This version: October 15, 2014 Abstract Observational evidence has shown

More information

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever Olga Gorelkina Max Planck Institute, Bonn Ioanna Grypari Max Planck Institute, Bonn Preliminary & Incomplete February 11, 2015 Abstract This paper

More information

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration Frederic Docquier (UCL) Caglar Ozden (World Bank) Giovanni Peri (UC Davis) December 20 th, 2010 FRDB Workshop Objective Establish a minimal common framework

More information

Climate Change Around the World

Climate Change Around the World Climate Change Around the World Per Krusell Institute for International Economic Studies, NBER, CEPR Joint with Anthony A. Smith, Jr. Yale University, NBER World Congress Montréal Août, 215 The project

More information

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping Peter Lanjouw and Martin Ravallion 1 World Bank, October 2006 The Evaluation of World Bank Research (hereafter the Report) focuses some of

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

World of Labor. John V. Winters Oklahoma State University, USA, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros

World of Labor. John V. Winters Oklahoma State University, USA, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros John V. Winters Oklahoma State University, USA, and IZA, Germany Do higher levels of education and skills in an area benefit wider society? Education benefits individuals, but the societal benefits are

More information

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants George Borjas (1987) Omid Ghaderi & Ali Yadegari April 7, 2018 George Borjas (1987) GSME, Applied Economics Seminars April 7, 2018 1 / 24 Abstract The age-earnings

More information

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Industrial & Labor Relations Review Industrial & Labor Relations Review Volume 60, Issue 3 2007 Article 5 Labor Market Institutions and Wage Inequality Winfried Koeniger Marco Leonardi Luca Nunziata IZA, University of Bonn, University of

More information

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Rural and Urban Migrants in India: Rural and Urban Migrants in India: 1983 2008 Viktoria Hnatkovska and Amartya Lahiri This paper characterizes the gross and net migration flows between rural and urban areas in India during the period 1983

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development December 26 1 Introduction For many OECD countries,

More information

Immigration, Worker-Firm Matching, and. Inequality

Immigration, Worker-Firm Matching, and. Inequality Immigration, Worker-Firm Matching, and Inequality Jaerim Choi* University of Hawaii at Manoa Jihyun Park** KISDI August 2, 2018 Abstract This paper develops a novel framework of worker-firm matching to

More information

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration Jérôme Adda Christian Dustmann Joseph-Simon Görlach February 14, 2014 PRELIMINARY and VERY INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper analyses the wage

More information

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network Working Paper No. 69 Immigrant Earnings Growth: Selection Bias or Real Progress? Garnett Picot Statistics Canada Patrizio Piraino Statistics Canada

More information

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit Drivers of Inequality in South Africa by Janina Hundenborn, Murray Leibbrandt and Ingrid Woolard SALDRU Working Paper Number 194 NIDS Discussion Paper

More information

Labor Market Adjustment to Globalization: Long-Term Employment in the United States and Japan 1

Labor Market Adjustment to Globalization: Long-Term Employment in the United States and Japan 1 Preliminary Draft WORKING PAPER #519 PRINCETON UNIVERSITY INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS SECTION June 2007 Version: September 11, 2007 Labor Market Adjustment to Globalization: Long-Term Employment in the United

More information

Why are the Relative Wages of Immigrants Declining? A Distributional Approach* Brahim Boudarbat, Université de Montréal

Why are the Relative Wages of Immigrants Declining? A Distributional Approach* Brahim Boudarbat, Université de Montréal Preliminary and incomplete Comments welcome Why are the Relative Wages of Immigrants Declining? A Distributional Approach* Brahim Boudarbat, Université de Montréal Thomas Lemieux, University of British

More information

School Performance of the Children of Immigrants in Canada,

School Performance of the Children of Immigrants in Canada, School Performance of the Children of Immigrants in Canada, 1994-98 by Christopher Worswick * No. 178 11F0019MIE No. 178 ISSN: 1205-9153 ISBN: 0-662-31229-5 Department of Economics, Carleton University

More information

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Sephorah Mangin 1 and Yves Zenou 2 September 15, 2016 Abstract: Workers from a source country consider whether or not to illegally migrate to a host country. This

More information

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W. A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) by Stratford Douglas* and W. Robert Reed Revised, 26 December 2013 * Stratford Douglas, Department

More information

GENDER SEGREGATION BY OCCUPATIONS IN THE PUBLIC AND THE PRIVATE SECTOR. THECASEOFSPAIN

GENDER SEGREGATION BY OCCUPATIONS IN THE PUBLIC AND THE PRIVATE SECTOR. THECASEOFSPAIN investigaciones económicas. vol. XXVIII (3), 2004, 399-428 GENDER SEGREGATION BY OCCUPATIONS IN THE PUBLIC AND THE PRIVATE SECTOR. THECASEOFSPAIN RICARDO MORA JAVIER RUIZ-CASTILLO Universidad Carlos III

More information

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation: Evidence from Financial Market Participation. Una Okonkwo Osili 1 Anna Paulson 2

Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation: Evidence from Financial Market Participation. Una Okonkwo Osili 1 Anna Paulson 2 Prospects for Immigrant-Native Wealth Assimilation: Evidence from Financial Market Participation Una Okonkwo Osili 1 Anna Paulson 2 1 Contact Information: Department of Economics, Indiana University Purdue

More information

Effects of Immigrants on the Native Force Labor Market Outcomes: Examining Data from Canada and the US

Effects of Immigrants on the Native Force Labor Market Outcomes: Examining Data from Canada and the US Effects of Immigrants on the Native Force Labor Market Outcomes: Examining Data from Canada and the US By Matija Jančec Submitted to Central European University Department of Economics In partial fulfillment

More information

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants Andri Chassamboulli (University of Cyprus) Giovanni Peri (University of California, Davis) February, 14th, 2014 Abstract A key controversy in

More information

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited Assaf Razin y and Efraim Sadka z January 2011 Abstract The literature on tax competition with free capital mobility cites several

More information

Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective

Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective s u m m a r y Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective Nicole M. Fortin and Thomas Lemieux t the national level, Canada, like many industrialized countries, has Aexperienced

More information

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities Job Market Paper Sreenath Majumder Draft: November 2008 Abstract This paper examines the effect of public policy on population

More information

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University February 2010 1 SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants George J. Borjas ABSTRACT The employment

More information

Skilled Immigration, Innovation and Wages of Native-born American *

Skilled Immigration, Innovation and Wages of Native-born American * Skilled Immigration, Innovation and Wages of Native-born American * Asadul Islam Monash University Faridul Islam Utah Valley University Chau Nguyen Monash University March 2012 Abstract The paper examines

More information

Using data provided by the U.S. Census Bureau, this study first recreates the Bureau s most recent population

Using data provided by the U.S. Census Bureau, this study first recreates the Bureau s most recent population Backgrounder Center for Immigration Studies December 2012 Projecting Immigration s Impact on the Size and Age Structure of the 21st Century American Population By Steven A. Camarota Using data provided

More information

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor Journal of Economic Integration 2(2), June 2008; -45 Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor Shigemi Yabuuchi Nagoya City University Abstract This paper discusses the problem of unemployment

More information

MEN in several minority groups in the United States

MEN in several minority groups in the United States WHY DO MINORITY MEN EARN LESS? A STUDY OF WAGE DIFFERENTIALS AMONG THE HIGHLY EDUCATED Dan Black, Amelia Haviland, Seth Sanders, and Lowell Taylor* Abstract We estimate wage gaps using nonparametric matching

More information

IMMIGRATION AND LABOR PRODUCTIVITY. Giovanni Peri UC Davis Jan 22-23, 2015

IMMIGRATION AND LABOR PRODUCTIVITY. Giovanni Peri UC Davis Jan 22-23, 2015 1 IMMIGRATION AND LABOR PRODUCTIVITY Giovanni Peri UC Davis Jan 22-23, 2015 Looking for a starting point we can agree on 2 Complex issue, because of many effects and confounding factors. Let s start from

More information

Immigrants are playing an increasingly

Immigrants are playing an increasingly Trends in the Low-Wage Immigrant Labor Force, 2000 2005 THE URBAN INSTITUTE March 2007 Randy Capps, Karina Fortuny The Urban Institute Immigrants are playing an increasingly important role in the U.S.

More information